Asset specificity and holdups. Benjamin Klein 1

Similar documents
Incomplete Contracts and Ownership: Some New Thoughts. Oliver Hart and John Moore*

Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

OWNERSHIP AND RESIDUAL RIGHTS OF CONTROL Ownership is usually considered the best way to incentivize economic agents:

Non-Legal Sanctions and Strategic Alliances: The Use of the Marriage Contract as a Model for Strategic Alliances

The Fundamental Transformation Reconsidered: Dixit vs. Williamson

Long-Term Contracts and Asset Specificity Revisited An Empirical Analysis of Producer-Importer Relations in the Natural Gas Industry

Definition of Incomplete Contracts

Up-front payment under RD rule

The inadequacy of specificity and role of importance in explaining hold-up

Rethinking Incomplete Contracts

Chapter 9 Topics in the Economics of Contract Law

Contracts in Natural Resources: What Does Contract Theory Tell Us?

Short-term, Long-term, and Continuing Contracts

Endogenous Transaction Cost, Specialization, and Strategic Alliance

Prof. Bryan Caplan Econ 812

Long-Term Contracts for Natural Gas - An Empirical Analysis. Anne Neumann and Christian von Hirschhausen

Microeconomics II Lecture 8: Bargaining + Theory of the Firm 1 Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics December 2016

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1

Entry Barriers. Özlem Bedre-Defolie. July 6, European School of Management and Technology

Holdup with Subsidized Investment

Some Puzzles. Stock Splits

What we know about monetary policy

Why Monetary Policy Matters: A Canadian Perspective

ECON DISCUSSION NOTES ON CONTRACT LAW. Contracts. I.1 Bargain Theory. I.2 Damages Part 1. I.3 Reliance

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5. Property Rights Theory. The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights?

Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment

Monopoly Power with a Short Selling Constraint

Formal Contracts, Relational Contracts, and the Holdup Problem

Exclusive contracts and protection of investments

Reasons for Not Extending the Contract Abrogation Provision of S. 615 to Contracts for Sales by Producers to End Users

CAN BLOCKCHAIN SOLVE THE HOLD-UP PROBLEM? RICHARD HOLDEN AND ANUP MALANI UNSW AND UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE SOCIAL VERSUS THE PRIVATE INCENTIVE TO BRING SUIT IN A COSTLY LEGAL SYSTEM. Steven Shavell. Working Paper No.

Beyond the Coasian Irrelevance: Externalities

Classification of Contracts under International Financial Reporting Standards IFRS [2005]

Holdup: Investment Dynamics, Bargaining and Gradualism

Chapter 3 Domestic Money Markets, Interest Rates and the Price Level

Recall: The Meaning of Money and Inflation. Money Growth and Inflation 1. HISTORICAL ASPECTS OF INFLATION. Key points

Defined contribution retirement plan design and the role of the employer default

y = f(n) Production function (1) c = c(y) Consumption function (5) i = i(r) Investment function (6) = L(y, r) Money demand function (7)

2. 4. Market failures and the rationale for public intervention (Stiglitz ch.4, 7, 8; Gruber ch.5,6,7, Rosen 5,6)

The Market for Lemons": A Lesson for Dividend Investors

Advanced Risk Management

Relational Contracts and the Theory of the Firm: A Renegotiation-Proof Approach

Revenue for power and utilities companies

Refelecting on the Fair Value Under IFRS for SMEs: Challenges and Perspectives

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

Exploring the Effect of Wealth Distribution on Efficiency Using a Model of Land Tenancy with Limited Liability. Nicholas Reynolds

University of New South Wales School of Economics

Journal of Central Banking Theory and Practice, 2017, 1, pp Received: 6 August 2016; accepted: 10 October 2016

EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK

Using Trade Policy to Influence Firm Location. This Version: 9 May 2006 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE DO NOT CITE

Finance: Risk Management

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Comment Does the economics of moral hazard need to be revisited? A comment on the paper by John Nyman

Rent Shifting and the Order of Negotiations

Theory of the firm transactions costs

Comments on Michael Woodford, Globalization and Monetary Control

Optimal Contract Design with Unilateral Market Option

Trade Agreements and the Nature of Price Determination

Does Retailer Power Lead to Exclusion?

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Business Combinations: Applying the Acquisition Method Board Meeting Handout. July 19, 2006

ECON 4245 ECONOMICS OF THE FIRM

Relational Contracts and the Value of Loyalty

JOURNAL OF PUBLIC PROCUREMENT, VOLUME 8, ISSUE 3,

ECON DISCUSSION NOTES ON CONTRACT LAW-PART 2. Contracts. I.1 Investment in Performance

1 The empirical relationship and its demise (?)

Theory. 2.1 One Country Background

A Taxonomy of the Modern Corporation

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation

A Theory of Joint Ownership

Foreign direct investment and export under imperfectly competitive host-country input market

The role of dynamic renegotiation and asymmetric information in financial contracting

The role of the employer default allocation in defined-contribution retirement plan design

Interchange Fees in Various Countries: Commentary on Weiner and Wright

Essays on Herd Behavior Theory and Criticisms

Chapter 7 The Stock Market, the Theory of Rational Expectations, and the Efficient Markets Hypothesis

Macroeconomics. Introduction to Economic Fluctuations. Zoltán Bartha, PhD Associate Professor. Andrea S. Gubik, PhD Associate Professor

Testing for Stock Market Overvaluation/ Undervaluation

THE CODING OF OUTCOMES IN TAXPAYERS REPORTING DECISIONS. A. Schepanski The University of Iowa

SYLLABUS: AGEC AGRICULTURAL FINANCE

STUDENTSFOCUS.COM BA ECONOMIC ANALYSIS FOR BUSINESS

(the centralized contractual agent) (Alchian & Demsetz,1972), (Alchian & Woodward,1987),

The Navigator. September 2016 Issue 9. Variable Annuities. A Financial Planning Resource from Pekin Singer Strauss Asset Management

2. 4. Market failures and the rationale for public intervention (Stiglitz ch.4, 7, 8; Gruber ch.5,6,7, Rosen 5,6)

Maximizing the value of the firm is the goal of managing capital structure.

The Auditor s Responsibility to Consider Fraud in an Audit of Financial Statements

Optimal Contract Design with Unilateral Market Option

CDM Transactions: A Review of Options

Discussion of the Evans Paper

FREE TRADE AND PROTECTIONISM BENONI DIMULESCU

Game Theory Analysis on Accounts Receivable Financing of Supply Chain Financing System

1. The Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH)

2. 4. Market failures and the rationale for public intervention (Stiglitz ch.4, 7, 8; Gruber ch.5,6,7, Rosen 5,6)

Objectives for Chapter 24: Monetarism (Continued) Chapter 24: The Basic Theory of Monetarism (Continued) (latest revision October 2004)

Breach remedies, reliance and renegotiation

ALI-ABA Course of Study Regulation D Offerings and Private Placements Highlights June 27, 2008,

Rural Financial Intermediaries

Chapter 6 Firms: Labor Demand, Investment Demand, and Aggregate Supply

Transcription:

Asset specificity and holdups Benjamin Klein 1 Specific assets are assets that have a significantly higher value within a particular transacting relationship than outside the relationship. To illustrate, consider the classic Fisher Body-General Motors case. 2 In 1919 Fisher Body undertook a very large expansion in its capacity to supply bodies to General Motors. Automobile bodies, like many other productive inputs, are not sold in a spot market. Therefore, if General Motors decided to stop purchasing from Fisher after Fisher Body made its capacity investments, the Fisher capacity used to produce bodies for General Motors could not immediately and costlessly be transferred to the production and sale of bodies to other automobile companies. Consequently, once Fisher Body made the investment, the plants Fisher built to supply General Motors had a higher value within the G.M. relationship than outside the G.M. relationship. The difference in value within and outside the General Motors relationship is equal to the G.M.-specific element of the assets. 3 The economic relevance of specific assets is that they create the potential for holdups. Once a transactor makes a relationship-specific investment, its transacting partner has the ability to take advantage of the specificity to appropriate some of the rents the transactor expects to earn on the investment. For example, after Fisher Body made its somewhat G.M.-specific capacity investments General Motors could threaten to stop purchasing bodies from Fisher and impose a capital cost on Fisher Body equal to the value of the G.M.-specific element of Fisher s capacity investments. Therefore, General Motors could, in principle, negotiate to obtain part (often assumed in theoretical models to be half) of the value of Fisher s G.M.-specific assets, either by demanding a lump-sum payment or a reduction in future body prices. Consequently, because transactors expect that they may lose a share of the return on their specific investments when a holdup occurs, one of the economic costs associated with holdups involves the reduced incentive of transactors to make efficient relationship-specific investments. These costs, however, are reduced because transactors, aware of the risks associated with specific investments, design contractual arrangements that avoid the likelihood of holdups. Asset specificity and the associated holdup potential, therefore, is an important economic determinant of contractual arrangements.

Contractual Solutions to Potential Holdups When transactors plan to make significant relationship-specific investments they often adopt explicit contract terms that, in combination with transactor reputational capital, reduces the ability and economic incentive for transactors to engage in a holdup. This use of a contractual arrangement to control the holdup potential associated with specific investments is illustrated by the Fisher Body-General Motors case, where a long-term contract was used to control the anticipated potential holdup problems. In particular, before Fisher made its G.M.-specific capacity investments, General Motors contracted to purchase all its closed auto bodies from Fisher Body over the next ten years. By making this long-term exclusive dealing commitment General Motors gave up the ability to hold up Fisher Body since General Motors could no longer threaten to switch its purchases to another body manufacturer. The contract therefore protected Fisher Body s large G.M.-specific investments. 4 Of course, General Motors would not make such an exclusive purchase commitment without also receiving contractual price protection. In the absence of price protection Fisher Body could take advantage of the long-term General Motors exclusive commitment to raise body prices without worrying about General Motors switching its purchases to another supplier. The exclusive contract therefore included provisions whereby the price of bodies was set on a cost-plus basis that permitted Fisher Body to earn a normal rate of return on its capital investments in plant and equipment required to supply bodies to General Motors. 5 Contractual solutions to holdup problems may include other ways to control long-term prices, with or without the presence of exclusive dealing, such as most-favored customer clauses or indexing to independently published price indices where appropriate. But these and other contractual devices designed to prevent holdup problems are inherently incomplete, in the sense that contracts do not accurately cover every possible future contingency or fully define all aspects of transactor performance in a court-enforceable way. Consequently, there may be significant contract negotiation costs associated with the presence of relationship-specific investments, as transactors attempt to negotiate advantageous contract terms that both reduce the probability they will be held up and increase the probability they will be able to take advantage of imperfect contract terms to engage in a hold up. In addition, transactors recognize that when they make specific investments and enter imperfect contracts they may bear rent-dissipating economic costs during a transitional contract renegotiation process when ex post conditions that are not covered by the contractual arrangement develop and a holdup occurs.

Ex Post Contractual Problems Because real world contracts are inherently imperfect, there is a possibility in all contractual arrangements that a transactor will be able to take advantage of the agreed upon contract to appropriate some of the return on its transacting partner s relationship-specific investments. When this occurs the imperfect long-term contract terms used to solve potential holdup problems in the face of specific investments may actually induce holdups. This is vividly illustrated by the changes that occurred over time in the Fisher Body-General Motors contractual relationship. In particular, the Fisher Body-General Motors contract did not cover the unexpected contingency that arose in 1922 when General Motors asked Fisher Body to build smaller body-producing plants co-located with General Motors assembly plants. Fisher resisted General Motors demand for co-located body plants and used this development to negotiate a highly favorable adjustment in the contractual arrangement, whereby General Motors made half of Fisher Body s required additional capital investments. This resulted, under the unchanged cost-plus body pricing formula originally designed to provide Fisher Body with a competitive return on its capital investments, in a large wealth transfer from General Motors to Fisher Body. General Motors had little choice because it was operating under a long-term exclusive dealing contract, and therefore could not switch its purchases of bodies to an alternative supplier. Consequently, the exclusive dealing contract designed to protect Fisher Body s original General Motors-specific capacity investments against a holdup threat by General Motors created conditions whereby Fisher Body held up General Motors. The Fisher Body-General Motors case demonstrates, however, that there are economic reasons to expect that a holdup, if it occurs, may not involve very significant rent-dissipating costs. Although Fisher Body clearly conveyed to General Motors in 1922 its reluctance to make efficient co-located plant investments, all the new Fisher Body plants built during 1922-24 were co-located with General Motors assembly facilities (Coase, 2000). However, this does not mean that Fisher Body did not engage in a holdup during this period. One must distinguish between how a transactor may threaten to hold up its transacting partner (Fisher refusing to make co-located plant investments) and how a holdup is actually accomplished (Fisher negotiating a highly favorable contract adjustment in return for agreeing to make the co-located plant investments). If contract rights are clearly specified and transaction costs are low, as they generally will be with only two transactors who have similar information, we would expect a negotiated solution to be reached and contract terms adjusted to the new, post-holdup equilibrium in a way that minimizes rent-dissipating transitional economic inefficiencies. Therefore, it is not surprising that the holdup

was accomplished in the Fisher Body-General Motors case without an inefficient increase in transportation and other costs from mislocated plants. Instead, the holdup was accomplished by Fisher Body renegotiating the contract so that General Motors made a significant part of the required new plant investments. This decreased Fisher Body s capital relative to its sales and, under the pricing terms of the contract, increased Fisher s profitability and G.M. s cost of bodies while avoiding any inefficiencies. In this way the total pie continued to be maximized while Fisher Body s share of the pie increased. 6 However, in contrast to the rapid contractual adjustment made by Fisher Body and General Motors in 1922, a contractual impasse between Fisher Body and General Motors persisted during 1925-26 over the terms of a new adjusted Fisher Body-General Motors relationship and a required new Buick body plant investment in Flint. This resulted in transitional inefficiencies, as Fisher Body continued to supply Buick bodies from Detroit rather than from the more efficient proposed Flint location. These difficulties arose because General Motors also was negotiating to acquire the remaining 40 percent interest of Fisher Body it did not already own. General Motors firmly believed that these acquisition terms should not reflect the increased profit Fisher Body had been earning since 1922 on the renegotiated General Motors body supply contract. In 1926 General Motors, in fact, successfully concluded these negotiations on terms that did not provide Fisher Body any continuing financial return for its past holdup (Klein, 2007, pp. 20 22). Increased General Motors control associated with vertical integration also largely eliminated the possibility of any future Fisher Body holdup. The economic benefit of increased control achieved by General Motors with vertical integration entailed the economic cost of a reduced Fisher profit incentive. It is this reduction in economic incentives associated with vertical integration that presumably explains why General Motors and Fisher Body did not adopt a full vertical integration-type of contractual arrangement in 1919 when they initially entered their relationship. They expected the particular long-term, fixed price formula, exclusive dealing contractual arrangement they designed could handle holdup problems while also preserving increased Fisher Body economic incentives. However, the analysis of the Fisher Body-General Motors case illustrates that because long-term contracts may create, as well as solve, potential holdup problems, vertical integration sometimes is the contractual arrangement that prevents potential holdup problems most cheaply. Integration avoids the difficulties that were created with the imperfect long-term, fixed-price-formula body supply contract. In fact, integration eliminated the need for any automobile body supply contract. Rather than attempt to specify

performance contractually, General Motors, as the employer/owner of Fisher Body, could now more flexibly organize production since it possessed the legal power to unilaterally make important investment and management decisions. And these control benefits associated with vertical integration at this point in time outweighed the costs of reduced Fisher incentives. 7 Why Does a Holdup Occur? Some economists are skeptical regarding the economic importance of asset specificity and associated holdups as a determinate of vertical integration. For example, Coase claims that the incentive for opportunistic behavior is usually checked by the need to take account of the effect on future business and that there are contractual devices that could be used to handle the problem (Coase, 2006). Transactors do employ their reputational capital and contract terms to design contractual arrangements whereby holdups are avoided. In fact, the exclusive dealing contractual arrangement initially adopted by Fisher Body and General Motors can be explained in terms of these two economic forces. However, the fact that holdup problems are usually successfully handled with a combination of contract terms and transactor reputations does not mean that holdups never occur. Because contract terms are inherently imperfect and transactor reputational capital is limited, transactors know when they design their contractual arrangements that there is some probability that they may be placed in a position where unanticipated events push the contractual relationship outside what I have called the self-enforcing range and that a holdup will occur (Klein, 1996). 8 This probabilistic view of hold-ups should be contrasted with the view that a holdup involves deceptive or fraudulent behavior. Coase, for example, claims that [o]pportunism is analogous to fraud (Coase, 2006, p. 260). And Williamson has also misleadingly defined a holdup in terms of deception: By opportunism I mean self-interest seeking with guile. This includes but is scarcely limited to more blatant forms, such as lying, stealing and cheating. Opportunism more often involves subtle forms of deceit. More generally, opportunism refers to the incomplete or distorted disclosure of information, especially to calculated efforts to mislead, distort, obfuscate, or otherwise confuse. (Williamson, 1985, p. 47) The major problem here is a semantic one because of the misleading connotation of holdup. All that is necessary for a holdup to occur is that the contract governing a relationship where specific investments does not cover some unanticipated change in market conditions and that reputational capital is insufficient to prevent one transactor from taking advantage of these circumstances to shift

rents in its favor by appropriating some portion of the relationship-specific assets. The existence of a holdup does not mean that a transactor has deceived its transacting partner. In fact, the possibility of holdup behavior understood in this way pervades and fundamentally influences all market exchange and the contractual arrangements chosen by transactors.

Bibliography Coase, Ronald H. (2000), The Acquisition of Fisher Body by General Motors, Journal of Law & Economics, 43, 15-32. Coase, Ronald H. (2006), The Conduct of Economics: The Example of Fisher Body and General Motors, Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 15, 255-278. Grossman, Sanford J., and Oliver D. Hart (1986), The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration, Journal of Political Economy, 94, 691-719. Joskow, Paul L. (1987), Contract Duration and Relationship-Specific Investments: Empirical Evidence From Coal Markets, American Economic Review, 77, 168-185. Klein, Benjamin, Robert G. Crawford and Armen A. Alchian (1978), Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents and the Competitive Contracting Process, Journal of Law & Economics. 21, 297-326. Klein, Benjamin (1996), Why Holdups Occur: The Self-Enforcing Range of Contractual Relationships, Economic Inquiry, 34, 444-463. Klein, Benjamin (2007), The Economic Lessons of Fisher Body-General Motors, International Journal of the Economics of Business, 14, 1-36. Segal, Ilya R., and Michael D. Whinston (2000), Exclusive Contracts and Protection of Investments, RAND Journal of Economics, 31, 603-633. Williamson, Oliver E. (1983), Credible Commitments: Using Hostages to Support Exchange, American Economic Review, 73, 519-540. Williamson, Oliver E. (1991), Comparative Economic Organization: The Analysis of Discrete Structured Alternatives, Administrative Science Quarterly, 36, 269-296. Whinston, Michael D. (2001), Assessing the Property Rights and Transaction-Cost Theories of Firm Scope, 91 American Economic Review, 91, pp. 184-188. Notes 1 Professor Emeritus of Economics, UCLA and Director, LECG. 2 This highly cited case was first described in Klein, Crawford and Alchian (1978). There has been an ongoing debate regarding the facts and interpretation of events surrounding the case, with the most recent and complete statement of the facts provided in Klein (2007). 3 Fisher Body s capacity investments to serve General Motors are referred to in the literature as dedicated assets. See Williamson (1983, p. 519, 526) and Joskow (1987, p. 168, 170-72). Williamson describes five other

different types of asset specificity: site specificity, physical asset specificity, human asset specificity, temporal specificity and brand name capital (Williamson, 1991). We now know that the important G.M.-specific Fisher Body investments did not consist of Fisher Body investments in G.M. tools and dies. Although tools and dies necessary for the production of General Motors bodies were highly G.M.-specific, General Motors merely purchased and owned these physical assets. See Klein (2007). 4 Segal and Whinston (2000) mistakenly claim that exclusive dealing did not protect Fisher Body s G.M.-specific investments. In the Segal and Whinston model the only effect of exclusive dealing is to prevent a buyer from free-riding by using a seller s specific investments when transacting with other sellers. Since Fisher Body s G.M.-specific capacity investments could not be used by General Motors with another body supplier, General Motors free-riding could not occur and exclusive dealing is asserted to serve no economic purpose. Segal and Whinston recognize that once a seller makes specific investments a holdup problem exists because the buyer can threaten to stop buying from the seller and thereby substantially reduce the value of the seller s specific investments. But Segal and Whinston maintain that exclusive dealing does not protect against such holdups because the penalty that can be imposed by the seller on the buyer with exclusive dealing can be imposed independent of buyer behavior. However, this unrealistically assumes that Fisher Body could legally enforce the exclusive [Exclusive what?] and also decide not to supply General Motors whether or not General Motors attempted a holdup by threatening to purchase elsewhere. Once one more realistically assumes that Fisher Body can impose a penalty on General Motors only if General Motors attempts a holdup, exclusive dealing can be used to protect Fisher Body s G.M.-specific investments from the threat of a General Motors holdup. See Klein (2007, pp. 7-9). 5 General Motors also acquired a 60 percent ownership of Fisher Body at the same time it entered into this contractual arrangement. However, the shares of Fisher Body common stock owned by General Motors were placed in a five year Voting Trust over which Fisher had veto power and therefore did not prevent Fisher Body from holding up General Motors in 1922, as described in the following section. Furthermore, after expiration of the Trust General Motors could not use its 60 percent ownership share to unilaterally abrogate the Fisher Body contract and reverse the holdup because it could not legally vote its Fisher Body shares without respecting the minority Fisher Body economic interests. The negotiated agreement that resulted in the vertical integration of General Motors and Fisher Body in 1926, however, involved terms that clearly eliminated any continuing Fisher Body holdup return. See discussion below and Klein (2007). 6 This result is related to the costless holdup renegotiation assumption made in the property rights theory of the firm originally proposed by Grossman and Hart (1986). 7 The likelihood that vertical integration will be used by transactors to solve potential holdup problems in any particular case will depend not only on the extent to which specific investments are present, but also on a number of other factors, including the difficulty of contractually specifying performance, the uncertainty associated with future performance, and the level of reputational capital possessed by transactors. However, holding these other factors constant, integration is more likely the greater the relationship-specific investments made by transactors. Empirical confirmation of this proposition has been described as one of the great success stories in industrial organization over the last 25 years. (Whinston, 2001, p. 184, 185). 8 The goal of contractual specification in this context often is not to create optimal incentives on some imperfect court-enforceable proxy for performance, but to economize on the reputational capital necessary to make a contractual relationship self-enforcing in the widest range of post-contract circumstances.