Marx s reproduction schemes and the Keynesian multiplier: a reply to Sardoni

Similar documents
Marx s Reproduction Schema and the Multisectoral Foundations of the Domar Growth Model

Eckhard Hein DISTRIBUTION AND GROWTH AFTER KEYNES A Post Keynesian Guide (Edward Elgar 2014)

WORKING PAPER SERIES. CEEAplA WP No. 05/2006. Teaching Keynes s Principle of Effective Demand and Chapter 19. Corrado Andini.

Working Paper No. 795

Eckhard Hein DISTRIBUTION AND GROWTH AFTER KEYNES A Post Keynesian Guide (Edward Elgar 2014) Chapter 1 Introduction

SCHOOL OF ACCOUNTING AND BUSINESS BSc. (APPLIED ACCOUNTING) GENERAL / SPECIAL DEGREE PROGRAMME YEAR II SEMESTER II END SEMESTER EXAMINATION APRIL 2015

TWO PRINCIPLES OF DEBT AND NATIONAL INCOME DYNAMICS IN A PURE CREDIT ECONOMY. Jan Toporowski

MARX, KEYNES, LEVY, KALECKI, STEINDL, MINSKY ON PROFIT. Jan Toporowski. School of Oriental & African Studies, University of London

4.3.1 The critique of the IS-LM representation of Keynes

Theory of the rate of return

Project Evaluation and the Folk Principle when the Private Sector Lacks Perfect Foresight

ECO 5116 POST-KEYNESIAN THEORY: VALUE AND PRODUCTION. Syllabus

Kalecki's Critique of Wicksellianism and the Miss-specification of Negative Interest Rates

Working Paper No. 807

Demand-Led Growth Theory: An Historical Approach

Keynesian Matters Source:

A REINTERPRETATION OF THE KEYNESIAN CONSUMPTION FUNCTION AND MULTIPLIER EFFECT

Kalecki s 1934 model VS. the IS-LM model of Hicks (1937) and Modigliani (1944)*

Gehrke: Macroeconomics Winter term 2012/13. Exercises

CITY UNIVERSITY LONDON. BSc (Honours) Degree in Actuarial Science BSc (Honours) Degree in Insurance and Investment. Part I Examination

Simple Notes on the ISLM Model (The Mundell-Fleming Model)

Is demand for money the same as demand for liquidity?

The Goods Market and the Aggregate Expenditures Model

y = f(n) Production function (1) c = c(y) Consumption function (5) i = i(r) Investment function (6) = L(y, r) Money demand function (7)

Demand-Led Growth Theory in a Classical Framework: Its Superiority, Its Limitations, and Its Explanatory Power

Fiscal stimulus : A loanable funds critique. Author. Published. Journal Title. Copyright Statement. Downloaded from. Link to published version

NOTES AND COMMENTS A note on the organic composition of capital and profit rates

This is IS-LM, chapter 21 from the book Finance, Banking, and Money (index.html) (v. 1.1).

The text was adapted by The Saylor Foundation under the CC BY-NC-SA without attribution as requested by the works original creator or licensee

Economics 1012A: Introduction to Macroeconomics FALL 2007 Dr. R. E. Mueller Third Midterm Examination November 15, 2007

Principles of Macroeconomics December 17th, 2005 name: Final Exam (100 points)

Come and join us at WebLyceum

This is IS-LM, chapter 21 from the book Finance, Banking, and Money (index.html) (v. 2.0).

Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics

Introduction The Story of Macroeconomics. September 2011

The Impact of an Increase In The Money Supply and Government Spending In The UK Economy

PART ONE INTRODUCTION

Macroeconomics: Principles, Applications, and Tools

FEEDBACK TUTORIAL LETTER

Please choose the most correct answer. You can choose only ONE answer for every question.

Classical and Keynesian Economics

EXCESSIVE LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE. Prabhat Patnaik

FALLACY OF THE MULTIPLIER EFFECT: CORRECTING THE INCOME ANALYSIS

From The Collected Works of Milton Friedman, compiled and edited by Robert Leeson and Charles G. Palm.

Convergence towards the normal rate of capacity utilization in Kaleckian models: The role of non-capacity autonomous expenditures.

Discrete models in microeconomics and difference equations

Chapter 4 Monetary and Fiscal. Framework

Models of Money Demand & Theories of Interest Rate Determination International Monetary Economics, Lecture 7

Aggregate Demand, Aggregate Supply, and the Self-Correcting Economy

Module 31. Monetary Policy and the Interest Rate. What you will learn in this Module:

Price stability means that the general price level in an economy increases at a low, stable and expected rate. [1]

Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output. The Core of Macroeconomic Theory. Aggregate Output and Aggregate Income (Y)

Economics II/Intermediate Macroeconomics (No. 5025) Prof. Dr. Gerhard Schwödiauer/ Prof. Dr. Joachim Weimann. Semester: Summer Semester 2003

Economic Importance of Keynesian and Neoclassical Economic Theories to Development

Part I (45 points; Mark your answers in a SCANTRON)

Chapter 1: Economics: The Core Issues - WHAT IS THIS CHAPTER ALL ABOUT?

Aggregate demand, income distribution and unemployment. Malcolm Sawyer University of Leeds

2015 EXAMINATIONS ECONOMICS - MSS J133 JOINT UNIVERSITIES PRELIMINARY EXAMINATIONS BOARD MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS

Archimedean Upper Conservatory Economics, November 2016 Quiz, Unit VI, Stabilization Policies

The Core of Macroeconomic Theory

Monetary Business Cycles. Introduction: The New Keynesian Model in the context of Macro Theory

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 11. Classical and Keynesian Macro Analyses

What is Macroeconomics?

The Short-Run: IS/LM

The economic situation in a wide range of economies in the wake of the crisis that began

International Monetary Policy

Name: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory II, Fall 2008 Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko Problem Set 2 (53 points). Due Friday, November 14

NATIONAL ACCOUNTS DATA AND MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS: A COMPARATIVE STUDY OF THE CZECH REPUBLIC, GERMANY, GREECE, IRELAND AND SLOVENIA

ECONOMICS EXAMINATION OBJECTIVES

Macroeconomics. Based on the textbook by Karlin and Soskice: Macroeconomics: Institutions, Instability, and the Financial System

Test Questions. Part I Midterm Questions 1. Give three examples of a stock variable and three examples of a flow variable.

The Great Depression

Capacity Utilization, Inflation and Monetary Policy: Marxian models and the New Keynesian Consensus

Chapter 15: Fiscal Policy Section 2

ECONOMICS. of Macroeconomic. Paper 4: Basic Macroeconomics Module 1: Introduction: Issues studied in Macroeconomics, Schools of Macroeconomic

Matthew 0. Shapiro. Working Paper No. 2146

Advanced Macroeconomics 6. Rational Expectations and Consumption

Model Question Paper Economics - II (MSF1A4)

The Trouble with Harrod: the fundamental instability of the warranted rate in the light of the Sraffian Supermultiplier

Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment

ECON 3010 Intermediate Macroeconomics Final Exam

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

1 of 15 12/1/2013 1:28 PM

Chapter 12 Keynesian Models and the Phillips Curve

ECONOMICS B.A. part 1 M.M.100 Paper I MICRO ECONOMICS Unit I 1.Consumer s Behaviour : The Neo Classical Marginal Utility approach and a study of

ECON 314: MACROECONOMICS II CONSUMPTION AND CONSUMER EXPENDITURE

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls UNIVERSITY OF LONDON

Chapter 22: Division of Profit. Rate of Interest. Natural Rate of Interest

Chapter 4. Determination of Income and Employment 4.1 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND ITS COMPONENTS

TWO VIEWS OF THE ECONOMY

Lecture 13: The Great Depression

INDIAN HILL EXEMPTED VILLAGE SCHOOL DISTRICT Social Studies Curriculum - May 2009 AP Economics

INTRODUCTORY ECONOMICS

Multiplier and Accelerator (Determination of National Income Continued)

VII. Short-Run Economic Fluctuations

Volume 29, Issue 1. Juha Tervala University of Helsinki

The Aggregate Expenditures Model. A continuing look at Macroeconomics

The Causes of Unemployment in the UK in 1994.

III. 9. IS LM: the basic framework to understand macro policy continued Text, ch 11

Economics II/Intermediate Macroeconomics (No. 5025) Prof. Dr. Gerhard Schwödiauer/ Prof. Dr. Joachim Weimann. Semester: Winter Semester 2002/03

Transcription:

Cambridge Journal of Economics 2010, 34, 591 595 doi:10.1093/cje/beq003 Advance Access publication 16 February 2010 Marx s reproduction schemes and the Keynesian multiplier: a reply to Sardoni Andrew B. Trigg and Jochen Hartwig* In a recent contribution to this journal, C. Sardoni takes issue with the identification by Trigg, in a 2006 publication, of a role for the Keynesian investment multiplier in Marx s schemes of reproduction. Indirectly, Sardoni also expresses his disagreement with Hartwig (by attributing one of his statements to Trigg). We appreciate the opportunity to defend our view against Sardoni s critique. This reply shows that a bridging point between Marx and Keynes can be established without recourse to microfoundations. As suggested by both Trigg, in 2006, and Hartwig, in 2004, the well known Harrod Domar model of economic growth provides an interpretation of Marx s reproduction schemes that has the Keynesian multiplier as a constituent element. This note will further explore the assumptions underlying the interface between Marx and Keynes, in response to the challenging questions raised in Sardoni s contribution. Key words: Marxian reproduction schemes, Keynesian multiplier, Harrod Domar model JEL classifications: E11, E12 1. Introduction C. Sardoni (2009, p. 162) is convinced that it is impossible to use the Keynesian multiplier within the Marxian schemes because of the way microfoundations are defined by Marx and Keynes. For Sardoni, a bridging point between Marx and Keynes requires particular assumptions about how competition and the short-run supply curve are defined. We counter this argument in three stages. First, from a long-run macroeconomic perspective, we show how the Keynesian multiplier is nested in the Harrod Domar interpretation of Marx s reproduction schemes. Second, we turn to the short-run multiplier developed by Keynes, and how this relates to the reproduction schemes. In the final part of this reply we discuss the role of microfoundations in this Marx Keynes interface. 2. Harrod Domar and the reproduction schemes Sardoni (2009, p. 166) derives a Keynesian multiplier (see his equation 8) from a multisectoral model of Marx s reproduction schemes: Y 5 1 s I ð1þ * The Open University, UK and the Swiss Economic Institute at ETH Zurich, Switzerland. Ó The Author 2010. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the Cambridge Political Economy Society. All rights reserved.

592 A. B. Trigg and J. Hartwig where Y is money income, I is gross investment, and s is the propensity to save. This multiplier is quite similar (Sardoni, 2009, p. 169) to that derived from Marx s schemes in Trigg (2006), the difference being that an average is taken of the consumption and savings of workers and capitalists. Hence there appears to be no substantive disagreement that a Keynesian multiplier can be derived from Marx s schemes; the argument is about how such a multiplier is applied. Following Domar, it is possible to use this multiplier to derive a Keynesian model of macroeconomic growth (see Trigg, 2006, pp. 55 6). If we let s represent the productivity of investment, and from (1) let it can follow that s 5 dy I dy 5 1 s di dy Y 5 di I 5 ss Under the assumption of full capacity utilisation, this can be defined as a full employment balanced rate of growth, derived from Marx s reproduction schemes. On this basis, Marx has been described as the forerunner of macroeconomics, showing the conditions under which balanced growth can be established in a multi-sectoral framework. Now this bridging point between Marx and Keynes can be derived without Sardoni s recourse to microfoundations. The model does not make any assumption about free competition. The reproduction schemes in Capital, Volume II, as an initial abstract starting point, are based on the assumption that prices are proportional to values. In both Marx s schemes and the Domar interpretation, there is no consideration of free competition and the tendency to uniform profitability that this would entail. Sardoni may object to the assumption of full capacity utilisation in the Domar model, since his main objective is to establish an underemployment equilibrium that resembles the short-run model developed by Keynes. No claim has been made, however, that the model developed in Trigg (2006) is a model of Keynes; it is a model of Marx s reproduction schemes that incorporates a Keynesian multiplier. Nor is there any claim that this is a model of actual economic growth. The objective for Marx, and Domar, is to develop a benchmark that explores the difficult and extreme conditions required for balanced growth to be achieved. It is more concerned with how an economy ought to grow rather than how it actually grows (see Hartwig, 2004, p. 321). With an exclusive focus on the search for more realistic microfoundations, Sardoni detracts from the main point of Marx s macroeconomic contribution. ð2þ ð3þ ð4þ 3. Keynes s structural multiplier Thus far we have referred to this multiplier as Keynesian but, following Hartwig (2004), we may take the argument one step further by exploring its resemblance to the structural multiplier identified in Keynes s General Theory. Writing at the time of the Great

A reply to Sardoni 593 Depression in the 1930s, a defining feature of Keynes s revolutionary approach to economic theory is his emphasis on the importance of production for generating employment. Production is disaggregated into two industries, producing capital goods and consumption goods. In Section IV, chapter 10, the multiplier is developed in relation to this two-sector production model: The discussion has been carried on, so far, on the basis of a change in aggregate investment which has been foreseen sufficiently in advance for the consumption-goods industries to advance pari passu with the capital-goods industries... (Keynes, 1973, p. 122) Firms in the consumption goods industries are able to anticipate the expansion of the capital goods sector correctly. Proportionality is hence assumed between the two industries, as reflected in Keynes s structural multiplier, which can now be derived. Since Y 5 C 1 I, with C representing total consumption expenditures, the Keynesian multiplier (1) can be re-expressed as C 1 I 5 1 s I Hence, since s 5 1 c, where c is the propensity to consume, C 5 c 1 2 c I ð6þ The structural multiplier c=12c provides a vehicle for firms in the consumption goods industries (producing C) to anticipate how much demand for consumption goods a certain value added in the investment goods industries (I) correctly foreseen will generate. Now although this multiplier is established for one (short-run) production period in which there is excess capacity, it anticipates the output of capital goods in the next production period, and the capacity generated by these goods. The short-run model points towards its development into a long-run model of proportional economic growth, as developed from Keynes s starting point by Harrod and Domar. 1 There is, therefore, a bridging point between Keynes s short-run structural multiplier and Marx s reproduction schemes. 4. Microfoundations For Sardoni, it is necessary to specify particular microfoundations for a bridging point between Marx and Keynes to be established. He argues that the microfoundations advocated by Marx and Keynes are either too far apart or too close to each other. On the one hand, Marx and Keynes differ in their assumptions about the slope of the supply curve. Keynes, being a Marshallian, assumes increasing marginal cost and hence an upwardsloped supply curve; Marx assumes constant variable costs. 2 On the other hand they both assume competitive markets in which firms are price-takers. Hence, since Marx assumes constant returns and free competition there cannot be an underemployment equilibrium. Firms maximise their profits to produce as much as they can. With production pushed to full capacity, there can be no room for the multiplier. The multiplier only has a role to play ð5þ 1 Hartwig (2004, p. 322) shows how the structural multiplier is embodied in the growth model developed by Harrod (1939); this multiplier is related to the alternative Domar variant in Trigg (2006), pp. 15 16, 55 6. 2 Although Sardoni admits that Marx never made a clear and explicit hypothesis of short-period nondecreasing returns (Sardoni, 2009, p. 166, fn. 2), he attributes exactly this hypothesis to Marx.

594 A. B. Trigg and J. Hartwig in the underemployment equilibrium established by Keynes under decreasing returns and perfect competition or alternatively for Sardoni under more realistic assumptions of constant returns and imperfect competition, as proposed by Kalecki. We take issue with Sardoni s notion of competition and price-taking, as well as with his conclusion that underemployment equilibria are impossible in Marx. Sardoni (2009) does not explain in detail what he associates with the terms free and imperfect competition, so we draw on his 1987 book. There, he attributes the notion of free competition to Marx and explains what this entails: many relatively small firms unable to influence the price at which commodities are sold and no barriers or obstacles to the entry of new firms in any industry (Sardoni, 1987, p. 44). To Keynes he attributes the concept of perfect competition (Sardoni, 1987, p. 102, n. 3). This, Sardoni explains, means that the demand for the output of an individual firm is perfectly elastic. If we ask what the differences are between free and perfect competition, Sardoni (1987, p. 116) tells us there are not really any because free competition also entails perfectly elastic demand curves. Sardoni (1987, pp. 121 2) contrasts the imperfect competition assumption of Kalecki with Marx and Keynes who assumed that the prevailing market form was competition. Now, contrary to Sardoni, it can be argued that neither Keynes nor Marx assumed that firms face perfectly elastic demand. In fact, to suggest that Keynes and Marx did assume perfectly elastic demand would contradict the idea that entrepreneurs have to plan their supply quantities under uncertainty before bringing them to the market. For Sardoni, the nexus between money and uncertainty established by Keynes is the ultimate reason for his critique of Say s Law. With money being a means to cope with uncertainty, money income need not be spent on either consumption or investment goods. Therefore, entrepreneurs have to form ex ante expectations about the level of demand. They will not produce more than they expect will be demanded. The resulting output level need not imply full employment of labour. Sardoni (1987, p. 3) presents Marx as a forerunner of Keynes in this regard. But, as is well known, when demand is perfectly elastic, entrepreneurs will expect to sell any amount of goods at a given price. They do not need to estimate the state of demand ex ante. Therefore, as Casarosa (1981, p. 192) argued, the idea of entrepreneurs forming ex ante expectations concerning demand is completely incompatible with the theory of the firm operating in an atomistic (let alone perfectly competitive) market. But neither Keynes nor Marx who were both concerned with the real world (we agree with Sardoni, 1987, pp. 131 43, on that) had such firms in mind. In their theories, firms are not atomistic, but also not powerful enough to dictate the price. They have to form expectations about the price for their products that the market will accept, and about the market share that might be attributable to them (cf. also Torr, 1984, p. 939). Chick (1983, pp. 24 6) points out that price-taking is impossible, even for the small firm, under uncertainty. In Chick (1992) she proposes an approach in which small firms are modelled without price-taking. This resembles Kahn s (1989, pp. 12 13) notion of polypoly, where there are many small firms in a market, but differences in market price may nevertheless persist over an appreciable period of time. Now what does this mean for Sardoni s critique of our attempts to reconcile the multiplier with Marx s reproduction schemes? Sardoni s conclusion that firms always produce up to capacity in Marx was based on the assumptions of perfectly elastic demand and price-taking. If we drop these assumptions there is ample scope for underemployment equilibria, further undermining the possibility that the actual economy can achieve the Marx Domar full employment growth path.

It might also be suggested that the notion of underemployment equilibrium in Sardoni needs clarification. According to Sardoni, Marx s theory implies that firms tend to produce at full capacity. Episodes of production at full capacity are abruptly brought to an end by recurrent overproduction crises. It lies in the nature of a crisis, however, that it is not permanent. Therefore, in Sardoni s view, Marx presents something of a business cycle theory. Keynes, on the other hand, presents an equilibrium theory: he derives a centre of gravitation (Sardoni, 1987, p. 9), which is characterised by unemployment. In our view, this juxtaposition is artificial. In the General Theory, Keynes acknowledges that his equilibrium is shifting (Keynes, 1973, p. 293). He has a whole chapter (chapter 22) on the business cycle. Marx, on the other hand, introduces the notion of the reserve army of the unemployed ; and Sardoni (2009, p. 166) admits that production at full capacity does not imply full employment. So both Marx and Keynes saw the economy departing from centres of attraction that involve unemployment. Where is the big difference? Does Sardoni think that the centre of attraction comes along with full utilisation of technical capacities in Marx but not in Keynes? Sardoni (1987, p. 54) seems to confirm this conjecture, but we were unable to find an elaboration in Sardoni of why Keynes should have thought that entrepreneurs systematically build up excess capacities. Rather, it seems reasonable to assume that for both Keynes and Marx firms operate at normal capacity utilisation, on average, over good and bad times. 1 This is not the same as full capacity utilisation. So, again, there is scope for multiplier reactions in the interface between Marx and Keynes. Bibliography A reply to Sardoni 595 Casarosa, C. 1981. The microfoundations of Keynes s aggregate supply and expected demand analysis, Economic Journal, vol. 91, 188 94 Chick, V. 1983. Macroeconomics after Keynes: a Reconsideration of the General Theory, Oxford, Philip Allan Chick, V. 1992. The small firm under uncertainty: a puzzle of the General Theory, pp. 149 64 in Gerrard, B. and Hillard, J. (eds), The Philosophy and Economics of J.M. Keynes, Aldershot, Edward Elgar Garegnani, P. 1992. Some notes for an analysis of accumulation, pp. 47 71 in Halevi, J., Laibman, D. and Nell, E. J. (eds), Beyond the Steady State: a Revival of Growth Theory, New York, St Martin s Press Harrod, R. F. 1939. An essay in dynamic theory, Economic Journal, vol. 59, 537 55 Hartwig, J. 2004. Keynes s multiplier in a two-sectoral framework, Review of Political Economy, vol. 16, 309 34 Kahn, R. 1989 [1929]. The Economics of the Short Period, Houndsmills, Macmillan Keynes, J. M. 1973 [1936]. The General Theory of Employment Interest and Money, London, Macmillan Kurz, H. 1990A. Capital, Distribution and Effective Demand, Cambridge, UK, Cambridge University Press Kurz, H. 1990B. Accumulation, distribution and the Keynesian hypothesis, pp. 396 413 in Baradwaj, K. and Schefold, B. (eds), Essays on Piero Sraffa, London, Unwin Hyman Sardoni, C. 1987. Marx and Keynes on Economic Recession, Brighton, Wheatsheaf Books Sardoni, C. 2009. The Marxian schemes of reproduction and the theory of effective demand, Cambridge Journal of Economics, vol. 33, 161 73 Torr, C. 1984. The microfoundations of Keynes s aggregate supply and expected demand analysis: a comment, Economic Journal, vol. 94, 936 40 Trigg, A. B. 2006. Marxian Reproduction Schema, London and New York, Routledge 1 Kurz (1990A, 1990B) and Garegnani (1992) in fact argue that this was Marx s assumption.