Gains from Trade. Rahul Giri

Similar documents
Chapter 2: Gains from Trade. August 14, 2008

Chapter 3: The Ricardian Trade Model. August 14, 2008

Consumer Theory. The consumer s problem: budget set, interior and corner solutions.

GE in production economies

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

ARE 202: Welfare: Tools and Applications Spring Lecture notes 03 Applications of Revealed Preferences

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

Lecture 3 Growth Model with Endogenous Savings: Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

Microeconomics IV. First Semster, Course

Intro to Economic analysis

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

ECMB02F -- Problem Set 2 Solutions

A Closed Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model

Problem Set 2. Theory of Banking - Academic Year Maria Bachelet March 2, 2017

Trade on Markets. Both consumers' initial endowments are represented bythesamepointintheedgeworthbox,since

Hedonic Equilibrium. December 1, 2011

COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE TRADE

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM. Wanna Download D. Salvatore, International Economics for free? Gr8, visit now jblogger2016.wordpress.com

File: Ch03; Chapter 3: The Standard Theory of International Trade

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 2 Consumer Behaviour 2.1 THE CONSUMER S BUDGET

ECON Micro Foundations

Economics 101. Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand

Chapter 4 Topics. Behavior of the representative consumer Behavior of the representative firm Pearson Education, Inc.

Summer 2016 ECN 303 Problem Set #1

Microeconomics Review in a Two Good World

Topic 3: The Standard Theory of Trade. Increasing opportunity costs. Community indifference curves.

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Intermediate Microeconomics EXCHANGE AND EFFICIENCY BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD PURDUE UNIVERSITY

1. Suppose a production process is described by a Cobb-Douglas production function f(v 1, v 2 ) = v 1 1/2 v 2 3/2.

MODULE No. : 9 : Ordinal Utility Approach

U(x 1, x 2 ) = 2 ln x 1 + x 2

2. Equlibrium and Efficiency

This assignment is due on Tuesday, September 15, at the beginning of class (or sooner).

Lecture 2 Consumer theory (continued)

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

We want to solve for the optimal bundle (a combination of goods) that a rational consumer will purchase.

max x + y s.t. y + px = m

Introductory to Microeconomic Theory [08/29/12] Karen Tsai

Lecture 15 - General Equilibrium with Production

Intermediate public economics 5 Externalities Hiroaki Sakamoto

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

Module 2 THEORETICAL TOOLS & APPLICATION. Lectures (3-7) Topics

3 General Equilibrium in a Competitive Market

Chapter 2 Commodity Trade

Consumer Theory. June 30, 2013

UNIT 1 THEORY OF COSUMER BEHAVIOUR: BASIC THEMES

ECONOMICS SOLUTION BOOK 2ND PUC. Unit 2

Online Appendix for Debt Contracts with Partial Commitment by Natalia Kovrijnykh

CHAPTER 9: THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

In our model this theory is supported since: p t = 1 v t

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Final Exam Suggested Solutions

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

ECON 311 Winter Quarter, 2010 NAME: KEY Prof. Hamilton

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

ECS2601 Oct / Nov 2014 Examination Memorandum. (1a) Raymond has a budget of R200. The price of food is R20 and the price of clothes is R50.

Introduction to the Gains from Trade 1

POSSIBILITIES, PREFERENCES, AND CHOICES

Set 3. Intertemporal approach to the balance of payments

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017]

Problem Set 1 Answer Key. I. Short Problems 1. Check whether the following three functions represent the same underlying preferences

AS/ECON AF Answers to Assignment 1 October Q1. Find the equation of the production possibility curve in the following 2 good, 2 input

ECN 2001 MICROECONOMICS I SLUTSKY EQUATION Class Discussion 6 (Ch. 7) - Answer Key TRUE-FALSE

Chapter 2 Equilibrium and Efficiency

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

Exchange. M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory. Boston College. M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory (BC) Exchange 1 / 23

Demand Side: Community Indifference Curve (CIC) Shows various combinations of two goods with equivalent welfare

Homework Assignment #1: Answer Sheet

Chapter 31: Exchange

U(x 1. ; x 2 ) = 4 ln x 1

Midterm Exam No. 2 - Answers. July 30, 2003

Chapter 4. Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work- Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization. Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

Chapter 23: Choice under Risk

Solution to Homework 3 Monopolistic Competition and Increasing Returns

Econ205 Intermediate Microeconomics with Calculus Chapter 1

International Economics Lecture 2: The Ricardian Model

General Equilibrium and Economic Welfare

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Lecture 4 - Utility Maximization

PAPER NO.1 : MICROECONOMICS ANALYSIS MODULE NO.6 : INDIFFERENCE CURVES

Consumer Budgets, Indifference Curves, and Utility Maximization 1 Instructional Primer 2

Lecture Notes on The Core

ECON Chapter 4: Firm Behavior

Techniques for Calculating the Efficient Frontier

Answers to June 11, 2012 Microeconomics Prelim

Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model

Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box

(a) Ben s affordable bundle if there is no insurance market is his endowment: (c F, c NF ) = (50,000, 500,000).

Chapter 12 GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM AND WELFARE. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Graphs Details Math Examples Using data Tax example. Decision. Intermediate Micro. Lecture 5. Chapter 5 of Varian

Consider the production function f(x 1, x 2 ) = x 1/2. 1 x 3/4

Homework 3 Solutions

AS/ECON 4070 AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2001

Chapter Thirty. Production

A b. Marginal Utility (measured in money terms) is the maximum amount of money that a consumer is willing to pay for one more unit of a good (X).

The text book to this class is available at

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

Chapter 3. A Consumer s Constrained Choice

Solutions to Assignment #2

Transcription:

Gains from Trade Rahul Giri Contact Address: Centro de Investigacion Economica, Instituto Tecnologico Autonomo de Mexico (ITAM). E-mail: rahul.giri@itam.mx

An obvious question that we should ask ourselves is : Is trade beneficial; are there gains from trade? In order to better understand this question, and ultimately answer it, we will need some theoretical structure. 1 Closed Economy OR Autarky Consider an economy, which can produce two goods - good X and good Y. The economy is in autarky, i.e. it does not trade (exchange goods X and Y) with any country. Then the equilibrium would be characterized by the following conditions: 1. Consumers maximize utility: px p y = MRS = Y X. Here is an example: max {X c,y c} U(X c, Y c ) = X δ cy 1 δ c, s.t. p x X c + p y Y c I. 2. Producers maximize profits: px p y = MRT = Y X. Here is an example: max {L x,k x} s.t. X p π x = p x X p wl x rk x, = K α x L 1 α x, and max {L y,k y} s.t. Y p π y = p y Y p wl y rk y, = K β y L 1 β y. 3. Markets for the two goods clear, i.e. the demand for each good equals its supply or consumption of each good equals its production: X c = X p and Y c = Y p. Also, markets for the factor inputs clear, i.e. all inputs are fully employed. In our example this would mean that L x + L y = L and K x + K y = K, where L and K are the total amount of labor and capital, respectively, available. Figure 1 depicts this autarky equilibrium. The country s production possibilities are given by the production possibility frontier Y AX. Producers maximize profit at point A, i.e. the slope of the tangent to the production possibility frontier at point A (given by MRT) is equal to the price ratio, p a (which is px p y ). Also, the consumers maximize their utility at point A, i.e. the slope of the tangent to the indifference curve U a at point A is equal to the price ratio p a. Lastly, at point A, the consumption of each good equals its production. 2

Figure 1: Autarky Equilbrium 2 Open Economy OR Trading Economy Now, let us allow this economy to trade at a fixed world price ratio, which is denoted by p = p x/p y. So, the producers and consumers choose amounts of good X and Y to be produced and consumed optimally given the world price ratio. Thus, the equilibrium condition is: 1. Consumers maximize utility: p x p y 2. Producers maximize profits: p x p y = MRS = Y X = MRT = Y X The more important difference between autarky and trade is in terms of market clearing condition. In the presence of trade the economy is no longer constrained to consume what it produces. It can consume more than what it produces of a certain good by importing it; and similarly, it can consume less than what it produces of a good by exporting it. It is this change which results in gains from trade. So, instead of the market clearing condition we have the balanced trade condition. The balanced trade condition states that the value of sales of a country on the world market must equal its purchases. Note that the market clearing for factor inputs remains unchanged because we assume that factor inputs cannot move across countries. p x (X c X p ) + p y (Y c Y p ) = 0 The term (X c X p ) denotes the excess demand for good X. If this is negative, it implies that the country consumes less of good X than it produces, i.e. it exports good X. Likewise, if this is positive it implies that the country imports good X. Thus, another way to state the balanced 3

trade condition is that the value of exports equals the value of imports. Yet another way to express the balanced trade condition is: the value of production must be equal to value of consumption. p xx p + p yy p = p xx c + p yy c Figure 2 depicts the equilibrium with trade. Given the world price ratio, the producers maximize profits at point B, whereas the consumers maximize utility at point C. Therefore, the economy imports good X and exports good Y. Figure 2: Trade Equilbrium Note that if the world prices happen to be equal to the country s autarky prices, then the trading equilibrium would be identical to the autarky equilibrium. 2.1 Determination of World Prices As always, prices are determined by the forces of demand and supply. In the case of a trading world, world prices are determined by the world demand for and world supply of each good. When the autarky price ratio, p a is greater than the world price ratio, p, it implies that the relative price of good X (relative price of good Y ) in the country is higher (lower) than that in the world economy. This would mean the country would import good X and export good Y. In other word the excess demand for good X is positive while the excess demand for good Y is negative. Analogously, if p a < p, then good X is exported (excess demand is negative) while good Y is imported (excess demand is positive). This analysis is depicted in Figure 3. Note that if the world price ratio equals the autarky (or domestic) price ratio then the excess demand is zero. The shape of the excess demand curve is determined by the response of producers 4

Figure 3: Excess Demand for Good X and consumers when the world price ratio deviates from the autarky price ratio. When p < p a, producers will move resources away from the production of good X and towards the production of Y, thereby increasing the excess demand for X. Consumers, on the other hand, would demand more of good X as a result of the substitution effect and income effect - X is relatively cheaper at the world price ratio and the real income increases due the lower relative price of X. The two imply that the excess demand curve is negatively sloped when p < p a. Furthermore, the concavity of the production possibility frontier implies that more and more units of X would have to given up in order to produce one unit of Y. Similarly, the convexity of the indifference curve would imply a larger and larger increase in consumption of X for each unit decline in consumption of Y. This explains the convex shape of the excess demand curve when p < p a. However, when p > p a, the analysis is not so simple. The reason is that now the income effect increases the demand for both X and Y, whereas the substitution effect reduces the consumption of X. 3 General Equilibrium: Introducing A Second Country Now, let us introduce a second country, which we are going to call foreign country, F. We call the original (existing) country home, H. In Figure 4 the excess demand curve of country F is denoted by EX F and that of country H is denoted by EH X. International general equilibrium is established at that world price ratio where the excess demand for good X in country H is exactly offset by the excess demand for good X in country F. This happens at p. Notice that equilibrium world price ratio lies between the autarky price ratios of the two countries. This result holds when 5

markets are perfectly competitive. Country H, which has p a < p, will be able to find more buyers in country F and hence will export good X. Country F, which has p a > p, will face less scarcity of good X as it can import it from country H. Figure 4: International General Equilibrium Notice that in order to determine international general equilibrium we do not need to worry about market clearing for good Y. Since in equilibrium it must be that each country satisfies its trade balance condition, which implies that p xe H x + p ye H y = 0 p xe H x = p ye H y, and since p xe F x + p ye F y = 0 p xe F x = p ye F y, p xe H x = p xe F x OR E H x = E F x p ye H y = p ye F y E H y = E F y, we have that market for good Y also clears. This is nothing but the Walras Law. 4 Gains from Trade Having developed the theoretical structure, we are now in a position to answer the question we had posed in the beginning: Is trade beneficial; are there gains from trade? And the answer to the question is YES. To see this, let us look at Figure 5, which shows the autarky and trade equilibria for one country. Point A is the autarky equilibrium; p a is the autarky price ratio; and U a is the autarky 6

utility level. Now consider trade equilibria for two different world price ratios - p 1 and p 2. For both price ratios the level of utility achieved is U t. Though the diagram has been drawn so that the same free trade utility level is achieved for both price ratios, you can see it for yourself that any price ratio other than the autarky price ratio would result in a higher level of utility. Therefore, trade makes the country better off. If the world price ratio equals the autarky price ratio then the country is no worse under trade off than in autarky. In case of a two country world, the two countries experience mutual gains from trade. As shown earlier in Figure 4, in a two country world the equilibrium world price ratio lies between the two countries autarky price ratios. And since we just showed that a country gains by trading at any price ratio other than the autarky price ratio, it implies that the two countries would experience mutual gains from trade. Note that the gains from trade are independent of the direction of trade, i.e. whether a country exports good X and imports good Y or vice-versa does not have any effect on the gains from trade. Figure 5: International General Equilibrium The formal proof uses the equilibrium conditions, i.e. firms maximize profits and consumers maximize utility. So, given the world price ratio p, if firms in a country choose to produce X t p and Y t p, then profit maximization ensures that for any other feasible production bundle (X f p, Y f p ), which also includes the autarky bundle (X a p, Y a p ), the value of the equilibrium production bundle must exceed the value of any other feasible production bundle, including that of the autarky bundle. p xxp t + p yyp t p xxp f + p yyp f 7

The balanced trade condition implies that value of production equals the value of consumption. Imposing this on both sides of the above equation implies that at the world price ratio the value of consumption under trade must be greater than or equal to the value of consumption of any other feasible consumption bundle. p xx t c + p yy t c p xx f c + p yy f c As a result the free-trade consumption bundle (X t c, Y t c ) is preferred to the autarky consumption bundle (X a c, Y a c ). This is also called the Gains-from-Trade Theorem. 8