Chapter 8. Markowitz Portfolio Theory. 8.1 Expected Returns and Covariance

Similar documents
Markowitz portfolio theory

Chapter 7: Portfolio Theory

Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Risk and Reward III: Basic Markowitz Portfolio Theory

Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Risk and Reward III: Basic Markowitz Portfolio Theory

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén

Lecture IV Portfolio management: Efficient portfolios. Introduction to Finance Mathematics Fall Financial mathematics

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require

MATH362 Fundamentals of Mathematical Finance. Topic 1 Mean variance portfolio theory. 1.1 Mean and variance of portfolio return

Lecture 2: Fundamentals of meanvariance

Midterm 1, Financial Economics February 15, 2010

MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 5: Mean-variance portfolio theory

MATH4512 Fundamentals of Mathematical Finance. Topic Two Mean variance portfolio theory. 2.1 Mean and variance of portfolio return

Techniques for Calculating the Efficient Frontier

Portfolio Sharpening

QR43, Introduction to Investments Class Notes, Fall 2003 IV. Portfolio Choice

2.1 Mean-variance Analysis: Single-period Model

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Mean Variance Portfolio Theory

Chapter 8: CAPM. 1. Single Index Model. 2. Adding a Riskless Asset. 3. The Capital Market Line 4. CAPM. 5. The One-Fund Theorem

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM

Advanced Financial Economics Homework 2 Due on April 14th before class

The Markowitz framework

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Tuesday October 6 Portfolio Allocation Mean-Variance Approach

Mean-Variance Portfolio Choice in Excel

Mathematics in Finance

Limits to Arbitrage. George Pennacchi. Finance 591 Asset Pricing Theory

Optimal Portfolio Selection

Solutions to questions in Chapter 8 except those in PS4. The minimum-variance portfolio is found by applying the formula:

Introduction to Computational Finance and Financial Econometrics Introduction to Portfolio Theory

In terms of covariance the Markowitz portfolio optimisation problem is:

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets 3: Markowitz Portfolios

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

Session 8: The Markowitz problem p. 1

Mean-Variance Portfolio Theory

Quantitative Portfolio Theory & Performance Analysis

Risk and Return and Portfolio Theory

FINC 430 TA Session 7 Risk and Return Solutions. Marco Sammon

Statistics for Business and Economics

Modern Portfolio Theory

Characterization of the Optimum

Use partial derivatives just found, evaluate at a = 0: This slope of small hyperbola must equal slope of CML:

Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics. The mean-absolute deviation portfolio selection problem with interval-valued returns

Lecture 5 Theory of Finance 1

Quantitative Risk Management

Lecture Notes 9. Jussi Klemelä. December 2, 2014

THE CHINESE UNIVERSITY OF HONG KONG Department of Mathematics MMAT5250 Financial Mathematics Homework 2 Due Date: March 24, 2018

Mean-Variance Analysis

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Diversification. Finance 100

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

Chapter 2 Portfolio Management and the Capital Asset Pricing Model

Optimizing Portfolios

1.1 Interest rates Time value of money

FINC3017: Investment and Portfolio Management

9.1 Principal Component Analysis for Portfolios

Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Portfolio Models 3. Markowitz Portfolios

PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION: ANALYTICAL TECHNIQUES

Return and Risk: The Capital-Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)

Random Variables and Applications OPRE 6301

The University of Sydney School of Mathematics and Statistics. Computer Project

MATH 4512 Fundamentals of Mathematical Finance

Two Hours. Mathematical formula books and statistical tables are to be provided THE UNIVERSITY OF MANCHESTER. 22 January :00 16:00

MVS with N risky assets and a risk free asset

Lecture 3: Return vs Risk: Mean-Variance Analysis

Economics 483. Midterm Exam. 1. Consider the following monthly data for Microsoft stock over the period December 1995 through December 1996:

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

P2.T8. Risk Management & Investment Management. Jorion, Value at Risk: The New Benchmark for Managing Financial Risk, 3rd Edition.

Solutions to Problem Set 1

CHAPTER 6: PORTFOLIO SELECTION

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Financial Analysis The Price of Risk. Skema Business School. Portfolio Management 1.

CSCI 1951-G Optimization Methods in Finance Part 07: Portfolio Optimization

SDMR Finance (2) Olivier Brandouy. University of Paris 1, Panthéon-Sorbonne, IAE (Sorbonne Graduate Business School)

Financial Economics: Risk Aversion and Investment Decisions, Modern Portfolio Theory

ECMC49S Midterm. Instructor: Travis NG Date: Feb 27, 2007 Duration: From 3:05pm to 5:00pm Total Marks: 100

Financial Economics: Capital Asset Pricing Model

The Optimization Process: An example of portfolio optimization

3. Capital asset pricing model and factor models

Andreas Wagener University of Vienna. Abstract

Extend the ideas of Kan and Zhou paper on Optimal Portfolio Construction under parameter uncertainty

ON SOME ASPECTS OF PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT. Mengrong Kang A THESIS

Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice

EE/AA 578 Univ. of Washington, Fall Homework 8

Archana Khetan 05/09/ MAFA (CA Final) - Portfolio Management

An Arbitrary Benchmark CAPM: One Additional Frontier Portfolio is Sufficient

General Notation. Return and Risk: The Capital Asset Pricing Model

Slides III - Complete Markets

Chapter 8. Portfolio Selection. Learning Objectives. INVESTMENTS: Analysis and Management Second Canadian Edition

Lecture 10-12: CAPM.

Version A. Problem 1. Let X be the continuous random variable defined by the following pdf: 1 x/2 when 0 x 2, f(x) = 0 otherwise.

Session 10: Lessons from the Markowitz framework p. 1

Optimal Portfolios and Random Matrices

1 The Solow Growth Model

Probability and Stochastics for finance-ii Prof. Joydeep Dutta Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Kanpur

Discrete Random Variables

Marshall and Hicks Understanding the Ordinary and Compensated Demand

Transcription:

Chapter 8 Markowitz Portfolio Theory 8.1 Expected Returns and Covariance The main question in portfolio theory is the following: Given an initial capital V (0), and opportunities (buy or sell) in N securities for investment, how would you allocate the capital so that the return on the portfolio is optimal in certain way? More specifically, what we are looking for is a collection of weights: w 1, w 2,..., w N with w 1 + w 2 + w 3 + + w N = 1, and w i V (0) invested in security i for i = 1, 2,..., N, such that the return of the portfolio is optimal in certain sense. Our common sense suggests that you will need to take more risk if you seek high expected returns. On the other hand, investors are always risk averse in the sense that they demand the largest expected return, given the risk level, or the least possible risk, given the expected return. This leads to the concept of efficient portfolios. An efficient portfolio is a portfolio having simultaneously the smallest possible risk for its given level of expected return and the largest possible expected return for its given level of risk. The collection of all efficient portfolios is called the efficient frontier. Given the weights w 1,..., w N, the number of shares to invest in security i is and the value of the portfolio at T is n i = w iv (0) S i (0) V (T ) = N n i S i (T ) i=1 so the return of the portfolio over [0, T ] is (8.1) R [0,T ] = N w i R i (8.2) i=1 1

where R i = (S i (T ) S i (0))/S i (0) is the return of security i. We can see that the return of the portfolio is a linear combination of the returns of individual securities. The study of the portfolio return is therefore a study of various linear combinations of a collection of random variables. Sometimes it is more convenient to use the log return: ( ) Si (T ) r i = log (8.3) S i (0) which has the useful property: suppose 0 = t 0 < t 1 < t 2 < < t m = T, the log return over [0, T ] ( ) ( S(T ) S(t1 ) r = log = log S(0) S(t 0 ) S(t ) 2) S(t 1 ) S(t m ) = r (1) + r (2) + + r (m) S(t m 1 ) where r (k) is the log return over (t k 1, t k ). It should be pointed out that for short period of time, ( ) S(t + t) r(t, t + t) = log = log (R(t, t + t) + 1) R(t, t + t) (8.4) S(t) So quite often we do not distinguish between these two returns, as long as the time period is short. 8.2 Assumptions of Markowitz Theory Before we begin the discussion on the Markowitz theory, we state some assumptions for the market: Investors are rational. The supply and demand equilibrium is instantly achieved. There are no arbitrage opportunities. Access to information is available to all participants. Price moves are efficient. The market is liquid. There is no transaction cost. There are no taxes. Everyone has the same opportunity of borrowing and lending. 2

We also establish some facts about the return vector R. There is a financial implication relating to the concept of linear independence: there is no redundant security in the portfolio, that is, there is no security in the portfolio that has a return as a linear combination of returns from other securities in the portfolio. The consequence of this is that the covariance matrix V is invertible. Since V is always semi-positive definite, the additional property that V is invertible implies that V is positive definite. How do we describe the portfolio risk? We should consider the variance of the return of the portfolio, which consists of weighted sum of the securities variances and the weighted sum of securities covariances, in the form of w T V w, where w = (w 1, w 2,..., w N ) T is the weight vector. 8.3 Two-Security Portfolio Theory Assumptions: two securities with µ 1 µ 2, σ 1 < σ 2 and correlation 1 < ρ < 1, and we use [ ] [ ] µ1 σ1 µ =, V = 2 ρσ 1 σ 2 µ 2 ρσ 1 σ 2 σ2 2 (8.5) We can calculate the portfolio return and variance µ P = w 1 µ 1 + w 2 µ 2 = µ T w (8.6) σ 2 P = w 2 1σ 2 1 + w 2 2σ 2 2 + 2w 1 w 2 ρσ 1 σ 2 = w T V w (8.7) Suppose we target a portfolio with portfolio return µ P, the minimization problem is to minimize σ P subject to w T e = 1, where e = (1, 1) T and w T µ = µ P. This problem is quite easy to solve as w can be determined from the two constraints first: ( ) wµ w =, w 1 w µ = µ P µ 2 (8.8) µ µ 1 µ 2 which leads to the portfolio variance satisfying σ 2 P = Aµ 2 P + Bµ P + C (8.9) for some constants A, B, and C. It can be shown that A > 0 and C > 0, therefore if we trace all these pairs (σ P, µ P ), we will find a hyperbola. With this information we will try to determine the efficient frontier from this hyperbola. This is a hyperbola with opening to the right, and we can find the turning point, which corresponds to the absolute minimum for σ P : σ G = detc σ 2 1 + σ 2 2 2ρσ 1 σ 2, µ G = (σ2 2 ρσ 1 σ 2 )µ 1 + (σ 2 1 ρσ 1 σ 2 )µ 2 σ 2 1 + σ 2 2 2ρσ 1 σ 2 (8.10) In figure 8.1, we use an example where µ 1 = 0.1, µ 2 = 0.15, σ 1 = 0.2, σ 2 = 0.4, and ρ = 0.5, and plot the Markowitz efficient frontier. The minimum-variance portfolio has µ G = 0.1 and σ G = 0.2 which is the portfolio with w 1 = 1 and w 2 = 0. We can make the following remarks: 3

µ 0.24 0.16 0.08 global minimumvariance portfolio 0 0.08 0.16 0.24 0.32 0.4 0.48 σ -0.08 Figure 8.1: Markowitz Efficient Frontier for Two Security Portfolios The efficient frontier consists of the upper branch of the hyperbola, including the turning point. We can in general reduce risk through diversification if we have reliable correlation information. Riskless portfolios exist only in the case ρ = ±1. In the case ρ = 0, we can create portfolios with 0 < σ G min{σ 1, σ 2 } and this portfolio requires no short selling (0 < w G < 1). 8.4 Efficient Frontier for N-Securities with Short Selling Assumptions: σ i > 0 for i = 1,..., N. Expected returns µ i s are distinct, and risk levels σ i s are distinct. Unlimited short sales are allowed. Given w 1, w 2,..., w N, we can express the portfolio return and risk as µ P (w) = w T µ, σ P (w) = w T V w 4

The following will be needed in the calculations: A = e T V 1 e > 0 B = µ T V 1 e C = µ T V 1 µ > 0 AC B 2 > 0 The minimization problem we want to solve is minimize 1 2 wt V w (8.11) subject to w T e = 1 and w T µ = µ (8.12) We cannot determine w from these two constraints like in the 2-security case. In fact, there will be infinitely many portfolios satisfying these two constraints. To solve this problem, we use the Langrange multiplier approach. The Lagrange function is where L(w, λ) = f(w) + λ 1 (1 w T e) + λ 2 (µ w T µ) = f(w) + λ T h(w) (8.13) λ = ( λ1 λ 2 ) ( 1 w, h = T e µ w T µ ) (8.14) To solve the Lagrange multiplier problem, we differentiate the Lagrange function with respect to each component of w and λ. The derivatives with respect to w yields L w j = 0 V w = λ 1 e + λ 2 µ w = λ 1 V 1 e + λ 2 V 1 µ (8.15) The other two derivatives give and L λ 1 = 0 1 w T e = 0 (8.16) L λ 2 = 0 µ w T µ = 0 (8.17) Using Eq.(8.15) in these two equations, we obtain the following 2 2 system for λ 1 and λ 2 : (e T V 1 e)λ 1 + (µ T V 1 e)λ 2 = 1 (8.18) (e T V 1 µ)λ 1 + (µ T V 1 µ)λ 2 = 1 (8.19) which gives λ 1 = C µb AC B 2, 5 λ 2 = µa B AC B 2 (8.20)

Therefore the solution for w is the minimum-variance portfolio weight vector ( ) ( ) C µb µa B w µ = V 1 e + V 1 µ (8.21) AC B 2 AC B 2 The efficient frontier is determined from the hyperbola σ 2 P (µ) = Aµ2 2Bµ + C AC B 2 (8.22) Similar to the 2-security case, the turning point gives the global minimum-variance portfolio: ( 1 (σ G, µ G ) =, B ), w G = V 1 e (8.23) A A A The set F P,N = { (σ P (w), µ P (w)) : w T e = 1 } is called the feasible set, where each point corresponds to a portfolio with the constraints met. In the case N = 2, the feasible set is just a one-parameter set that is the hyperbola itself. In the cases N 3, it is represented by the region enclosed and including the hyperbola show in the following graph. 8.5 Efficient Frontier N-Securities without Short Selling If short selling is not allowed, the weight vector has additional constraints so the space of weights become W N = { w : w T e = 1, w i 0, i = 1,..., N } The optimization problems with this nonlinear constraint are much more difficult than the original optimization problem with linear constraints, and in most situations some nonlinear programming methods are needed to solve this problem. 8.6 Mutual Fund Theorem In Eq.(8.20), we wonder if there are points (σ, µ) on the efficient frontier that correspond to particular λ 1 and λ 2 values. In particular, we ask what happens when λ 1 = 0 or λ 2 = 0. In the first case, we have µ = C B = µ D, w = V 1 µ B = w D, σ 2 = C B 2 = σ2 D 6

For reasons that become clear later, we call this portfolio the diversified portfolio so the solution above is denoted by a subscript D. In the second case when we consider the portfolio that corresponds to λ 2 = 0, we have µ = B A = µ G, w = V 1 e A = w G, σ 2 = σ 2 G that means that λ 2 = 2 corresponds to the global minimum variance portfolio. Are these two portfolios so special that we can obtain any other portfolio on the frontier as a linear combination of these two portfolios? A straightforward calculation shows that given any required expected return µ, we can find a µ = A(C µb) AC B 2 such that the portfolio with the following weight vector w µ = a µ w G + (1 a µ )w D will have the desired expected return µ. This is called a mutual fund theorem or separation theorem. µ 0.24 0.16 λ_1=0 λ_2=0 0.08 0 0.08 0.16 0.24 0.32 0.4 0.48 σ -0.08 Figure 8.2: Two Mutual Fund Portfolios As it turns out, this can be achieved with any two portfolios on the frontier so the more general mutual fund theorem states: Any minimum variance portfolio w can be expressed in terms of any two distinct minimum variance portfolios w = s 1 w a + s 2 w b where w a w b, and s 1 and s 2 satisfying s 1 + s 2 = 1 can be calculated by certain formula similar to the formula for a µ. 7

The significance of the mutual fund theorem is that if you want to construct a portfolio with a required µ, you don t have to build from scratch to pick all the individual securities according to the weight w µ. All you have to do is to invest in two minimum variance portfolios (mutual funds) with the weight vectors w 1 and w 2 corresponding to two points on the frontier, and calculate the allocation s 1 and s 2 similar to a µ. In another word, you would let people do the work for you. 8

Bibliography [1] A. O. Petters and X. Dong, An Introduction to Mathematical Finance and Applications. Springer Undergraduate Texts in Mathematics and Technology, 2016. 9