Utility Maximization and Choice

Similar documents
Preferences and Utility

Chapter 4 UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Intro to Economic analysis

Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Chapter 4. Our Consumption Choices. What can we buy with this money? UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE

Microeconomics Pre-sessional September Sotiris Georganas Economics Department City University London

Chapter 4 UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE

We want to solve for the optimal bundle (a combination of goods) that a rational consumer will purchase.

Graphs Details Math Examples Using data Tax example. Decision. Intermediate Micro. Lecture 5. Chapter 5 of Varian

Lecture 4 - Utility Maximization

ECMB02F -- Problem Set 2 Solutions

We will make several assumptions about these preferences:

Cost Functions. PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

Overview Definitions Mathematical Properties Properties of Economic Functions Exam Tips. Midterm 1 Review. ECON 100A - Fall Vincent Leah-Martin

Chapter 3. A Consumer s Constrained Choice

Lecture 7. The consumer s problem(s) Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2018 Last updated: April 28, 2018

MODULE No. : 9 : Ordinal Utility Approach

Macroeconomics for Development Week 3 Class

Chapter 3: Model of Consumer Behavior

MICROECONOMIC THEORY 1

Consumer Theory. The consumer s problem: budget set, interior and corner solutions.

Marginal Utility, Utils Total Utility, Utils

Review of Previous Lectures

Johanna has 10 to spend, the price of an apple is 1 and the price of a banana is 2. What are her options?

Math: Deriving supply and demand curves

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

a. Show the budget set containing all of the commodity bundles that the following individuals can afford.

p 1 _ x 1 (p 1 _, p 2, I ) x 1 X 1 X 2

3. Consumer Behavior

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

Solutions to Assignment #2

(0.50, 2.75) (0,3) Equivalent Variation Compensating Variation

2) Indifference curve (IC) 1. Represents consumer preferences. 2. MRS (marginal rate of substitution) = MUx/MUy = (-)slope of the IC = (-) Δy/Δx

Lecture Demand Functions

Chapter 4 The Theory of Individual Behavior

CLAS. Utility Functions Handout

Chapter 8 COST FUNCTIONS. Copyright 2005 by South-western, a division of Thomson learning. All rights reserved.

Econ205 Intermediate Microeconomics with Calculus Chapter 1

Economics II - Exercise Session # 3, October 8, Suggested Solution

14.03 Fall 2004 Problem Set 2 Solutions

Budget Constrained Choice with Two Commodities

Faculty: Sunil Kumar

Summer 2016 Microeconomics 2 ECON1201. Nicole Liu Z

Taxation and Efficiency : (a) : The Expenditure Function

Chapter Four. Utility Functions. Utility Functions. Utility Functions. Utility

3/1/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 4: Solving the Consumer s Problem. The Story So Far. Today s Aims. Solving the Consumer s Problem

Introductory to Microeconomic Theory [08/29/12] Karen Tsai

14.54 International Trade Lecture 3: Preferences and Demand

Lecture 2 Consumer theory (continued)

PROBLEM SET 3 SOLUTIONS. 1. Question 1

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

Lecture 1: The market and consumer theory. Intermediate microeconomics Jonas Vlachos Stockholms universitet

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 1

Chapter 3. Consumer Behavior

Budget Constrained Choice with Two Commodities

Lecture 5. Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H. 1 Summary of Lectures 1, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality

Lecture Note 7 Linking Compensated and Uncompensated Demand: Theory and Evidence. David Autor, MIT Department of Economics

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

UNIT 1 THEORY OF COSUMER BEHAVIOUR: BASIC THEMES

ECON Micro Foundations

The objectives of the producer

Chapter 6 DEMAND RELATIONSHIPS AMONG GOODS. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Section 2 Solutions. Econ 50 - Stanford University - Winter Quarter 2015/16. January 22, Solve the following utility maximization problem:

Lecture 4 - Theory of Choice and Individual Demand

Consumers cannot afford all the goods and services they desire. Consumers are limited by their income and the prices of goods.

14.03 Fall 2004 Problem Set 3 Solutions

PAPER NO.1 : MICROECONOMICS ANALYSIS MODULE NO.6 : INDIFFERENCE CURVES

Preferences. Rationality in Economics. Indifference Curves

Simple Model Economy. Business Economics Theory of Consumer Behavior Thomas & Maurice, Chapter 5. Circular Flow Model. Modeling Household Decisions

The Rational Consumer. The Objective of Consumers. The Budget Set for Consumers. Indifference Curves are Like a Topographical Map for Utility.

Firm s demand for the input. Supply of the input = price of the input.

ECN 2001 MICROECONOMICS I SLUTSKY EQUATION Class Discussion 6 (Ch. 7) - Answer Key TRUE-FALSE

I. More Fundamental Concepts and Definitions from Mathematics

ECONOMICS SOLUTION BOOK 2ND PUC. Unit 2

PRODUCTION COSTS. Econ 311 Microeconomics 1 Lecture Material Prepared by Dr. Emmanuel Codjoe

If Tom's utility function is given by U(F, S) = FS, graph the indifference curves that correspond to 1, 2, 3, and 4 utils, respectively.

Midterm 1 - Solutions

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 1-2: Uncompensated and Compensated Elasticities; Static and Dynamic Labor Supply

CHAPTER 4 APPENDIX DEMAND THEORY A MATHEMATICAL TREATMENT

Lecture 4: Consumer Choice

Preferences - A Reminder

Consumer Choice. Theory of Consumer Behavior. Households and Firms. Consumer Choice & Decisions

Intermediate Micro HW 2

CPT Section C General Economics Unit 2 Ms. Anita Sharma

Module 4. The theory of consumer behaviour. Introduction

Midterm #1 Exam Study Questions AK AK AK Selected problems

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Problem Set 1 Answer Key. I. Short Problems 1. Check whether the following three functions represent the same underlying preferences

Eliminating Substitution Bias. One eliminate substitution bias by continuously updating the market basket of goods purchased.

Consumer Budgets, Indifference Curves, and Utility Maximization 1 Instructional Primer 2

CONSUMER OPTIMISATION

Journal of College Teaching & Learning February 2007 Volume 4, Number 2 ABSTRACT

Mathematical Economics Dr Wioletta Nowak, room 205 C

Introduction to Economics I: Consumer Theory

Topic 2 Part II: Extending the Theory of Consumer Behaviour

University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2013 Ajaz Hussain TEST 1 SOLUTIONS GOOD LUCK!

Firm s Problem. Simon Board. This Version: September 20, 2009 First Version: December, 2009.

Transcription:

Utility Maximization and Choice PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University 1

Utility Maximization and Choice Complaints about the Economic Approach Do individuals make the lightning calculations required for utility maximization? The utility-maximization model predicts many aspects of behavior Economists assume that people behave as if they made such calculations 2

Utility Maximization and Choice Complaints about the Economic Approach The economic model of choice is extremely selfish Nothing in the model prevents individuals from getting satisfaction from doing good 3

An Initial Survey Optimization principle, Utility maximization To maximize utility, given a fixed amount of income to spend An individual will buy those quantities of goods That exhaust his or her total income And for which the MRS is equal to the rate at which the goods can be traded one for the other in the marketplace MRS (of x for y) = the ratio of the price of x to the price of y (p x /p y ) 4

Assumptions The Two-Good Case Budget: I dollars to allocate between good x and good y p x - price of good x p y - price of good y Budget constraint: p x x + p y y I Slope = -p x /p y If all of I is spent on good x, buy I/p x units of good x 5

4.1 The Individual s Budget Constraint for Two Goods Quantity of y I p y I=p x x+p y y I Quantity of x p x Those combinations of x and y that the individual can afford are shown in the shaded triangle. If, as we usually assume, the individual prefers more rather than less of every good, the outer boundary of this triangle is the relevant constraint where all the available funds are spent either on x or on y. The slope of this straight-line boundary is given by p x /p y. 6

The Two-Good Case First-order conditions for a maximum Point of tangency between the budget constraint and the indifference curve: slope of budget constraint=slope of indifference curve p p x y dy =- = MRS(of x for y) dx U=constant 7

4.2 A Graphical Demonstration of Utility Maximization Quantity of y B y* C D I=p x x+p y y A U 3 U 2 x* U 1 Quantity of x Point C represents the highest utility level that can be reached by the individual, given the budget constraint. Therefore, the combination x*,y* is the rational way for the individual to allocate purchasing power. Only for this combination of goods will two conditions hold: All available funds will be spent, and the individual s psychic rate of trade-off (MRS) will be equal to the rate at which the goods can be traded in the market ( p x /p y ). 8

The Two-Good Case The tangency rule Is necessary but not sufficient unless we assume that MRS is diminishing If MRS is diminishing, then indifference curves are strictly convex If MRS is not diminishing, we must check second-order conditions to ensure that we are at a maximum 9

4.3 Example of an Indifference Curve Map for Which the Tangency Condition Does Not Ensure a Maximum Quantity of y A C U 3 U 2 B U 1 Quantity of x If indifference curves do not obey the assumption of a diminishing MRS, not all points of tangency (points for which MRS = p x /p y ) may truly be points of maximum utility. In this example, tangency point C is inferior to many other points that can also be purchased with the available funds. In order that the necessary conditions for a maximum (i.e., the tangency conditions) also be sufficient, one usually assumes that the MRS is diminishing; that is, the utility function is strictly quasi-concave. 10

Corner solutions The Two-Good Case Individuals may maximize utility by choosing to consume only one of the goods At the optimal point the budget constraint is flatter than the indifference curve The rate at which x can be traded for y in the market is lower than the MRS 11

4.4 Corner Solution for Utility Maximization Quantity of y U 1 U 2 U 3 x* Quantity of x With the preferences represented by this set of indifference curves, utility maximization occurs at E, where 0 amounts of good y are consumed. The first-order conditions for a maximum must be modified somewhat to accommodate this possibility. 12

The n-good Case The individual s objective is to maximize utility = U(x 1,x 2,,x n ) subject to the budget constraint I = p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 + + p n x n Set up the Lagrangian: L = U(x 1,x 2,,x n ) + λ(i - p 1 x 1 - p 2 x 2 - - p n x n ) 13

The n-good Case First-order conditions for an interior maximum L/ x 1 = U/ x 1 - λp 1 = 0 L / x 2 = U/ x 2 - λp 2 = 0 L / x n = U/ x n - λp n = 0 L / λ = I - p 1 x 1 - p 2 x 2 - - p n x n = 0 14

The n-good Case Implications of first-order conditions For any two goods, x i and y j : U / xi pi = = U / x p j j MRS ( x for x ) i j 15

The n-good Case Interpreting the Lagrange multiplier λ is the marginal utility of an extra dollar of consumption expenditure λ The marginal utility of income U / x U / x U / x = 1 = 2 =... = n p p p 1 2 n 16

The n-good Case At the margin, the price of a good Represents the consumer s evaluation of the utility of the last unit consumed How much the consumer is willing to pay for the last unit p i = U / λ x i, for every i 17

Corner solutions The n-good Case Means that the first-order conditions must be modified: L/ x i = U/ x i - λp i 0 (i = 1,,n) If L/ x i = U/ x i - λp i < 0, then x i = 0 This means that p i U / x xi i > = λ MU any good whose price exceeds its marginal value to the consumer will not be purchased λ 18

4.1 Cobb Douglas Demand Functions Cobb-Douglas utility function: U(x,y) = x α y β Setting up the Lagrangian: L = x α y β + λ(i - p x x - p y y) First-order conditions: L/ x = αx α-1 y β - λp x = 0 L/ y = βx α y β-1 - λp y = 0 L/ λ = I - p x x - p y y = 0 19

4.1 Cobb Douglas Demand Functions First-order conditions imply: αy/βx = p x /p y Since α + β = 1: p y y = (β/α)p x x = [(1- α)/α]p x x Substituting into the budget constraint: I = p x x + [(1- α)/α]p x x = (1/α)p x x Solving: x*=αi/p x and y*=βi/p y The individual will allocate α percent of his income to good x and β percent of his income to good y 20

4.1 Cobb Douglas Demand Functions Cobb-Douglas utility function Is limited in its ability to explain actual consumption behavior The share of income devoted to a good often changes in response to changing economic conditions A more general functional form might be more useful 21

4.2 CES Demand Assume that δ = 0.5 U(x,y) = x 0.5 + y 0.5 Setting up the Lagrangian: L = x 0.5 + y 0.5 + λ(i - p x x - p y y) First-order conditions for a maximum: L/ x = 0.5x -0.5 - λp x = 0 L/ y = 0.5y -0.5 - λp y = 0 L/ λ = I - p x x - p y y = 0 22

4.2 CES Demand This means that: (y/x) 0.5 = p x /p y Substituting into the budget constraint, we can solve for the demand functions x* = I p [1 + ( p / p )] x x y y* = I p [1 + ( p / p )] y y x The share of income spent on either x or y is not a constant Depends on the ratio of the two prices The higher is the relative price of x, the smaller will be the share of income spent on x 23

4.2 CES Demand If δ = -1, U(x,y) = -x -1 - y -1 First-order conditions imply that y/x = (p x /p y ) 0.5 The demand functions are x* = p x I py 1 + p x 0.5 y* = p y I p x 1+ p y 0.5 24

4.2 CES Demand If δ = -, U(x,y) = Min(x,4y) The person will choose only combinations for which x = 4y This means that I = p x x + p y y = p x x + p y (x/4) I = (p x + 0.25p y )x The demand functions are x* = p x + I 0.25 p y y* = I + 4 p x p y 25

Indirect Utility Function It is often possible to manipulate firstorder conditions to solve for optimal values of x 1,x 2,,x n These optimal values will be x* 1 = x 1 (p 1,p 2,,p n,i) x* 2 = x 2 (p 1,p 2,,p n,i) x* n = x n (p 1,p 2,,p n,i) 26

Indirect Utility Function We can use the optimal values of the x s to find the indirect utility function maximum utility = U[x* 1 (p 1,p 2,,p n,i), x* 2 (p 1,p 2,,p n,i),,x* n (p 1,p 2,,p n,i)] = = V(p 1,p 2,,p n,i) The optimal level of utility will depend indirectly on prices and income 27

The Lump Sum Principle Taxes on an individual s general purchasing power Are superior to taxes on a specific good An income tax allows the individual to decide freely how to allocate remaining income A tax on a specific good will reduce an individual s purchasing power and distort his choices 28

4.5 The Lump Sum Principle of Taxation A tax on good x would shift the utility-maximizing choice from x*, y* to x 1, y 1. An income tax that collected the same amount would shift the budget constraint to I. Utility would be higher (U 2 ) with the income tax than with the tax on x alone (U 1 ). 29

4.3 Indirect Utility and the Lump Sum Principle Cobb-Douglas utility function With α = β = 0.5, We know that x*=i/2p x and y*=i/2p y The indirect utility function V p p (x*) (y*) 0. 5 0. 5 ( x, y, I) = = 2 p I p 0.5 0.5 x y 30

4.3 Indirect Utility and the Lump Sum Principle Fixed proportions x*=i/[p x + 0.25p y ] and y*=i/[4p x +p y ] The indirect utility function V ( p, p, I) = min( x*,4 y*) = x y I = x* = = p + 0.25 p x = 4 y* = 4 p x 4 + p y y 31

4.3 Indirect Utility and the Lump Sum Principle The lump sum principle Cobb-Douglas If a tax of $1 was imposed on good x The individual will purchase x* = 2 Indirect utility will fall from 2 to 1.41 An equal-revenue tax will reduce income to $6 Indirect utility will fall from 2 to 1.5 32

4.3 Indirect Utility and the Lump Sum Principle The lump sum principle Fixed-proportions If a tax of $1 was imposed on good x Indirect utility will fall from 4 to 8/3 An equal-revenue tax will reduce income to $16/3 Indirect utility will fall from 4 to 8/3 Since preferences are rigid, the tax on x does not distort choices 33

Expenditure Minimization Dual minimization problem for utility maximization Allocate income to achieve a given level of utility with the minimal expenditure The goal and the constraint have been reversed 34

4.6 The Dual Expenditure-Minimization Problem Quantity of y E 2 E 3 B y* A E 1 C x* U 2 Quantity of x The dual of the utility-maximization problem is to attain a given utility level (U2) with minimal expenditures. An expenditure level of E1 does not permit U2 to be reached, whereas E3 provides more spending power than is strictly necessary. With expenditure E2, this person can just reach U2 by consuming x and y. 35

Expenditure Minimization The individual s problem is to choose x 1,x 2,,x n to minimize total expenditures = E = p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 + + p n x n subject to the constraint utility =Ū= U(x 1,x 2,,x n ) The optimal amounts of x 1,x 2,,x n will depend on the prices of the goods and the required utility level 36

Expenditure Minimization Expenditure function The individual s expenditure function Shows the minimal expenditures Necessary to achieve a given utility level For a particular set of prices minimal expenditures = E(p 1,p 2,,p n,u) 37

Expenditure Minimization The expenditure function and the indirect utility function Are inversely related Both depend on market prices But involve different constraints 38

Cobb-Douglas 4.4 Two Expenditure Functions The indirect utility function in the two-good case: I V ( px, py, I) = 2 0.5 0.5 p p x y If we interchange the role of utility and income (expenditure), we will have the expenditure function E(p x,p y,u) = 2p x 0.5 p y 0.5 U 39

4.4 Two Expenditure Functions Fixed-proportions case The indirect utility function: V ( p, p, I) x y If we interchange the role of utility and income (expenditure), we will have the expenditure function E(p x,p y,u) = (p x + 0.25p y )U = p x I + 0.25 p y 40

Properties of Expenditure Functions Homogeneity A doubling of all prices will precisely double the value of required expenditures Homogeneous of degree one Nondecreasing in prices E/ p i 0 for every good, i Concave in prices Functions that always lie below tangents to them 41

4.7 Expenditure Functions Are Concave in Prices E(p 1, ) E pseudo E(p1, ) E(p* 1, ) p* 1 p1 At p 1 this person spends E(p 1 *,...). If he or she continues to buy the same set of goods as p 1 changes, then expenditures would be given by E pseudo. Because his or her consumption patterns will likely change as p 1 changes, actual expenditures will be less than this. 42

Engel s law Budget Shares Fraction of income spent on food decreases as income increases Budget shares, s i =p i x i / I Recent budget share data Engel s law is clearly visible Cobb Douglas utility function Is not useful for detailed empirical studies of household behavior 43

E4.1 Budget shares of U.S. households, 2008 44

Linear expenditure system Generalization of the Cobb Douglas function Incorporates the idea that certain minimal amounts of each good must be bought by an individual (x 0, y 0 ) U(x,y)=(x-x 0 ) α (y-y 0 ) β For x x 0 and y y 0, Where α+β=1 45

Linear expenditure system Supernumerary income (I*) Amount of purchasing power remaining after purchasing the minimum bundle I*=I-p x x 0 -p y y 0 The demand functions are: x = (p x x 0 +αi*)/p x and y = (p y y 0 +βi*)/p y The share equations: s x = α+(βp x x 0 -αp y y 0 )/I s x = β+(αp y y 0 -βp x x 0 )/I Not homothetic 46

CES utility function CES utility δ δ x y U ( x, y) =, for δ 1, δ 0 δ + δ Budget shares: s x =1/[1+(p y /p x ) K ] and s y =1/[1+(p x /p y ) K ] Where K = δ/(δ-1) Homothetic 47

The almost ideal demand system Expenditure functions Logarithmic differentiation ln E( px, py, V ) 1 E px xpx = = = ln p E( p, p, V ) p ln p E x x y x x s x 48

The almost ideal demand system Almost ideal demand system Expenditure function ln E( p, p, V ) = a + a ln p + a ln p + x y 0 1 x 2 y + 0.5 b (ln p ) + b ln p ln p + 2 1 x 2 x y + 0.5 b (ln p ) + Vc p p 2 c c 3 y 0 x y 1 2 Almost ideal demand system Expenditure function 49

The almost ideal demand system s = a + b ln p + b ln p + c Vc p p c c x 1 1 x 2 y 1 0 x y 1 2 s = a + b ln p + b ln p + c Vc p p s c c y 2 2 x 3 y 2 0 x y x + s = 1 s = a + b ln p + b ln p + c ( E / p) s x 1 1 x 2 y 1 y 2 y 2 2 x 3 y 2 p is an index of prices ln p ln l + b = a + b ln p + b ln p + c 1 2 2 = a0 + a1 px + a2 n py + 0.5 b1 (ln px) + ln p x ln py + 0.5b (ln ) 3 p y 2 ( E / p) 50