HIGHER ORDER BINARY OPTIONS AND MULTIPLE-EXPIRY EXOTICS

Similar documents
INTEGRALS OF HIGHER BINARY OPTIONS AND DEFAULTABLE BONDS WITH DISCRETE DEFAULT INFORMATION

THE USE OF NUMERAIRES IN MULTI-DIMENSIONAL BLACK- SCHOLES PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS. Hyong-chol O *, Yong-hwa Ro **, Ning Wan*** 1.

Exotic Options. Chapter 19. Types of Exotics. Packages. Non-Standard American Options. Forward Start Options

American options and early exercise

TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Option Pricing Model with Stepped Payoff

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Options

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS

2.1 Mathematical Basis: Risk-Neutral Pricing

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Multiple Optimal Stopping Problems and Lookback Options

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility

No-Arbitrage Conditions for a Finite Options System

Advanced Stochastic Processes.

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Aspects of Financial Mathematics:

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

CHAPTER 10 OPTION PRICING - II. Derivatives and Risk Management By Rajiv Srivastava. Copyright Oxford University Press

FE610 Stochastic Calculus for Financial Engineers. Stevens Institute of Technology

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

d St+ t u. With numbers e q = The price of the option in three months is

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

A NEW NOTION OF TRANSITIVE RELATIVE RETURN RATE AND ITS APPLICATIONS USING STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS. Burhaneddin İZGİ

Black-Scholes Option Pricing

Black-Scholes-Merton Model

The Black-Scholes Equation

Homework Assignments

Option Pricing Formula for Fuzzy Financial Market

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF FINITE

Integrating rational functions (Sect. 8.4)

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Stochastic Differential Equations in Finance and Monte Carlo Simulations

F A S C I C U L I M A T H E M A T I C I

American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market

The Pennsylvania State University. The Graduate School. Department of Industrial Engineering AMERICAN-ASIAN OPTION PRICING BASED ON MONTE CARLO

Cash Accumulation Strategy based on Optimal Replication of Random Claims with Ordinary Integrals

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1

Probability in Options Pricing

1 Geometric Brownian motion

A Moment Matching Approach To The Valuation Of A Volume Weighted Average Price Option

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

Numerical schemes for SDEs

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

A distributed Laplace transform algorithm for European options

Solving the Black-Scholes Equation

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Solving the Black-Scholes Equation

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing

Barrier Options Pricing in Uncertain Financial Market

Pricing levered warrants with dilution using observable variables

Analysis of the sensitivity to discrete dividends : A new approach for pricing vanillas

Computing Bounds on Risk-Neutral Measures from the Observed Prices of Call Options

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

A THREE-FACTOR CONVERGENCE MODEL OF INTEREST RATES

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Degree project. Pricing American and European options under the binomial tree model and its Black-Scholes limit model

European call option with inflation-linked strike

Non replication of options

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Numerical Solution of BSM Equation Using Some Payoff Functions

Finance II. May 27, F (t, x)+αx f t x σ2 x 2 2 F F (T,x) = ln(x).

Option Pricing. Chapter Discrete Time

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.gn] 13 Aug 2018

1.12 Exercises EXERCISES Use integration by parts to compute. ln(x) dx. 2. Compute 1 x ln(x) dx. Hint: Use the substitution u = ln(x).

A Study on Numerical Solution of Black-Scholes Model

CS476/676 Mar 6, Today s Topics. American Option: early exercise curve. PDE overview. Discretizations. Finite difference approximations

Homework Set 6 Solutions

Valuation of performance-dependent options in a Black- Scholes framework

MATH 476/567 ACTUARIAL RISK THEORY FALL 2016 PROFESSOR WANG

PDE Methods for the Maximum Drawdown

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

B is the barrier level and assumed to be lower than the initial stock price.

Pricing Exotic Options Under a Higher-order Hidden Markov Model

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing

TEST OF BOUNDED LOG-NORMAL PROCESS FOR OPTIONS PRICING

Some Computational Aspects of Martingale Processes in ruling the Arbitrage from Binomial asset Pricing Model

Computer Exercise 2 Simulation

Extensions to the Black Scholes Model

- 1 - **** d(lns) = (µ (1/2)σ 2 )dt + σdw t

PAijpam.eu ANALYTIC SOLUTION OF A NONLINEAR BLACK-SCHOLES EQUATION

Hull, Options, Futures & Other Derivatives Exotic Options

One Period Binomial Model: The risk-neutral probability measure assumption and the state price deflator approach

Lecture 1 Definitions from finance

Derivative Securities Fall 2012 Final Exam Guidance Extended version includes full semester

Review Direct Integration Discretely observed options Summary QUADRATURE. Dr P. V. Johnson. School of Mathematics

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Pricing Volatility Derivatives with General Risk Functions. Alejandro Balbás University Carlos III of Madrid

Transcription:

Electronic Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications Vol. (2) July 203, pp. 247-259. ISSN: 2090-792X (online) http://ejmaa.6te.net/ HIGHER ORDER BINARY OPTIONS AND MULTIPLE-EXPIRY EXOTICS HYONG-CHOL O, MUN-CHOL KIM Abstract. In this paper we extend Buchen s method to develop a new technique for pricing of some exotic options with several expiry dates (more than 3 expiry dates) using a concept of higher order binary option. At first we introduce the concept of higher order binary option and then provide the pricing formulae of n-th order binaries using PDE method. After that, we apply them to get the pricing of some multiple-expiry exotic options such as Bermudan option, multi time extendable option, multiple shout option and etc. Here, when calculating the price of concrete multiple-expiry exotic options, we do not try to get the formal solution to corresponding initial-boundary problem of the Black-Scholes equation, but explain how to express the expiry payoffs of the exotic options as a combination of the payoffs of some class of higher order binary options. Once the expiry payoffs are expressed as a linear combination of the payoffs of some class of higher order binary options, in order to avoid arbitrage, the exotic option prices are obtained by static replication with respect to this family of higher order binaries.. Introduction European and American options are referred to as vanilla options. Vanilla options have a single future expiry payoff that corresponds to buying or selling the underlying asset for a fixed amount called the strike price. European options can only be exercised at the expiry date, whereas American options may be exercised at any time before and at the expiry date. The various needs of risk management in financial markets give rise to many exotic (not ordinary) options with various payoff structures, and thus a lot of exotic options continue to be popular in the over-the counter market. Among them, there exists a class of exotic options whose payoff structure involves several fixed future dates, here we write them by T 0 < T < < T N. Usually, at the first expiry date T 0, the option holder receives a contract related with dates T,, T N. Options belonging to this class are called multiple-expiry exotic options. Bermudan options or several times extendable options are good examples. 200 Mathematics Subject Classification. 35C5, 9G80. Key words and phrases. Multiple-expiry, Exotic option, Bermudan option, Extendable option, Shout option, Higher order Binary Option. Submitted May, 203; first revised May 7, 203; last revised May 29, 203. 247

248 HYONG-CHOL O, MUN-CHOL KIM EJMAA-203/(2) In this paper we extend Buchen s method [2] to develop a new technique for pricing of multiple expiry exotic options in terms of a portfolio of higher order binary options. An up (or down) binary option is the option that on its expiry date delivers an agreed payoff if the price of the underlying asset is above (or bellow) a fixed exercise price and zero otherwise. Binary options whose agreed payoff is an asset are referred as first order asset binaries and binary options whose agreed payoff is cash are referred as first order bond binaries [2]. In this paper, the binary options whose agreed payoff is a (n )-th order binary are called n-th order binaries by induction. The basic idea of expressing the payoffs of complex options in terms of binary options can be seen in previous publications. Rubinstein and Reiner [7] considered the relationship of barrier options and binaries. Ingersoll [3] extended the idea by expressing complex derivatives in terms of event-driven binaries. Event ε-driven binary option pays one unit of underlying asset if and only if the event ε occurs, otherwise it pays nothing. Buchen [2] developed a theoretical framework for pricing dual-expiry options in terms of a portfolio of elementary binary options. He introduced the concepts of first and second order binary options and provided the pricing formula for them using expectation method. And then he applied them to pricing some dual expiry exotic options including compound option, chooser option, one time extendable option, one time shout option, American call option with one time dividend and partial barrier options. The purpose of this paper is to extend the Buchen s procedure to the case of multiple-expiry options (more than 3 expiry dates). To do that, here, at first we introduced the concept of higher order binary options and then provided the pricing formula of n-th order binaries using PDE method. After that, we applied them to pricing of some multiple-expiry exotic options such as Bermudan options, multi time extendable options, multiple shout options and etc. As Buchen [2] mentioned, historically, dual expiry exotics as well as multipleexpiry option prices have been derived individually by various authors. This paper has demonstrated that multiple-expiry options can be priced in a unified framework by expressing each as a portfolio of higher order binaries. The focus of this paper is on explaining the basic pricing method in terms of static replication with higher order binaries, and so issues such as the financial motivation for trading multiple-expiry exotics, computation and simulation will not be considered here in detail and the explanation about another authors results on concrete multiple-expiry exotics such as Bermudan option, extendable option and shout option will refer to [6, 9, 0]. 2. Higher Order Binary Options Consider an underlying asset (for example, a stock) whose price x satisfies Ito stochastic differential equation. Let r, q and σ be respectively risk free rate, dividend rate and volatility. Then to avoid arbitrage, the price of V (x, t) of any derivative on the stock with expiry date T and expiry payoff f(x) must satisfy the following ()-(2). V t + σ2 2 x 2 V 2 + (r q)x V rv = 0, 0 t < T, 0 < x < 2 () V (x, T ) = f(x) (2)

EJMAA-203/(2) HIGHER ORDER BINARY OPTIONS 249 This price V (x, t) is called a standard option with expiry payoff f(x) [2]. Proposition [5] Assume that there exist non negative constants M and α such that f(x) Mx α ln x, x > 0. Then the price of standard option, that is, the solution of () and (2) is provided as follows: V (x, t; T ) = e r(t t) = xe q(t t) 0 0 σ 2π(T t) σ 2π(T t) [ln x +(r q σ2 )(T t)]2 z 2 z e 2σ 2 (T t) [ln x +(r q+ σ2 )(T t)]2 z 2 z 2 e f(z)dz 2σ 2 (T t) f(z)dz. (3) Remark. It is well known that the change of variable y = ln x transforms () to a parabolic PDE with constant coefficients which can be easily transformed into a heat equation. (For example, see [4].) From the theory of heat equations we can know that the singular integral on the left side of (3) and its t and x derivatives always exist under the above condition on f, which can be easily seen in references such as [8] on PDE or equations of mathematical physics, and we can easily check that (3) satisfies () and (2). An up binary option of exercise price ξ on the standard option with expiry payoff f(x) is a contract with expiry payoff f(x) if x > ξ and zero otherwise. A down binary option pays f(x) if x < ξ and zero otherwise. Let s be the sign + or. In what follows we use the sign + and as sign indicators for up and down binaries, respectively. Then the expiry payoff functions for up and down binaries can be written in the form V s ξ (x, T ) = f(x) (sx > sξ). From this there holds the following parity relation between the standard option price and the corresponding up and down binaries: V + ξ (x, t) + V (x, t) = V (x, t), t < T. ξ If f(x) = x, the standard option simply pays one unit of the asset at expiry date T, and the price of the standard option is A(x, t; T ) = xe q(t t) for all t < T. And the corresponding binaries are the very asset-or-nothing binaries, here their prices are denoted by A s ξ (x, t; T ). Then from the above mentioned parity relation, we have A + ξ (x, t; T ) + A ξ (x, t; T ) = A(x, t; T ) = x e q(t t), t < T. If f(x) =, the standard option simply pays one unit of cash at expiry date T, and the price of the standard option is B(x, t; T ) = e r(t t) for all t < T. And the corresponding binaries are the very cash-or-nothing binaries (or bond binaries), here their prices are denoted by Bξ s (x, t; T ). From the parity relation, we have B + ξ (x, t; T ) + B ξ (x, t; T ) = B(x, t; T ) = e r(t t), t < T. The concept of Q-option plays a very useful role in the pricing of dual expiry options and, in particular, simplifying the notation of the price formula. (See [2].) Consider a standard contract that pays f(x) = s(x K) at expiry date T ; this is a kind of forward contract, where the holder must buy if s = + (or sell if s = ) one unit of underlying asset for K units of cash. Since f(x) =

250 HYONG-CHOL O, MUN-CHOL KIM EJMAA-203/(2) s[a(x, T ; T ) K B(x, T ; T )], the price Q(x, t; T, K) of this contract at time t < T is given by Q(x, t; T, K) = s[a(x, t; T ) K B(x, t; T )] = s[x e q(t t) K e r(t t) ]. The binary option that pays f(x) = s(x K) (sx > sξ) at expiry date T is called a first order Q-option, their prices denoted by Q s ξ (x, t; T, K). If ξ = K, then Q s K (x, t; T, K) is is the very ordinary European (call if s = +, or put if s = ) option. So Q s ξ (x, t; T, K) is called a generalized European option. These options are more general in the sense that their exercise price ξ is different from their strike price K. The price of first order Q-options are given as follows: Q s ξ(x, t; T, K) = s[a s ξ(x, t; T ) K B s ξ(x, t; T )]. (4) The asset or nothing binary, bond binary and the first order Q-option are called the first order binaries.[2] Proposition 2[2, 4]. The prices of asset and bond binary options are provided as follows: A s ξ(x, t; T ) = x e q(t t) N(sd), B s ξ(x, t; T ) = e r(t t) N(sd ). (5) Here N(x) is the accumulated normal distribution function N(x) = ( 2π) x and d, d are respectively given as follows: e y2 2 dy, d = ln x z + (r q + σ 2 2 )(T t) σ, d = d σ T t. T t Definition. An n-th order binary option is a binary contract with expiry date T 0 on an underlying (n )-th order binary option. Specifically, the payoff at time T 0 has the following form V (x, T 0 ) = F s sn (x, T 0 ; T,, T n ) (s 0 x > s 0 ξ 0 ). (6) Here F s sn (x, T 0 ; T,, T n ) is the price of the underlying (n )-th order binary option with expiry time T,, T n at the time T 0 and either F = A if the underlying binary is asset binary, F = B for the underlying bond binary or F = Q for the underlying Q-option; and s 0,, s n are up-down indicators (+ or ) at times T 0,, T n respectively. ξ 0,, ξ n are their corresponding exercise prices. The prices of these n-th order binary options at time t < T 0 are denoted by F s0s sn (x, t; T 0, T,, T n ). Then from the definition we have Q s0s sn (x, t; T 0, T,, T n, K) = s n [A s0s sn (x, t; T 0, T,, T n ) K B s0s sn (x, t; T 0, T,, T n )]. (7) Note that the strike price K in the higher order Q-binary is effective only at last time T n. From the parity relation, we have F +s sn (x, t; T 0, T,, T n ) + F s sn (x, t; T 0, T,, T n ) =

EJMAA-203/(2) HIGHER ORDER BINARY OPTIONS 25 = F s sn (x, t; T,, T n ). If the pricing formulae of the higher order asset binary A s0s sn (x, t; T 0, T,, T n ) and the higher order bond binary B s0s sn (x, t; T 0, T,, T n ) are provided, then the price of the higher order Q-binary is easily provided by (7). Black-Scholes expressions for higher order binary options involve multidimensional normal distribution function N(x 0, x,, x n ; P ), here P is the correlation matrix, that is: N(x 0, x,, x n ; P ) = x0 xn ( det P e 2π) n 2 yt P y dy. (8) Here y T = (y 0, y,, y n ). Let define the matrix A = (a ij ) i,j=0,,,n related to the expiry dates T 0, T,, T n as follows: a 00 = (T t)/(t T 0 ), a n,n = (T n t)/(t n T n 2 ), a ii = (T i t)/(t i T i ) + (T i t)/(t i+ T i ), i n 2, a i,i+ = a i+,i = (T i t)(t i+ t)/(t i+ T i ), 0 i n 2, and another elements are all zero. Then we have correlation matrix and determinant: A = (r ij ); r ij = (T i t)/(t j t), r ji = r ij, i j, det A = T t T 2 t T n t. T T 0 T 2 T T n T n 2 Let s i = + or (that is, sign indicators and i = 0,,, n ) and define a new matrix by A s0s s n = (s i s j a ij ) n i,j=0. Then we have det A s0s s n = det A. Theorem The price of n-th order asset binary and bond binary are provided as follows : Here A s0s sn (x, t; T 0, T,, T n ) = = x e q(tn t) N(s 0 d 0, s d,, s n d n ; A s0s s n ), (9) B s0s sn (x, t; T 0, T,, T n ) = d i = ln x ξ i = e r(tn t) N(s 0 d 0, s d,, s n d n ; A s0s s n ). (0) + (r q + σ 2 2 )(T i t) σ, d i = d i σ T i t, i = 0,,, n. T i t

252 HYONG-CHOL O, MUN-CHOL KIM EJMAA-203/(2) Proof: The cases of n = and n = 2 were proved by Buchen in [2] using probability theory and can be easily proved using the formula (3) too. In the case of n > 2 we will give a sketch of the proof by induction. We assume that theorem holds in the case of n. From the definition, A s0s sn (x, t; T 0, T,, T n ) satisfies () and V (x, T 0 ) = A s sn (x, T 0 ; T,, T n ) (s 0 x > s 0 ξ 0 ). Therefore by the formula (3), If we let G(z) = σ 2π(T 0 t) z 2 e [ln x +(r q+ σ2 z 2 )(T 0 t)]2 2σ 2 (T 0 t), then A s0s sn (x, t; T 0, T,, T n ) is provided as follows: A s0s sn (x, t; T 0, T,, T n ) = = x e q(t0 t) 0 G(z)A s sn (z, T 0 ; T,, T n ) (s 0 z > s 0 ξ 0 )dz. Here A s sn (z, T 0 ; T,, T n ) is the price of the underlying (n )-th order asset binary option. By induction-assumption, the formula (9) holds for A s sn (z, T 0 ; T,, T n ). Thus we have A s sn (z, T 0 ; T,, T n ) = = z e q(tn T0) N(s d,, s n d n ; A s s n ). Substitute this equality into the above singular integral representation and calculate the integral, then we have (9) for the case of n > 2. The proof for (0) is similar. (Proof End) The formulae (7), (9) and (0) give the following price of higher order Q- option : Q s0s sn (x, t; T 0, T,, T n, K) = = s n [x e q(tn t) N(s 0 d 0, s d,, s n d n ; A s0s s n ) Kė r(tn t) N(s 0 d 0, s d,, s n d n ; A s0s s n )]. () 3. Applications to Multiple-Expiry Exotics In this section, we applied the results of previous section to the pricing of some multiple expiry exotics. The Static Replication Theorem If the payoff of an option at expiry time T 0 is a linear combination of prices at time T 0 of higher order binaries, then its price at all time t < T 0 is the combination of the corresponding prices at time t of the higher order binaries.

EJMAA-203/(2) HIGHER ORDER BINARY OPTIONS 253 The static replication theorem can be proved from the uniqueness of solution to the initial value problem of Black-Scholes equation. And we need one lemma that guarantees the monotonousness of the option price on the underlying asset price and provides some estimates about the gradient of the price on the underlying asset price. If V (x, t) is the so- Lemma Assume that f(x) is piecewise differentiable. lution of () and (2), then we have f min x e q(t t) V f (x, t) max x e q(t t). In particular, if E = {z : f (z) < max x f f }, F = {z : (z) > min x f }, E > 0 and F > 0, then f min x e q(t t) < V f (x, t) < max x e q(t t), t < T. Using the formula (3) and the assumption of lemma, we can easily prove the required results. 3.. Bermudan Options. The Bermudan option is one type of nonstandard American options and early exercise is restricted to certain dates during the life of the option. For example, let t < t 2 < < t n = T be the dates of early exercise for put option with strike price K. Let t 0 = 0. Let denote the option price on the interval (t i, t i ] by V i (x, t), where i =,, n. Then [4] (See figure.) V i (x, t i ) = max(v i (x, t i ), (K x) + ), i =,, n. (2) Figure. For fixed i =,, n, we consider the following equation: V i (x, t i ) = (K x) +. (3) If V i (x, t i ) is monotonously decreasing on x, 0 < V i (x, t i ) < K and < Vi(x,ti), then the equation (3) has a unique root a i such that 0 < a i < K. (See figure 2.) Lemma 2 Fix i {,, n }. Assume that V i (x, t i ) is monotonously decreasing on x, 0 < V i (x, t i ) < K and < Vi(x,ti). Let a i be the unique root of the equation (3). Then for any t [t i, t i ), we have V i (x, t) = (V i ) + a i (x, t; t i ) + Q a i (x, t; t i, K) and Vi 0. In particular, if t i t < t i, then < Vi (x,t) < 0. Here (V i ) + a i (x, t; t i ) is the solution of Black-Scholes equation () satisfying the condition V (x, t i ) = V i (x, t i ) (x > a i ).

254 HYONG-CHOL O, MUN-CHOL KIM EJMAA-203/(2) Figure 2. Proof. From the assumption, we can rewrite (2) as follows. (See figure 2.) V i (x, t i ) = V i (x, t i ) (x > a i ) + (K x) (x < a i ). Thus from the definition of the binary option, we have V i (x, t) = (V i ) + a i (x, t; t i ) + Q a i (x, t; t i, K), t (t i, t i ]. From the assumption we have 0 < a i < K and thus using lemma, we have the conclusion on Vi. (Proof End) Using this lemma, we can easily calculate the price of Bermudan put options. Since the payoff at time t n is (K x) + and we can t early exercise after the time t n, so the option on the interval (t n, t n ] becomes an ordinary European put option, and thus its price V n (x, t) in the interval [t n, t n ) is given by V n (x, t) = Q K (x, t; t n, K), t [t n, t n ) and V n (x, t n ) satisfies 0 < V n (x, t n ) < K and < Vn (x, t n ) < 0. By the static replication theorem and lemma 2, our option price at time t [t n 2, t n ) is given by V n 2 (x, t) = Q + a (x, t; t n K n, t n, K) + Qa n (x, t; t n, K), t [t n 2, t n ). and < Vn 2 formulae: < 0. Repeating the similar considerations, we can get the following V i (x, t) = Q + + a (x, t; t i a n K i,, t n, K) + Q + a + i a n 2a n (x, t; t i,, t n, K)+ + + Q + a ia i+ (x, t; t i, t i+, K) + Q a i (x, t; t i, K), t [t i, t i ), i {,, n}. (4) In particular, V 0 gives the price of Bermudan put option at time t = 0. V 0 (x, t) = Q + + a (x, t; t a n K,, t n, K) + Q a + + a n 2a n (x, t; t,, t n, K)+ + + Q + a a 2 (x, t; t, t 2, K) + Q a (x, t; t, K), t [0, t ).

EJMAA-203/(2) HIGHER ORDER BINARY OPTIONS 255 3.2. Multiple Extendable Options. Extendable options were first studied and analyzed in detail by Longstaff [6]. Here we consider the holder extendable options in his sense. The holder n-times extendable call (or put) option has the right at some certain dates T i to exercise a standard European call (or put) option of strike price K i or to extend the expiry date to time T i+ (> T i ) and change the strike price from K i to K i+ (i = 0,,, n ) for a premium C i. Here we consider n-times extendable call option. Let denote the option price on the interval [T i, T i ) by V i (x, t), where i = 0,,, n and T = 0. Then from the definition of extendable option, we have V i (x, T i ) = max(v i+ (x, T i ) C i, (x K i ) + ), i = 0,, n. (5) First, let consider the price V n (x, t) in the last interval (T n, T n ]. In this interval we can no longer extend our option contract and thus our option is just an ordinary European call with the expiry date T n and strike price K n. Therefore V n (x, t) = Q + K n (x, t; T n, K), t [T n, T n ). And it satisfies 0 < Vn(x,Tn ) < by lemma. Now consider the price V n (x, t) in the interval (T n 2, T n ]. Then by (5) we have V n (x, T n ) = max(q + K n (x, T n ; T n, K n ) C n, (x K n ) + ). From the property of Q + K n (x, T n ; T n, K n ), the following two equations on x have unique roots a n and b n, respectively. Q + K n (x, T n ; T n, K n ) C n = 0, Q + K n (x, T n ; T n, K n ) C n = (x K n ) + (6) And it is quite natural that we assume that a n < K n < b n. (Otherwise the extension of T n to T n would not occur as Buchen [2] mentioned. See figure 3. Similarly, in put we assume that a n > K n > b n.) Figure 3. Then we can rewrite V n (x, T n ) as follows: V n (x, T n ) = [Q + K n (x, T n ; T n, K n ) C n ] (a n < x < b n ) +(x K n ) (x > b n ) = = Q + K n (x, T n ; T n, K n ) (x > a n ) Q + K n (x, T n ; T n, K n ) (x > b n )

256 HYONG-CHOL O, MUN-CHOL KIM EJMAA-203/(2) C n (x > a n ) + (x K n + C n ) (x > b n ) Thus using the Static Replication Theorem, we have V n (x, t) = [Q + + a n K n (x, t; T n, T n, K n ) Q + + b n K n (x, t; T n, T n, K n ) C n B + a n (x, t; T n ) + Q + b n (x, t; T n, K n C n ), t [T n 2, T n ). And V n (x, T n ) is a monotone increasing function of x with a positive inclination less than in x (a n, b n ). (See figure 3.) By lemma, we have 0 < V n (x, t) <, t [T n 2, T n ). By similar consideration and induction, we can prove that the formula of price V i (x, t) of our option in the time interval [T i, T i ) is provided by s(j i ) s(j n ) Q + + + j i j n K n (x, t; T i,, T n, K n )+ (j i j n ) {a i,b i} {a n,b n } n k=i (j i j k ) {a i,b i} {a k,b k } n + C k k=i (j i j k ) {a i,b i} {a k,b k } Here s(j) is the a or b indicator, that is, {, j m = a m, s(j m ) =, j m = b m. s(j i ) s(j k ) Q + + + j i j k b k (x, t; T i,, T k, K k C k ) s(j i ) s(j k ) B + + + j i j k a k (x, t; T i,, T k ). In particular V 0 gives the price of n-times extendable call option in the time interval [0, T 0 ). (7) 3.3. Multiple Shout Options. Shout options (Thomas [0]) are exotic options that allow the holder to lock in a payoff at times prior to the final expiry date. If the shout times would be selected randomly according to the holder s mind, the pricing of shout option will be quite challenging, but if the shout times are pre-determined, then it would be simpler ([2]). In a fixed time multiple shout call option with expiry date T and strike price K, their payoff can be locked in at some predetermined times T 0 < < T n (< T ). So at the final expiry date T = T n, its payoff is given as follows: V (x, T ) = max(x 0 K,, x n K, x K, 0), (8) where x i (i = 0,, n ) are the underlying asset price x(t i ) at the shout time T i. For simplicity, here we consider the case n = 2. Then the expiry payoff (8) is given by V (x, T 2 ) = max(x 0 K, x K, x K, 0), (9)

EJMAA-203/(2) HIGHER ORDER BINARY OPTIONS 257 Note that in the last interval (T, T 2 ] both of the underlying asset prices x 0 = x(t 0 ) and x = x(t ) are known constants and in the interval (T 0, T ] the underlying asset price x 0 = x(t 0 ) is a known constant. The case of x 0 < K. We can rewrite (9) as V (x, T 2 ) = max(x K, x K, 0) and this is the terminal payoff of one-shout option in the time interval (T 0, T 2 ] and thus by the method of [2], for T 0 t < T we have V (x, t) = Q + KK (x, t; T, T 2, K) + e r(t2 T) Q + K (x, t; T, K) + g(t, T 2 )A + K (x, t; T ). Here g(t, T 2 ) = e q(t2 T) N(d + (T, T 2 )) e r(t2 T) N(d (T, T 2 )), d ± (T, T 2 ) = [(r q)/σ ± σ/2] T 2 T. (20) In particular x 0 = x at the time t = T 0, we have V (x, T 0 ) = Q + KK (x, T 0; T, T 2, K) + e r(t2 T) Q + K (x, T 0; T, K)+ + g(t, T 2 )A + K (x, T 0; T ), x < K. (2) The case of x 0 > K. If x 0 x, then we can rewrite (9) as follows: V (x, T 2 ) = max(x K, x K, 0) = (x K) + (x x ) +. Thus in the time interval [T, T 2 ) we have V (x, t) = (x K) e r(t2 t) + Q + x (x, t; T 2, x ). In particular, x = x at the time t = T and V (x, T ) = (x K) e r(t2 T) + Q + x (x, T ; T 2, x), x x 0. Here by (4) and (5) we have where g(t, T 2 ) is as in (20). Thus Q + x (x, T ; T 2, x) = x g(t, T 2 ), V (x, T ) = x [e r(t2 T) + g(t, T 2 )] K e r(t2 T), x x 0. (22) If x 0 > x, then we can rewrite (9) as follows: V (x, T 2 ) = max(x 0 K, x K, 0) = (x 0 K) + (x x 0 ) +. Thus in the time interval [T, T 2 ) we have In particular, at the time t = T V (x, t) = (x 0 K) e r(t2 t) + Q + x 0 (x, t; T 2, x 0 ). V (x, T ) = (x 0 K) e r(t2 T) + Q + x 0 (x, T ; T 2, x 0 ), x < x 0. (23) Combining (22) with (23) to get V (x, T ) = [e r(t2 T) + g(t, T 2 )] x (x > x 0 ) e r(t2 T) K (x > x 0 ) +(x 0 K) e r(t2 T) (x < x 0 ) + Q + x 0 (x, T ; T 2, x 0 ) (x < x 0 ). Note that in the interval (T 0, T ] the underlying asset price x 0 = x(t 0 ) is a known constant. Then using the Static Replication Theorem, for t [T 0, T ), we have V (x, t) = [e r(t2 T) + g(t, T 2 )] A + x 0 (x, t; T ) K e r(t2 T) B + x 0 (x, t; T )+ +(x 0 K) e r(t2 T) B x 0 (x, t; T ) + Q + x 0x 0 (x, t; T, T 2, x 0 )

258 HYONG-CHOL O, MUN-CHOL KIM EJMAA-203/(2) = [e r(t2 T) + g(t, T 2 )] A + x 0 (x, t; T ) K e r(t2 t) + +x 0 e r(t2 T) B x 0 (x, t; T ) + Q + x 0x 0 (x, t; T, T 2, x 0 ). In particular, x 0 = x at the time t = T 0 and V (x, T 0 ) = [e r(t2 T) + g(t, T 2 )] A + x (x, T 0 ; T ) K e r(t2 T0) +x e r(t2 T) B x (x, T 0 ; T ) + Q + x x(x, T 0 ; T, T 2, x). Here by (4) and (5), we have where d ± (T 0, T ) is as in (20) and A + x (x, T 0 ; T ) = xe q(t T0) N(d + (T 0, T )), B x 0 (x, T 0 ; T ) = e r(t T0) N(d (T 0, T )), Q + x x(x, T 0 ; T, T 2, x) = g (T 0, T, T 2 ) x, g (T 0, T, T 2 ) = e q(t2 T0) N 2 ( d + (T 0, T ), d + (T 0, T 2 ); A + ) Thus we have e r(t2 T0) N 2 ( d (T 0, T ), d (T 0, T 2 ); A + ). (24) V (x, T 0 ) = G(T 0, T, T 2 ) x K e r(t2 T0), x > K. (25) Here G(T 0, T, T 2 ) = [e r(t2 T) + g(t, T 2 )] e q(t T0) N(d + (T 0, T ))+ + e r(t2 T0) N( d (T 0, T )) + g (T 0, T, T 2 ). (26) Putting the two expressions (2) and (25) of V (x, T 0 ) together, we have V (x, T 0 ) = Q + KK (x, T 0; T, T 2, K)(x < K)+ +e r(t2 T) Q + K (x, T 0; T, K)(x < K)+ +g(t, T 2 )A + K (x, T 0; T )(x < K) + G(T 0, T, T 2 )x(x > K) Ke r(t2 T0) (x > K). Thus the price of fixed time twice shout call option at t < T 0 is given by V (x, t) = Q + KKK (x, t; T 0, T, T 2, K) + e r(t2 T) Q + KK (x, t; T 0, T, K)+ +g(t, T 2 )A + KK (x, t; T 0, T ) + G(T 0, T, T 2 )A + K (x, t; T 0) Ke r(t2 T0) B + K (x, t; T 0), t < T 0. (27)

EJMAA-203/(2) HIGHER ORDER BINARY OPTIONS 259 4. Conclusions In this paper we introduced the concept of higher order binary options and then provide the pricing formulae of n-th order binaries using solving method of PDE. Then we applied them to pricing of some multiple-expiry exotic options such as Bermudan options, multi time extendable options, fixed time twice shout options and etc. Here when calculating the price of concrete multiple-expiry exotic options, the focus of discussion was on explaining how to express the expiry payoffs of the exotic option as a combination of the payoffs of some class of higher order binary options. Here we assumed that risk free rate, dividend rate and volatility are constant but we could easily extend to the case with time dependent coefficients. Acknowledgment The author would like to thank the managing editor Ahmed El-Sayed and Carlo Bianca for their help and valuable advices for this article. References [] Broadie, M. and Yamamoto Y., Application of the Fast Gauss Transform to option pricing, Management science, Vol. 49, No. 8, 07-088, 2003 [2] Buchen, P., The Pricing of dual-expiry exotics, Quantitative Finance, 4, 0-08, 2004 [3] Ingersoll, J. E., Digital contract: simple tools for pricing complex derivatives, J. Business, 73, 67-88, 2000 [4] Jiang, Li-shang, Mathematical Modeling and Methods of Option Pricing, World Scientific, Singapore, 2005 [5] Kwok, Y.K., Mathematical models of Financial Derivatives, Springer-verlag, Berlin, 55-82, 999 [6] Longstaff, F., Pricing options with extendable maturities: analysis and applications, J. Finance, 45, 935-957, 2000. [7] Rubinstein, M. and Reiner, E., Unscrambling the binary code, Risk Mag. 4, 75-83, 99 [8] Rubinstein, I. and L. Rubinstein, Partial Dierential Equations in Classical Mathematical Physics, Cambridge Univ. Press, 296-324, 998 [9] Schweizer, M., On Bermudan Options, Advances in Finance and Stochastics, in Essays in Honor of Dieter Sondermann, Springer, 257-269, 2002 [0] Thomas, B., Something to shout about, Risk Mag. 6, 56-58, 994 HYONG-CHOL O Faculty of Mathematics, Kim Il Sung University, Pyongyang, D. P. R. Korea E-mail address: ohyongchol@yahoo.com MUN-CHOL KIM Faculty of Mathematics, Kim Il Sung University, Pyongyang, D. P. R. Korea E-mail address: ohyongchol@63.com