sequence economies S000097

Similar documents
Notes on Syllabus Section VI: TIME AND UNCERTAINTY, FUTURES MARKETS

Lecture Notes: November 29, 2012 TIME AND UNCERTAINTY: FUTURES MARKETS

Measuring the Benefits from Futures Markets: Conceptual Issues

Uncertainty in Equilibrium

Chapter 2 Equilibrium and Efficiency

Macroeconomic equilibrium in a monetary economy 1 2

Radner Equilibrium: Definition and Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

Discussion Paper Series. Short Sales, Destruction of Resources, Welfare. Nikos Kokonas and Herakles Polemarchakis

Financial Economics: Risk Sharing and Asset Pricing in General Equilibrium c

General Equilibrium under Uncertainty

Assets with possibly negative dividends

Economics 200A part 2 UCSD Fall quarter 2010 Prof. R. Starr Mr. Ben Backes 1 FINAL EXAMINATION - SUGGESTED ANSWERS

II. The Arrow-Debreu Model of Competitive Equilibrium - Definition and Existence A. Existence of General Equilibrium in a simple model

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Arrow Debreu Equilibrium. October 31, 2015

Macroeconomic Theory I Professor George Alogoskoufis Winter Semester Course Structure

Interest Rates and Currency Prices in a Two-Country World. Robert E. Lucas, Jr. 1982

1 Dynamic programming

Asset Pricing(HON109) University of International Business and Economics

Introducing money. Olivier Blanchard. April Spring Topic 6.

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

Income and Efficiency in Incomplete Markets

Optimal Asset Division Rules for Dissolving Partnerships

Ross M. Starr Department of Economics, University of California, San Diego, USA

The Theory of Unconventional Monetary Policy

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory. Steve Williamson Dept. of Economics Washington University in St. Louis St. Louis, MO 63130

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

Econ 219 Spring Lecture #11

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

1 The Exchange Economy...

Conventional and Unconventional Monetary Policy with Endogenous Collateral Constraints

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ON THE POSSIBILITY OF PRICE DECREASING BUBBLES. Philippe Weil. No Working Paper

Consumption and Saving

2. Equlibrium and Efficiency

Optimal Capital Income Taxes in an Infinite-lived Representative-agent Model with Progressive Tax Schedules

A Note on Competitive Investment under Uncertainty. Robert S. Pindyck. MIT-CEPR WP August 1991

Part A: Questions on ECN 200D (Rendahl)

A Note on Optimal Taxation in the Presence of Externalities

Golden rule. The golden rule allocation is the stationary, feasible allocation that maximizes the utility of the future generations.

Moral Hazard, Retrading, Externality, and Its Solution

On the Limitations of Monetary Policy 1

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland

Slides III - Complete Markets

CONVENTIONAL AND UNCONVENTIONAL MONETARY POLICY WITH ENDOGENOUS COLLATERAL CONSTRAINTS

Notes, Comments, and Letters to the Editor. Cores and Competitive Equilibria with Indivisibilities and Lotteries

Bubbles and the Intertemporal Government Budget Constraint

Continuous time Asset Pricing

Comment on: Optimal saving distortions with recursive preferences by Emmanuel Fahri and Iva n Werning $

Competitive Equilibria with Asymmetric Information*

Alternative sources of information-based trade

Term Structure of Interest Rates

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Fiat Value in the Theory of Value

ECON 581. Introduction to Arrow-Debreu Pricing and Complete Markets. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

INEFFICIENT TRADE PATTERNS: EXCESSIVE TRADE, CROSS-HAULING, AND DUMPING. by Benjamin Eden. Working Paper No. 05-W03. February 2005

How Much Trading Volume is Too Much?

1 Precautionary Savings: Prudence and Borrowing Constraints

Volume Title: The Demand for Health: A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation. Volume URL:

Intergenerational Risk Sharing in the Spirit of Arrow, Debreu, and Rawls, with Applications to Social Security Design.

Bilateral trading with incomplete information and Price convergence in a Small Market: The continuous support case

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Measuring Sustainability in the UN System of Environmental-Economic Accounting

Alberto Bisin Lecture Notes on Financial Economics:

A Double Counting Problem in the Theory of Rational Bubbles

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Asset price dynamics with heterogeneous, boundedly rational, utility-optimizing agents

The Duration Derby: A Comparison of Duration Based Strategies in Asset Liability Management

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

Competitive Outcomes, Endogenous Firm Formation and the Aspiration Core

Endogenous State Prices, Liquidity, Default, and the Yield Curve

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2015

Final Exam Solutions

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization

Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

Subgame Perfect Cooperation in an Extensive Game

Behavioral Equilibrium and Evolutionary Dynamics

Liquidity, Interest, and Asset Prices

Inflation. David Andolfatto

HETEROGENEITY AND REDISTRIBUTION: BY MONETARY OR FISCAL MEANS? BY PETER N. IRELAND 1. Boston College and National Bureau of Economic Research, U.S.A.

Some Simple Analytics of the Taxation of Banks as Corporations

National Debt and Economic Growth with Externalities and Congestions

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract

Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models. 1 Introduction. Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert. February 15, 2007

Topic 3: International Risk Sharing and Portfolio Diversification

Microeconomic Theory May 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program.

International Macroeconomics

Leverage, Incomplete Markets and Pareto Improving Regulation

EU i (x i ) = p(s)u i (x i (s)),

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014

HEDONIC PRODUCER PRICE INDEXES AND QUALITY ADJUSTMENT

Markets Do Not Select For a Liquidity Preference as Behavior Towards Risk

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

Transcription:

S000097 A sequence economy is a general equilibrium model including markets at a sequence of dates, reopening over time. It is alternative to the Arrow Debreu model with a full set of futures markets where all exchanges for current and future goods are transacted without transaction cost at a single market date. Sequence economy markets reopen and may be incomplete (some markets, particularly futures, may be inactive) because of transaction costs. The model can provide a microeconomic general equilibrium foundation for the storeof-value function of money, since markets reopening over time create an incentive to carry money and debt intertemporally. A sequence economy is a general equilibrium model in discrete time including specific provision for the availability of markets at a sequence of dates (Hicks, 1939; Radner, 1972). Markets reopen over time, and at each date firms and households act so that plans and prospects for actions on markets available in the future significantly affect their current actions. This model is in contrast to the Arrow Debreu model with a (complete) full set of futures markets (Debreu, 1959). There, all exchanges for current and future goods (including contingent commodities, futures contracts contingent on the realization of uncertain events) are transacted on a market at a single point in time. In the Arrow Debreu model, there is no need for markets to reopen in the future; economic activity in the future consists simply of the execution of the contracted plans. The Arrow Debreu model with a full set of futures markets appears unsatisfactory in that it denies commonplace observation: futures markets for goods and Arrow securities (contingent contracts payable in money) are not generally available for most dates or a sufficiently varied array of uncertain events; markets do reopen over time. The sequence economy model is an alternative that allows formalization and explanation of these observations. Several major classes of theoretical model are set in the sequence economy framework: overlapping generations (Balasko and Shell, 1980; 1981; Geanakoplos and Polemarchakis, 1991; Wallace, 1980); temporary equilibrium (Grandmont, 1977; Lucas, 1978), sunspot equilibrium (Chiappori and Guesnerie, 1991), incomplete markets (Geanakoplos, 1990; Magill and Quinzii, 1996). These are general equilibrium models over sequential time emphasizing monetary and financial structure. Each of these areas has a large literature of its own. Typically these models assume a given (incomplete) structure of active financial markets without a detailed foundation for how markets come to be incomplete. This contrasts with the statement of the sequence economy model presented below, which derives market activity and incompleteness endogenously as an equilibrium outcome reflecting transaction costs. The sequence economy model is particularly suitable to provide a microeconomic foundation for the store-of-value function of money (Hahn, 1971; Starrett, 1973). It is precisely because markets reopen over time that agents may find it desirable to carry abstract purchasing power from one date to succeeding dates. Typically, this will take the form of transactions on spot markets at a succession of dates with money or other financial assets held over time to reflect the (net) excess value of prior sales over purchases. This may occur simply because the model does not provide for futures markets or because futures markets, though available in principle, are in practice inactive. Endogenously determined inactivity of futures markets is the result of

2 We now present a formal pure exchange sequence economy model with transaction costs (Kurz, 1974; Heller and Starr, 1976). Commodity i for delivery at date t may be bought spot at date t or futures at any date t, 1 tot. The complete system of spot and futures markets is available at each date (although some markets may be inactive). The time horizon is date K; eachofh households is alive at time 1 and cares nothing about consumption after K. There are n commodities deliverable at each date; in the monetary interpretation of the model spot money is one of the goods. At each date and for each commodity, the household has available the current spot market, and futures markets for deliveries at all future dates. Spot and futures markets will also be available at dates in the future and prices on the markets taking place in the future are currently known. Thus in making his purchase and sale decisions, the household considers without price uncertainty whether to transact on current markets or to postpone transactions to markets available at future dates. There is a sequence of budget constraints, one for the market at each date. That is, for every date, the household faces a budget constraint on the spot and futures transactions taking place at that date, (4) below. The value of its sales to the market at each date (including delivery of money) must balance its purchases at that date. In addition to a budget constraint, the agent s actions are restricted by a transaction technology. This technology specifies for each complex of purchases and sales at date t, what resources will be consumed by the process of transaction. It is because transaction costs may differ between spot and futures markets for the same good that we consider the reopening of markets allowed by the sequence economy model. Specific provision for transaction cost is introduced to allow an endogenous determination of the activity or inactivity of markets. In the special case where all transaction costs are nil, the model is unnecessarily complex; there is no need for the reopening of markets, and the equilibrium allocations are identical to those of the Arrow Debreu model. Conversely, in the case where some futures markets are prohibitively costly to operate and others are costless, then there is an insequence economies transaction costs which tend to make the use of futures markets disproportionately costly compared with spot markets. There are three principal reasons for the excess cost of futures markets: 1. The necessarily greater complexity of futures contracts may require use of more resources (for example, for record keeping or enforcement) than spot markets. 2. The transaction costs of a futures contract are incurred (partly) at the transaction date, those of an equivalent spot transaction are incurred in the future. The present discounted value of the spot transaction costs incurred in the distant future may be lower than the futures market transaction cost incurred in the present, simply because of time-discounting. 3. Use of a full set of futures markets under uncertainty implies that most contracts transacted become otiose and are left unfulfilled as their effective dates pass and the events on which they were contingent do not occur. There is a corresponding saving in transaction costs associated with reducing the number of transactions required by use of a single spot transaction instead of many contingent commodity contracts, though this reduction may imply a different and inferior allocation of risk-bearing.

3 complete array of spot and futures markets and the model is an example of that of Radner (1972). All of the n-dimensional vectors below are restricted to be non-negative. x h tðtþ=vector of purchases for any purpose at date t by household h for delivery at date t. ðtþ=vector of sales analogously defined. y h t z h t ðtþ=vector of inputs necessary to transactions undertaken at time t. The index t again refers to date at which these inputs are actually delivered. o h (t)=vector of endowments at t for household h. s h (t)=vector of goods coming out of storage at date t. r h (t)=vector of goods put into storage at date t. p t (t)=price vector on market at date t for goods deliverable at date t. With this notation, p it (t) is the (scalar) spot price of good i at date t, and p it (t) for t4t is the futures price (for delivery at t) of good i at date t. The (non-negative) consumption vector for household h is c h ðtþ ¼o h ðtþþ Xt t¼1 x h t ðtþ yh t ðtþ zh t ðtþ þs h ðtþ r h ðtþ ^ 0; ðt ¼ 1;...; KÞ. (1) That is, consumption at date t is the sum of endowments plus all purchases past and present with delivery date t minus all sales for delivery at t minus transaction inputs with date t (including those previously committed) plus what comes out of storage at t minus what goes into storage. We suppose that households care only about consumption and not about which market consumption comes from. The household is constrained by its transaction technology, T h (t), and by its storage technology, S h (t). T h (t) specifies the resources, for example, how much leisure time and shoeleather, must be used to carry out a transaction. Let x h (t) denote the vector of x h t ðtþ s [and similarly for yh (t) and z h (t)]. We insist ½x h ðtþ; y h ðtþ; zðtþš 2 T h ðtþ; ðt ¼ 1;...; KÞ. ð2þ Naturally, storage input and output vectors must be feasible, so ½r h ðtþ; s h ðt þ 1ÞŠ 2 S h ðtþ; ðt ¼ 1;...; K 1Þ. ð3þ The budget constraints for household h are then: pðtþx h ðtþ % pðtþy h ðtþ; ðt ¼ 1;...; KÞ. ð4þ Households may transfer purchasing power forward in time by using futures markets and by storage of goods that will be valuable in the future. Purchasing power may be carried backward by using futures markets. But these may be very costly transactions. In a monetary interpretation of the model, where money and promissory notes are present, the household can either hold money as a store of wealth, or it can buy or sell notes. Let household h s action at date t be denoted a h ðtþ ½x h ðtþy h ðtþ; z h ðtþ; r h ðtþ; s h ðtþš. Let a h be a vector of the a h (t) s, and define x h, y h, z h, r h and s h similarly. Define B h (p) as the set of a h s which satisfy constraints (1) (4). The household chooses a h (t) to maximize U h (c h ) over B h (p). Denote the demand correspondence (i.e. the set of maximizing a h s) by g h (p). The model can be interpreted as monetary or non-monetary. We think of money as simply a 0th good that does not enter household preferences.

4 Futures contracts in money are discounted promissory notes. x h 0tðtÞ is h s monetary receipts at t; x h 0tðtÞ is h s note purchase at t due at t. Money is not treated as numeraire positivity of its value cannot be assumed it has a price p 0t (t). The correspondences g h t ðpþ are always homogeneous of degree zero in p(t), as is seen from the definition of B h (p). We can therefore restrict the price space to the simplex. Let S t denote the unit simplex of dimensionality, n(k t+1). Let P ¼ X K t¼1 St, where X denotes a Cartesian product. An equilibrium of the economy is a price vector p 2 P and an allocation a h, for each h, so that a h 2 g h ðp Þ for all h and X H h¼1 x h % XH (the inequality holds coordinate-wise), where for any good i, t, t such that the strict inequality holds in (5) it follows that p itðtþ ¼0. The equilibrium of a monetary economy is said to be non-trivial (that is, the economy is really monetary) if p 0tðtÞa0 for all t. Sufficient conditions for existence of equilibrium are continuity and convexity requirements typical of an Arrow Debreu model appropriately extended. Transaction costs are often thought to be non-convex, leading to approximate equilibrium rather than full equilibrium results (Heller and Starr, 1976). In the case of fiat (unbacked) money, existence of non-trivial monetary equilibrium requires additional structure designed to maintain positivity of the price of money (boundedness of the price level expressed in monetary terms). This may take a variety of forms: the model may arbitrarily require that fiat money be held or turned in at a finite horizon; households may expect fiat money to be valuable in the future sustaining its value in the present; there may be taxes payable in fiat money. Alternatively, the model may assume an infinite horizon (typical of the overlapping generations model) so that the lack of backing for fiat money need not be experienced (though a nil value of fiat money in equilibrium is still a logical possibility). In contrast to the Arrow Debreu economy, a sequence economy equilibrium allocation is not generally Pareto efficient. This is not due simply to the presence of transaction costs; transaction costs technically necessary to a reallocation must be incurred, and they represent no inefficiency. The Arrow Debreu model, however, uses a lifetime budget constraint. The corresponding constraint here is the sequence of budget constraints in (4). Transfer of purchasing power intertemporally costless in the Arrow Debreu model is here a resource using activity; it requires purchase and sale of assets with resultant transaction cost. But the intertemporal transfer of purchasing power, unlike reallocation of goods among households, is needed not to satisfy technical or consumption requirements but rather to satisfy the administrative requirements of sequential budget constraint embodied in (4). Hence technically feasible Pareto-improving reallocations may be prevented in equilibrium by prohibitive transaction costs which would have to be incurred to satisfy the purely administrative requirements of crediting and debiting agents budgets intertemporally (Hahn, 1971). If trade in monetary instruments is costless, however, then an equilibrium allocation is Pareto efficient (Starrett, 1973). Thus the sequence economy model provides a valuetheoretic foundation for the store-of-value role of money. Ross M. Starr h¼1 y h ð5þ

5 See also <xref=xyyyyyy> general equilibrium. Bibliography Balasko, Y. and Shell, K. 1980. The overlapping-generations model, I. The case of pure exchange without money. Journal of Economic Theory 23, 281 306. Balasko, Y. and Shell, K. 1981. The overlapping-generations model. II. The case of pure exchange with money. Journal of Economic Theory 24, 112 42. Chiappori, P.A. and Guesnerie, R. 1991. Sunspot equilibria in sequential markets models. In Handbook of Mathematical Economics, vol. 4, eds. W. Hildenbrand and H. Sonnenschein. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Debreu, G. 1959. Theory of Value. New York: Wiley. Geanakoplos, J. 1990. An Introduction to General Equilibrium with Incomplete Asset Markets. Journal of Mathematical Economics 19, 1 38. Geanakoplos, J.D. and Polemarchakis, H.M. 1991. Overlapping generations. In Handbook of Mathematical Economics, vol. 4, eds. W. Hildenbrand and H. Sonnenschein. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Grandmont, J.M. 1977. Temporary general equilibrium theory. Econometrica 45, 535 72. Hahn, F.H. 1971. Equilibrium with transaction costs. Econometrica 39, 417 39. Heller, W.P. and Starr, R.M. 1976. Equilibrium with non-convex transactions costs: monetary and non-monetary economies. Review of Economic Studies 43, 195 215. Hicks, J.R. 1939. Value and capital. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Kurz, M. 1974. Equilibrium in a finite sequence of markets with transactions cost. Econometrica 42, 1 20. Lucas, Jr., R.E. 1978. Asset prices in an exchange economy. Econometrica 46, 1429 45. Magill, M. and Quinzii, M. 1996. Theory of incomplete markets. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Radner, R. 1972. Existence of equilibrium of plans, prices, and price expectations in a sequence of markets. Econometrica 40, 289 303. Starrett, D.A. 1973. Inefficiency and the demand for money in a sequence economy. Review of Economic Studies 40, 437 48. Wallace, N. 1980. The overlapping generations model of money. In Models of Monetary Economics, eds. J.H. Kareken and N. Wallace. Minneapolis: Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Index terms Arrow Debreu model budget constraint fiat money futures markets general equilibrium incomplete markets infinite horizons intertemporal transfers overlapping generations models spot markets store-of-value function of money sunspot equilibrium

6 temporary equilibrium transaction costs