Zhen Sun, Milind Dawande, Ganesh Janakiraman, and Vijay Mookerjee

Similar documents
ISSN BWPEF Uninformative Equilibrium in Uniform Price Auctions. Arup Daripa Birkbeck, University of London.

6.896 Topics in Algorithmic Game Theory February 10, Lecture 3

GAME THEORY. Department of Economics, MIT, Follow Muhamet s slides. We need the following result for future reference.

October An Equilibrium of the First Price Sealed Bid Auction for an Arbitrary Distribution.

Byungwan Koh. College of Business, Hankuk University of Foreign Studies, 107 Imun-ro, Dongdaemun-gu, Seoul KOREA

CHAPTER 14: REPEATED PRISONER S DILEMMA

Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A.

ECE 586BH: Problem Set 5: Problems and Solutions Multistage games, including repeated games, with observed moves

Yao s Minimax Principle

HW Consider the following game:

Math 167: Mathematical Game Theory Instructor: Alpár R. Mészáros

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions?

Maximizing Winnings on Final Jeopardy!

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017

All-Pay Contests. (Ron Siegel; Econometrica, 2009) PhDBA 279B 13 Feb Hyo (Hyoseok) Kang First-year BPP

(a) Describe the game in plain english and find its equivalent strategic form.

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring

Optimal Auctions. Game Theory Course: Jackson, Leyton-Brown & Shoham

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

Mechanism Design and Auctions

Maximizing Winnings on Final Jeopardy!

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

Strategy -1- Strategy

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

The Real Numbers. Here we show one way to explicitly construct the real numbers R. First we need a definition.

Francesco Nava Microeconomic Principles II EC202 Lent Term 2010

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

IEOR E4004: Introduction to OR: Deterministic Models

ECON 803: MICROECONOMIC THEORY II Arthur J. Robson Fall 2016 Assignment 9 (due in class on November 22)

Zhiling Guo and Dan Ma

Their opponent will play intelligently and wishes to maximize their own payoff.

ECE 586GT: Problem Set 1: Problems and Solutions Analysis of static games

B. Online Appendix. where ɛ may be arbitrarily chosen to satisfy 0 < ɛ < s 1 and s 1 is defined in (B1). This can be rewritten as

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Econ 601 Prof. James Peck Extra Practice Problems Answers (for final)

Regret Minimization and Security Strategies

MAT 4250: Lecture 1 Eric Chung

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Solution to Tutorial 1

Solution to Tutorial /2013 Semester I MA4264 Game Theory

Exercises Solutions: Game Theory

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

Lecture 5: Iterative Combinatorial Auctions

Lecture 11: Bandits with Knapsacks

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012

CS711 Game Theory and Mechanism Design

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

Outline for today. Stat155 Game Theory Lecture 13: General-Sum Games. General-sum games. General-sum games. Dominated pure strategies

Chapter 10: Mixed strategies Nash equilibria, reaction curves and the equality of payoffs theorem

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 9

Approximate Revenue Maximization with Multiple Items

Web Appendix: Proofs and extensions.

Recap First-Price Revenue Equivalence Optimal Auctions. Auction Theory II. Lecture 19. Auction Theory II Lecture 19, Slide 1

The Duo-Item Bisection Auction

Comparative Study between Linear and Graphical Methods in Solving Optimization Problems

Chapter 2 Strategic Dominance

Pricing Problems under the Markov Chain Choice Model

CS364A: Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture #3: Myerson s Lemma

Lecture 5 Leadership and Reputation

Matching Markets and Google s Sponsored Search

An Ascending Double Auction

Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions.

Haiyang Feng College of Management and Economics, Tianjin University, Tianjin , CHINA

In Class Exercises. Problem 1

All Equilibrium Revenues in Buy Price Auctions

Game Theory: Additional Exercises

CMSC 858F: Algorithmic Game Theory Fall 2010 Introduction to Algorithmic Game Theory

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

A folk theorem for one-shot Bertrand games

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Auctions with Severely Bounded Communication

Multiunit Auctions: Package Bidding October 24, Multiunit Auctions: Package Bidding

Foreign Bidders Going Once, Going Twice... Protection in Government Procurement Auctions

Notes on Auctions. Theorem 1 In a second price sealed bid auction bidding your valuation is always a weakly dominant strategy.

Problem Set 2 Answers

Equilibrium Selection in Multi-Player Games with Auction Applications

Answer Key for M. A. Economics Entrance Examination 2017 (Main version)

When does strategic information disclosure lead to perfect consumer information?

Game Theory Lecture #16

The Cascade Auction A Mechanism For Deterring Collusion In Auctions

Bargaining and Competition Revisited Takashi Kunimoto and Roberto Serrano

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV. If any mistakes or typos are spotted, kindly communicate them to

MA300.2 Game Theory 2005, LSE

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours

Game Theory: Normal Form Games

Prisoner s dilemma with T = 1

MATH 4321 Game Theory Solution to Homework Two

ECO 426 (Market Design) - Lecture 11

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Second Midterm Examination Answers

( ) = R + ª. Similarly, for any set endowed with a preference relation º, we can think of the upper contour set as a correspondance  : defined as

Efficiency in Decentralized Markets with Aggregate Uncertainty

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Graduate School of Management and Economics

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

Transcription:

RESEARCH ARTICLE THE MAKING OF A GOOD IMPRESSION: INFORMATION HIDING IN AD ECHANGES Zhen Sun, Milind Dawande, Ganesh Janakiraman, and Vijay Mookerjee Naveen Jindal School of Management, The University of Texas at Dallas, Richardson, T 75080 U.S.A. {zhen.sun@utdallas.edu} {milind@utdallas.edu} {ganesh@utdallas.edu} {vijaym@utdallas.edu} Appendix A Proof of Theorem Proof. Since the bids for impressions from publisher θ are less than or equal to u θ, pu θ θ is an upper bound of the expected revenue. We θ will show that the expected revenue from the policy of complete revealing converges to this upper bound as C approaches infinity. To establish this, we will show that, as C 6 4, E[SH c {w c (θ)}] 6 u θ To establish this, we will show that SH c {w c (θ)} 6 u θ in probability. That is, for any δ θ > 0, c ( θ c{ w θ } δθ) lim P u SH ( ) = 0 ( c{ } ) Since SH c {w c (θ)} # u θ, we will show that lim c P SH w ( θ ) u δ =. θ θ 0 Let F θ (x) and F S θh (x) denote the cumulative density function of w c (θ) and SH c {w c (θ)}, respectively. Then, we have Let h = F θ (u θ δ θ ) <, then c SH ( H c{ ( θ) } θ δθ) = θ ( θ δθ) = [ Fθ( uθ δθ) ] + [ Fθ( uθ δθ) ] [ Fθ( uθ δθ) ] PS w u F u MIS Quarterly Vol. 40 No. 3 Appendices/September 206 A

c ( SHc{ θ } θ δθ) [ h Ch ( h) ] h [ Ch ( h) ] lim [ Ch ( h) ] h ( Ch ) lim P w ( ) u = lim + = lim + lim = 0+ = ( ) lim = ( h) lim ( h ) ln( h ) = 0 where the penultimate equality follows from L Hôpital s rule. This completes the proof of the claim. Proof of Theorem 2 Proof. It suffices to demonstrate a specific instance (of the optimization problem under the one-call design) for which the stated claim holds. Let C = {, 2}, and Θ = {, 2}. Let A c = for all c 0 C. Thus, the advertiser label a can be suppressed. In this instance, let bidder hold a valuation of 0 if θ =, and 0 if θ = 2. That is, for c =, v () = 0, v (2) = 0. Let bidder 2 hold a valuation of 0 if θ = 2, and 0 if θ =. That is, for c = 2, v 2 () = 0, v 2 (2) = 0. Let p = p 2 = 2, that is, both publisher identities are equally likely. Consider the policy of always revealing θ. Then, for any realization of θ, one bid is 0 and the other bid is 0. Since the second-highest bid is 0, then any impression generates a revenue of 0. Therefore, the expected revenue generated from the auction is 0. Next, consider the policy 0+ 0 of always hiding θ. In this case, each bidder submits a bid equal to 2 = 5 and, therefore, the second-highest bid is 5. Thus, the expected revenue generated from the auction is 5. The result follows. Proof of Theorem 3 Proof. In this case, we have C = 2 and A c = for all c 0 C. Therefore, we can simplify the objective function by replacing SH c {.} with min c {.} and suppressing the advertiser label a. Then the optimization problem becomes where q R 0, [ ] Θ. Observe that θ c θ c { pq θ RE[ { v θ }] + E[ { pqhv θ θ θ } c c θ ]} max min ( ) min ( ) qr A2 MIS Quarterly Vol. 40 No. 3 Appendices/September 206

( ) = min{ ()}+min () = min () + min () = min () + min () min () + min () =min () + min () min () + () =min () + =min{ ()} = (0). Thus, the expected revenue under any feasible policy is smaller than (0), which is the expected revenue from the complete hiding policy. This implies the optimality of the complete hiding policy. Proof of Theorem 4 Proof. Consider the following instance of the optimization problem under the one-call design. For an integer 2, let = {,2,,2,2} and Θ ={,2,,}. Let = for all. Therefore, we suppress the advertiser label. In this instance, let bidders and 2 hold a valuation of when =, and 0 otherwise. That is, for =,2, () = () =, (2) = (2) = 0,, () = () = 0. Similarly, let bidders 3 and 4 hold a valuation of when =2, and 0 otherwise. That is, for =3,4, () = () = 0, (2) = (2) =, (3) = (3) = 0,, () = () = 0. In general, for =,2,,, let bidders 2 and 2 hold a valuation of when =, and 0 otherwise. That is, for =2,2, () = () =, and () = 0, {2,2}and. Let = for all Θ, i.e., all publisher identities are equally likely. Consider the policy of always revealing. Then, for any realization of, the second-highest bid is. Thus, every impression generates a revenue of. Therefore, the expected revenue generated from an auction is. Next, consider the policy of always hiding. In this case, each bidder submits a bid equal to and, therefore, the second-highest bid is. Thus, the expected revenue generated from an auction is. The result follows. Proof of Theorem 5 Proof. From inequality (5), we have ( ) ()+ (0). Thus, OPT ()+ (0) Since the maximum of two numbers is at least as large as their average, we have max (), (0) ( ()+ (0)) The two inequalities above imply that max (), (0) OPT To establish the tightness of the bound, consider the following example. Let ={,2,3,4} and Θ={,2,3,4}. Let = for all. Therefore, we suppress the advertiser label. The matrix of valuations, where the rows correspond to and the columns correspond to, is as follows: 0 0 0 0 0 0 2 0 0 0 0 2 MIS Quarterly Vol. 40 No. 3 Appendices/September 206 A3

Let = for all Θ. Consider the policy of complete revealing. For the first two realizations of, the second-highest bid is, while, for the last two realizations of, the second-highest bid is 0. Thus, () = + =. Also, (0) =SH,,, =. Finally, max (), (0) = OPT. This implies that OPT. The policy of revealing the first two publisher identities and hiding the last two, has expected revenue + + min{,} =, and is therefore optimal. The tightness follows. Proof of Theorem 6 Proof. For a uniform policy, we have = for every Θ. Then, the expected revenue for such a policy is ( )= [SH { ()}] + max () (,) (from()) = [SH { ()}] +() max (, ) = ()+() (0) (from (3) and (4)) () We know from inequality (5) that Thus, for a uniform policy with =, we have OPT ()+ (0) 2 = 2 ()+ 2 (0) 2 OPT The tightness of this bound can be shown by the example in the proof of Theorem 5. Proof of Theorem 8 Proof. Consider the following example. Let ={,2} and Θ={,2,...,2} where 2. Let each bidder work with exactly advertisers. More specifically, let = {,2,, } and = { +,,2}. Let (, ) = if = and (, ) = 0 otherwise. Let (, ) = if =+ and (, ) = 0 otherwise. An explanation follows. For the first bidder ( =), an impression from any of the first publishers ( {,2,, }) generates a value of when the specific ad = is served. All other publisher-ad pairs result in zero value. Similarly, for the second bidder, an impression from any publisher { +,,2} generates a value of when the specific ad = is served, whereas all other (, ) pairs provide zero value. The matrices of valuations for the two bidders are provided below: 2 Valuations for Bidder (c = ) 2 + 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 + +2 2 Valuations for Bidder 2( = 2) + +2 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Let = for all Θ, that is, all publisher identities are equally likely. This completes the specification of the example. A4 MIS Quarterly Vol. 40 No. 3 Appendices/September 206

We will prove our result by showing the claims that the optimal expected revenue under one-call design (OPT ) is and that the optimal expected revenue under the two-call design (OPT ) is at least. Thus, is larger than, which can be made arbitrarily large. We now proceed to prove the two claims made above. In the one-call design, notice that the expected revenue of the complete revealing policy, that is, (), is 0 since the second-highest bid is 0 for every impression. Similarly, the expected revenue of the complete hiding policy, i.e., (0), is since both bidders have an expected valuation of for every impression. Next, consider the policy of revealing every impression with probability (i.e., = ). We know from () that the expected revenue under this policy is ( )= (0)+ () =. We also know from Theorem 6 that this policy ( = ) generates a revenue of at least half of OPT. This implies that OPT, which as we have seen above, is (0). Therefore, OPT =. In the two-call design, consider the policy of choosing =0. Since is known to the winning bidder before choosing the ad, we see from the matrices of valuations above that each bidder obtains a value of from 50% of the publishers and a value of 0 from the remaining publishers. Thus, under the =0 policy, each of the two bidders submits a bid equal to for every impression. Therefore, the expected revenue under this policy is (0) =. This implies that OPT. Proof of Theorem 9 Proof. The arguments used in the proofs of Statements and 2 are similar to those in the proofs of Theorems 5, and 6. Therefore, for brevity, we avoid providing the proofs of these statements here. Note that the policy of complete revealing is the same under the one-call and the twocall designs. Therefore, Statement 3 follows from Theorem. Recall that the instances in the proofs of Theorems 2 and 4 use = for all. Since the expected revenue of any policy stays the same under the one-call and the two-call designs when = for all, the proof of Statement 5 follows from those of Theorems 2 and 4. We now proceed to prove Statement 4. Consider a policy of. Then the expected revenue of this policy is The result follows. ( )= min { ()}+min ( ) () = min () + min ( ) () min () + min ( ) () min () + ( ) () =min{ ()} = (0). Appendix B Derivations of the Closed-Form Expressions in Simplification under Uniform Bidder Valuations Assume that the valuation of bidder toward publisher Θ (i.e., ()) follows a uniform distribution with the support [0, ]. For a given, let (), be the smallest and let (), =0. For a given publisher identity, let () () and () () denote the cumulative density function and the probability density function, respectively, of bidder ()'s valuation towards publisher (i.e., () ()), where () () follows a uniform distribution with support [0, (), ]. Then, MIS Quarterly Vol. 40 No. 3 Appendices/September 206 A5

max { ()} = (), (), = (), (),, = (), (), (), = (), (), (),, (), = (), (), (), = = (), (), (), (), (), ( ) (), (), () () () () The last expression above is the one specified in the Simplification under Uniform Bidder Valuations in the article. Next, we derive a closed-form expression for [SH { ()}]. [SH { ()}] = = = = (), (),, () (),, () () ( ) () + (), () () () () () () (),,,, (the first term captures the case in which the bidder with bids from Uniform0, b ( ), has the second highest bid, and the second term captures all the other possibilities. ) (), (), (), (), (), (), (), (), (), (),,,,,, (), (),,,,, + (), ( ), (), (), + (),, (), (),, (), +, (), (), A6 MIS Quarterly Vol. 40 No. 3 Appendices/September 206

= = = = = (), (), (), (), (), (),,, (), (), (), (), (), (),, =,, (), (),, (),, (),, (), (),, (), (),, (), (),,,, (),, (), + (),,, (),, (),,, (),,, (), (),,, (),,, (), (), (),, (), (),,, (), (), (), (), ( + ), (),, (), (), (), +, (), (), +, (), (), + (),, + (), (),,, (), (), (), (), (), (), + ( + 2) (),, (), (), ( + ), (), (), (), ( + 2) (),., MIS Quarterly Vol. 40 No. 3 Appendices/September 206 A7

The last expression above is the one specified in the Simplification under Uniform Bidder Valuations in the article. Appendix C Viability of Information Hiding by Competing Ad Exchanges Consider two ad exchanges ( and ), four bidders (B, B2,, and B4), and four publishers (P, P2, P3, and P4). Ad exchange sells impressions from publishers P and P2, and ad exchange sells impressions from publishers P3 and P4. The valuations of the bidders toward the impressions from different publishers are given in Table C. For example, the value in row B and column P indicates that bidder B has valuation towards an impression from publisher P. This bidder has a valuation of 0, 0.8, and 0, for the impressions from publishers P2, P3, and P4, respectively. Table C. Bidder Valuations Toward Publishers P P2 P3 P4 B 0 0.8 0 B2 0 0 0.8 0 0.8 0 B4 0.8 0 0 The game has two stages: First, ad exchanges and simultaneously decide on their information revelation policies. For an ad exchange, there are two options: () Reveal the publisher identity to bidders in all auctions (CR policy). (2) Hide the publisher identity to bidders in all auctions (CH policy). Second, bidders B-B4 choose one ad exchange to join after knowing the information revelation policies chosen by the two ad exchanges. Using backward induction, we first analyze how bidders choose between the two ad exchanges in the second stage. Since there are two options for an ad exchange, there are four information revelation scenarios that the four bidders face: Scenario : Both the ad exchanges choose the CR policy. Scenario 2: Ad exchange chooses the CR policy and ad exchange chooses the CH policy. Scenario 3: Ad exchange chooses the CH policy and ad exchange chooses the CR policy. Scenario 4: Both ad exchanges choose the CH policy. Table C2 describes the game between the four bidders and reports the possible equilibria under scenario above. Each cell in Table C2 reports the payoffs corresponding to a set of joining decisions made by the four bidders. For example, the cell in the last row and last column (i.e., in row B2--B- and column B4---) reports that if bidders BB4 all choose to join ad exchange, then the payoffs of bidders BB4 are 0, 0, 0., and 0., respectively. These four payoffs are computed as follows: Since all four bidders join ad exchange and this ad exchange chooses the CR policy, the four bidders bid their true valuations listed in Table C. If the impression is from publisher P3, then bidders B--B4 bid 0.8, 0,, 0, respectively. Thus, bidder wins the auction and pays 0.8. Therefore, the payoff of bidder is 0.8= 0.2. The payoff of each of the other three bidders is 0 because they do not win. Similarly, if the impression is from publisher P4, then the payoff of bidder B4 is 0.2 and the payoff of each of the other three bidders is 0. Since the probability that an impression is from either publisher P3 or P4 is 0.5, the expected payoffs of bidders and B4 are both 0.5 0.2+0.5 0=0., and the expected payoffs of bidders B and B2 are 0. A8 MIS Quarterly Vol. 40 No. 3 Appendices/September 206

Table C2. Game Between the Bidders in Scenario (The possible equilibria are highlighted in red) B4 Scenario : chooses CR Policy chooses CR Policy (0.5, 0.5, 0.5, 0.5) B (0., 0., 0, 0) (0., 0.5, 0.5, 0) (0.5, 0., 0, 0.5) Rev = 0 Rev = 0 B2 (0.4, 0., 0, 0.4) (0, 0.5, 0., 0.4) (0.4, 0., 0, 0.5) (0, 0.5, 0., 0.5) (0., 0.4, 0.4, 0) (0., 0.4, 0.5, 0.4) (0.5, 0, 0.4,0.) (0.5, 0, 0.5, 0.) B (0.4, 0.4, 0.4, 0.4) Rev = 0 Rev = 0 (0, 0.4, 0., 0.4) (0.4, 0, 0.4, 0.) (0, 0, 0., 0.) An entry in this payoff vector is underlined in Table C2 if it is the best response of the corresponding bidder, given the choices of which ad exchange to join by the other bidders. For example, consider the payoff vector (0.5, 0.,0, 0.5) corresponding to the choice of bidders B, B2, and to join ad exchange and bidder B4 to join ad exchange. Here, given the choice by bidders B2 and to join exchange and bidder B4 to join, the best response of Bidder B is to join exchange and her corresponding payoff is 0.5. Clearly, for a cell to correspond to an equilibrium, all four elements in its payoff vector should be underlined. There are two possible equilibria of the bidders under scenario : One is that bidders B and B2 join ad exchange and bidders and B4 join ad exchange. The other is that bidders B and B2 join ad exchange and bidders and B4 join ad exchange. The two equilibria are highlighted in red in Table C2. Based on the valuations of bidders in Table C, it is easy to verify that in both these equilibria, the revenue of each ad exchange will be zero. For example, for the case in which bidders B and B2 join ad exchange while bidders and B4 join ad exchange, ad exchange gets zero revenue because the second-highest bid in an auction of an impression from either publisher P or P2 is zero. The same calculation can be done for ad exchange. The revenues of ad exchanges and are reported in the table as Rev and Rev, respectively. The games between the bidders in scenarios 2 through 4 and the corresponding equilibria are reported in a similar fashion in TablesC3 through C5, respectively. Note that we assume that the probability that an impression sold by ad exchange (resp., ad exchange ) is from P or P2 (resp., P3 or P4) is 0.5. Thus, when an ad exchange hides the publisher identity from bidders, each bidder submits her average valuation as her bid in the auction. For example, from Table 3, Bidder has valuation toward the impressions from P3 and valuation 0 toward the impressions from P4. If ad exchange chooses CH policy, then Bidder will submit 0.5 as her bid. Similarly, under the condition that ad exchange chooses the CH policy, the valuations from bidders B, B2, and B4 are 0.4, 0.4, and 0.5, respectively. As an example, consider scenario 2 where ad exchange chooses the CR policy and ad exchange chooses the CH policy. If (say) all the bidders join ad exchange, then the bids from bidders BB4 are 0.4, 0.4, 0.5, and 0.5, respectively. Therefore, bidders and B4 have an equal chance (i.e., 50%) to win the auction and pay 0.5. The corresponding payoff of bidder and of bidder B4 is 50% [0.5 ( 0.5) + 0.5 (0 0.5)] = 0. The payoff of each of the other two bidders is 0, since they do not win. Therefore, the payoff vector in the last row and last column of Table C3 is (0,0,0,0). All potential equilibria for the bidders are highlighted in red in Tables C3 through C5; the corresponding revenues of the ad exchanges are also reported. For example, in Scenario 2, one possible equilibrium is that bidders B and B2 choose ad exchange while bidders and B4 choose ad exchange. The corresponding revenues of exchanges and are 0 and 0.5, respectively. Next, we analyze the first stage of the game, namely the game between the ad exchanges. Since there exist multiple equilibria under each scenario, we consider a few possibilities by choosing one possible equilibrium for each scenario. Possibility : In scenario, bidders B and B2 join ad exchange while bidders and B4 join ad exchange ; the corresponding revenues of ad exchanges and are 0 and 0, respectively. In scenario 2, bidders B and B2 join ad exchange while bidders and B4 join ad exchange ; the corresponding revenues of ad exchanges and are 0 and 0.5, respectively. In scenario 3, bidders B and B2 join ad exchange while bidders and B4 join ad exchange ; the corresponding revenues of ad exchanges and are 0.5 and 0, respectively. In scenario 4, bidders B and B4 join ad exchange while bidders B2 and join ad exchange ; the corresponding revenues of ad exchanges and are 0.4 and 0.4, respectively. The game between the two ad exchanges is described in Table C6. The unique equilibrium for the ad exchanges under this possibility is that both of them choose the CH policy. MIS Quarterly Vol. 40 No. 3 Appendices/September 206 A9

Table C3. Game Between the Bidders in Scenario 2 (The possible equilibria are highlighted in red) B2 Scenario 2: chooses CR Policy chooses CH Policy B B (0., 0., 0, 0) B4 (0., 0.5, 0.5, 0) (0.5, 0., 0, 0.5) (0.5, 0.5, 0, 0) Rev = 0.4 Rev = 0.4 Rev = 0 Rev = 0 Rev = 0 Rev = 0 (0.4, 0., 0, 0.4) (0, 0.5, 0., 0.4) (0, 0., 0, 0.) (0, 0.5, 0, 0) (0., 0.4, 0.4, 0) (0., 0, 0., 0) (0.5, 0, 0.4, 0.) (0.5, 0, 0, 0) (0, 0, 0.4, 0.4) (0, 0, 0., 0.4) (0, 0, 0.4, 0.) (0, 0, 0, 0) Table C4. Game Between the Bidders in Scenario 3 (The possible equilibria are highlighted in red) B4 Scenario 3: chooses CH Policy chooses CR Policy (0, 0, 0, 0) (0, 0, 0.5, 0) (0, 0, 0, 0.5) (0, 0, 0.5, 0.5) Rev = 0.5 B Rev = 0 (0, 0.5, 0., 0.5) B2 (0.4, 0., 0, 0) (0, 0., 0., 0) (0.4, 0., 0, 0.5) Rev = 0 Rev = 0.4 B (0.5, 0, 0.5, 0.) (0., 0.4, 0, 0) (0., 0.4, 0.5, 0) (0., 0, 0, 0.) Rev = 0 Rev = 0.4 (0.4, 0.4, 0, 0) (0, 0.4, 0., 0.4) (0.4, 0, 0.4, 0.) (0, 0, 0., 0.) Table C5 Game Between the Bidders in Scenario 4 (The possible equilibria are highlighted in red) B2 Scenario 4: chooses CH Policy chooses CH Policy B B (0, 0, 0, 0) (0.4, 0., 0, 0) (0., 0.4, 0, 0) B4 (0, 0, 0.5, 0) (0, 0, 0, 0.5) Rev = 0.5 Rev = 0.5 Rev = 0 Rev = 0 (0, 0., 0., 0) Rev = 0.4 Rev = 0.4 (0., 0, 0., 0) Rev = 0.4 Rev = 0.4 (0., 0, 0, 0.) Rev = 0.4 Rev = 0.4 (0., 0, 0, 0.) Rev = 0.4 Rev = 0.4 (0, 0, 0, 0) Rev = 0.5 Rev = 0.5 (0, 0.5, 0, 0) Rev = 0 Rev = 0.5 (0,5, 0, 0, 0) Rev = 0 Rev = 0.5 (0, 0, 0, 0) (0, 0, 0., 0.4) (0, 0, 0.4, 0.) (0, 0, 0, 0) Table C6. Game Between Ad Exchanges under Possibility (The equilibrium is highlighted in red) CR Policy CH Policy CR Policy (0,0) (0,0.5) CH Policy (0.5,0) (0.4, 0.4) A0 MIS Quarterly Vol. 40 No. 3 Appendices/September 206

Possibility 2: In scenario, bidders B and B2 join ad exchange while bidders and B4 join ad exchange ; the corresponding revenues of ad exchanges and are 0 and 0, respectively. In scenario 2, bidders B and B2 join ad exchange while bidders and B4 join ad exchange ; the corresponding revenues of ad exchanges and are 0 and 0.5, respectively. In scenario 3, bidders B join ad exchange while the other three bidders join ad exchange ; the corresponding revenues of ad exchanges and are 0 and 0.4, respectively. In scenario 4, bidders B join ad exchange while the other three bidders join ad exchange ; the corresponding revenues of ad exchanges and are 0 and 0.5, respectively. The game between the two ad exchanges is described in Table C7. There are two equilibria for the ad exchanges under this possibility: One is that both the ad exchanges choose the CH policy while the other is that ad exchange chooses the CR policy and ad exchange chooses the CH policy. Table C7. Game Between the Ad Exchanges under Possibility 2 (The possible equilibria are highlighted in red) CR Policy CH Policy CR Policy (0,0) (0,0.5) CH Policy (0,0.4) (0,0.5) Possibility 3: In scenario, bidders B and B2 join ad exchange while bidders and B4 join ad exchange ; the corresponding revenues of ad exchanges and are 0 and 0, respectively. In scenario 2, bidders B4 joins ad exchange while the other three bidders join ad exchange ; the corresponding revenues of ad exchanges and are 0.4 and 0, respectively. In scenario 3, bidders B join ad exchange while the other three bidders join ad exchange ; the corresponding revenues of ad exchanges and are 0 and 0.4, respectively. In scenario 4, bidders B join ad exchange while the other three bidders join ad exchange ; the corresponding revenues of ad exchanges and are 0 and 0.5, respectively. The game between the two ad exchanges is described in Table C8. There are two equilibria of the ad exchanges under this possibility: One is that both the ad exchanges choose the CR policy while the other is that ad exchange chooses the CR policy and ad exchange chooses the CH policy. Table C8. Game Between the Ad Exchanges under Possibility 3 (The possible equilibria are highlighted in red) CR Policy CH Policy CR Policy (0,0) (0.4,0) CH Policy (0,0.4) (0,0.5) As the above analysis shows, it is possible that either one of the ad exchanges or both of them choose to hide in equilibrium. This analysis also gives us a glimpse of the complexity involved in studying a more-general setting with an arbitrary number of competing ad exchanges and bidders, and continuous hide/reveal decisions. Note: With a more-careful choice of the valuations in Table C, it should be possible to ensure that each of the second-stage and first-stage games in the analysis above have unique equilibria. Since our goal is only to demonstrate the possibility of ad exchanges choosing to hide in equilibrium, the present analysis is sufficient for our purpose. MIS Quarterly Vol. 40 No. 3 Appendices/September 206 A