MAY Carbon taxation and fiscal consolidation: the potential of carbon pricing to reduce Europe s fiscal deficits

Similar documents
MAY Carbon taxation and fiscal consolidation: the potential of carbon pricing to reduce Europe s fiscal deficits

Environmental taxes: economic principles and the UK experience

THE NEW EUROPEAN COMMISSION PROPOSAL ON COMMERCIAL FUEL DUTY

MEDIA RELEASE. The road to Copenhagen. Ends Media Contact: Michael Hitchens September 2009

New Member States Climate Protection and Economic Growth. Macroeconomic implications of a burden sharing non-ets GHG target in Bulgaria and Romania

The macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in the Netherlands Íde Kearney, 13 th September 2018.

2. Constitutional principles or rules with influence on the legislative procedure regarding non-fiscal purposed tax rules

Official Journal of the European Union L 240/27

The impact of Brexit on the UK energy sector

Ways out of the crisis

Green Taxation: a contribution to sustainability

Trends in European Household Credit

DG TAXUD. STAT/11/100 1 July 2011

Lowest implicit tax rates on labour in Malta, on consumption in Spain and on capital in Lithuania

T5-Europe The Jus Semper Global Alliance 01/09/16 1 6

EUROCHAMBRES response to the consultation on the Emission Trading System (ETS) post-2020 carbon leakage provisions

EUROPA - Press Releases - Taxation trends in the European Union EU27 tax...of GDP in 2008 Steady decline in top corporate income tax rate since 2000

CONTRIBUTION TO THE REVISION OF THE ENERGY TAX DIRECTIVE

DANISH ECONOMY SPRING 2018 SUMMARY AND RECOMMENDATIONS

Experiences with EFR in Europe

Effective Tax Rates on Employee Stock Options in the European Union and the USA

Summary SOU 2017:115

PUBLIC SPENDING ON CULTURE IN EUROPE

DECISIONS ADOPTED JOINTLY BY THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL

On the Structure of EU Financial System. by S. E. G. Lolos. Contents 1

AQA Economics A-level

Carbon taxation an instrument for developing countries to raise revenues and support national climate policies

DANISH ECONOMY SPRING 2018 SUMMARY AND RECOMMENDATIONS

Study on the Contribution of Sport to Economic Growth and Employment in the EU

This document is meant purely as a documentation tool and the institutions do not assume any liability for its contents

SETTING THE TARGETS. Figure 2 Guidebook Overview Map: Objectives and targets. Coalition for Energy Savings

Question 5: In your view, how does free allocation impact the incentives to innovate for reducing emissions? b) it largely keeps the incentive

Green Budget Europe. Environmental fiscal reform for the EU

The regional analyses

Technical report on macroeconomic Member State results of the EUCO policy scenarios

10. Taxation of multinationals and the ECJ

74 ECB THE 2012 MACROECONOMIC IMBALANCE PROCEDURE

WG5/6 Sub-Working. EU Emissions Trading Scheme - Auctioning Proceeds

The Economy Wide Benefits of Increasing the Proportion of Students Achieving Year 12 Equivalent Education

Joint Research Centre

Government Response to the Environmental Audit Committee's Report on the Energy Intensive Industries Compensation Scheme

CARBON PRICING PRINCIPLES. Prepared by the ICC Commission on Environment and Energy

The Effects of the Ecological Tax Reform in Germany

OCR Economics A-level

STATISTICS. Taxing Wages DIS P O NIB LE E N SPECIAL FEATURE: PART-TIME WORK AND TAXING WAGES

We are IntechOpen, the world s leading publisher of Open Access books Built by scientists, for scientists. International authors and editors

Respons. Introduction. Our reference: NA. Directorate-General for Competition Unit for State aids Energy and Environment.

Eurozone Ernst & Young Eurozone Forecast Winter edition December 2012

Household Balance Sheets and Debt an International Country Study

Key Trends of Energy Transition in the EU-28 Region

ETS PHASE IV REVIEW AMENDMENTS OPTIONS CEMENT INDUSTRY S VIEWS

The CRC Energy Efficiency Scheme

The Stability and Growth Pact Status in 2001

Potential value of processing of telecom metadata for the European economy

Taxation trends in the European Union Further increase in VAT rates in 2012 Corporate and top personal income tax rates inch up after long decline

Measuring European Construction Output: Problems and possible solutions

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES. Recommendation for a COUNCIL OPINION

GHG EMISSIONS TAX RATIONALE AND DESIGN ELEMENTS GRZEGORZ PESZKO, LEAD ECONOMIST, WORLD BANK

Olivier Blanchard Economic Counsellor and Director of the Research Department, International Monetary Fund

Fiscal Consolidation Strategy: An Update for the Budget Reform Proposal of March 2013

Eurozone. EY Eurozone Forecast March 2015

EU BUDGET FOR EVERYONE

Treatment of Losses by Network Operators an ERGEG Position Paper for public consultation

Carbon Market Institute. Submission - Emissions Reduction Fund: Safeguard Mechanism

Mobilizing Resources for Climate Finance

Eurozone Ernst & Young Eurozone Forecast Spring edition March 2013

CONTRIBUTED PAPER FOR THE 2007 CONFERENCE ON COR- PORATE R&D (CONCORD) Drivers of corporate R&D investments, Parallel Session 3B

Environmental taxes in Country Specific Recommendations for Denmark

10 Ways to Kick-start the Economy

Fortum as a tax payer 2017

Our inaugural Fiscal risks report. Robert Chote Chairman

Green Budget Europe ENVIRONMENTAL FISCAL REFORM: KEY FOR THE EUROPEAN SEMESTER TO DELIVER

Budget Analysis May 2012

Summary. 1. Aviation taxation. February a briefing by

OECD Policy Instruments for the Environment

Erste Group Bank AG H results presentation 30 July 2010, Vienna

Consultation on revision of the EU Emission Trading System (EU ETS) Directive

PEPANZ Submission: New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme Review 2015/16

Questions and Answers 1 on the Commission's decision on national implementation measures (NIMs)

Pensions and other age-related expenditures in Europe Is ageing too expensive?

Spring Forecast: slowly recovering from a protracted recession

ILO World of Work Report 2013: EU Snapshot

The role of regional, national and EU budgets in the Economic and Monetary Union

GA No Report on the empirical assessment of monitoring and enforcement of EU ETS regulation

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION

BARRIERS TO TRADE AND THE EFFECTIVENESS OF POTENTIAL TRADE ARRANGEMENTS AFTER BREXIT

More Jobs, a Growing Economy, and a Stronger Middle Class

Developments in the Croatian Tax System

Briefing on request for VAT exemption on sanitary towels

Eurozone Ernst & Young Eurozone Forecast June 2013

After Fukushima: A New Role for Energy Taxes in Switzerland

Consultation on revision of the EU Emission Trading System (EU ETS) Directive

The impact of the European System of Accounts 2010 on euro area macroeconomic statistics

5+1 charts on how Hungary can catch up with France

Carbon Fund Annual Report

Taxation, Innovation and the Environment:

Some Basic Facts about Government Expenditures and Taxation in Canada. Econ 525

Synergies and Trade-offs between Energy Efficiency and Sustainablity Indicators: The EU-28 Study of Sustainable Energy Use

COST IMPACTS OF REDUCING SMOKING PREVALENCE THROUGH TOBACCO TAXATION IN

GUIDELINES FOR CENTRAL GOVERNMENT DEBT MANAGEMENT 2018

Transcription:

MAY 2012 Carbon taxation and fiscal consolidation: the potential of carbon pricing to reduce Europe s fiscal deficits

An appropriate citation for this report is: Vivid Economics, Carbon taxation and fiscal consolidation: the potential of carbon pricing to reduce Europe s fiscal deficits, report prepared for the European Climate Foundation and Green Budget Europe, May 2012 A collaboration between the European Climate Foundation and Green Budget Europe, in association with Vivid Economics. Prepared for submission to the Grantham Institute at the London School of Economics.

Executive summary The benefits of carbon pricing for closing deficits The overriding challenge for many European governments today is to reduce major fiscal deficits with the least collateral damage to the economy. This report shows that carbon fiscal measures may raise significant revenues while having a less detrimental macro-economic impact than other tax options. This gives them an important potential role in fiscal policy; a role that is currently widely overlooked. This benefit arising from carbon fiscal measures goes beyond the usual arguments in their favour namely that they are crucial, cost effective instruments to reduce Europe s greenhouse gas emissions. Carbon fiscal measures offer two specific opportunities for governments: 1. They can introduce and/or increase national taxes on energy consumption. We explore these national tax reform opportunities through case studies of Hungary, Poland and Spain. These countries were selected for their fiscal deficits, their diverse locations, their different sizes, as well as for the range of economies that they represent. The analysis of these three countries may therefore provide insights for other member states even though particular circumstances, and hence policy, vary from member state to member state. 2. They can support reform of the European Union Emission Trading System with the potential to generate significant revenues. We also present a detailed review of the existing carbon energy tax structure in the following six countries: France, Germany, Greece, Italy, Portugal, and the UK. Energy taxes: an attractive way to raise fiscal revenues In each of the three countries that we examine Spain, Poland and Hungary modelling suggests that energy taxes would cause less economic harm per unit of revenue than direct (i.e. income) or indirect taxes, while also producing other benefits. Direct taxes could have twice as much negative impact on GDP as energy taxes which raise the same revenues between 2013 and 2020. Indirect taxes (VAT) appear less damaging than direct taxes but still tend to perform slightly worse than energy taxes. In many cases, a key factor is that energy taxes lead to a reduction in imported energy. In other words, the decline in production and economic activity takes place outside the country (and in these cases often outside Europe). This has the added benefit of improving energy security. All taxes have similar employment impacts, although indirect taxes (VAT), which particularly penalise the retail sector (which is labour-intensive), tend to perform worst. Of course, energy taxes are also much more effective at reducing emissions. By 2020, the packages examined cause CO 2 emissions to fall by between 1.5 and 2.5 per cent relative to the baseline. The other taxes make no meaningful impact on emissions. A valid concern regarding energy taxes is that they are regressive. Our analysis confirms this in one respect: energy taxes reduce the spending power of lower income households and other disadvantaged groups by proportionally more than the spending power of higher income households. However, the evidence also indicates that lower income and disadvantaged households may suffer even greater losses under direct or indirect taxes, as the greater squeeze on overall economic activity affects all social groups, including the most disadvantaged. The report suggests that concerns over the regressive impact of energy taxes can be alleviated, with preferred options likely to vary from country to country. None is perfect, but each largely resolves the problem by using a small proportion of the revenue raised to off-set negative impacts on low income groups. 1

Scope for improving tax design The amount of revenue that can be raised depends on which energy taxes are raised and by how much. The impacts described above reflect packages of reform chosen on the basis of a detailed review of the current profile of national energy taxes in Spain, Poland and Hungary. The same detailed review of national energy tax profiles was completed for a further six European countries: France, Germany, Greece, Italy, Portugal, and the UK. For each one, we converted current energy taxes into a rate per tonne of carbon dioxide. Economic analysis suggests that for maximum effectiveness and efficiency, the implicit rate should be sufficiently high that the tax induces changes in behaviour and be sufficiently similar across sources of emissions to ensure that behaviour changes wherever it is most cost effective to do so. In addition, taxes should focus on economic activity that is not covered by the EU ETS, to prevent double-burdening certain activities. In this way, the costs of raising revenue can be kept minimal. 1 transport the implied CO 2 tax rate on diesel is much lower than that for petrol, despite its higher CO 2 content. If progress was made towards removing these discrepancies (as is broadly suggested by current proposals for reform of the European Union Energy Tax Directive) the effect would be to raise substantial amounts of revenue: between 1.0 per cent and 1.3 per cent of GDP in 2020 could be raised in each of the three countries (focussing on sectors not covered by the EU ETS). 2 This equates to more than 10 billion per annum in Spain, more than 5 billion per annum in Poland and more than 1 billion per annum in Hungary. With regards to current budget deficits, and in light of the need for fiscal consolidation, these revenues can make a significant contribution: in the short run (by 2013), they could reduce deficits by 4 (Poland) to 8 (Hungary and Spain) per cent of 2011 deficits; over the medium run (by 2020) the annual reduction increases to: 50 per cent of the 2011 deficit for Hungary, 25 per cent for Poland, and 15 per cent for Spain. Judged against these two criteria, the report finds that current fiscal practice is far from optimal. In the three chosen countries, significant sources of emissions, including emissions from household energy consumption, are not taxed at all. Moreover, the pattern of taxes on commercial and industrial energy use is highly irregular, and in As an illustration of the scope for energy tax reform, figure 1 shows the average implied CO 2 tax rate on energy consumption in nine countries and a measure of the variation in rates within the country. To our knowledge, this is the first time these calculations have been made. Figure 1. Energy taxation: there is significant variation both within and between European countries Note: Source: Yellow bars indicate the weighted average for each country; blue boxes indicate the size of a standard deviation for each country, not minimum and maximum tax rates. PPP is purchasing power parity and takes account of the relative purchasing power of a euro/domestic currency converted to euros at market exchange rates. Vivid Economics 1 As discussed in the body of the text, there are other externalities that can also justify energy taxation, most notably in relation to the consumption of transport fuels. The tax rates across fuels should reflect the magnitude of the externalities they cause. 2 For illustration, 1 per cent of EU-27 GDP in 2011 was approximately 130 billion; 1 per cent of German GDP approximately 26 billion; 1 per cent of UK GDP approximately 15 billion; and 1 per cent of French GDP approximately 20 billion. 2

The figure shows substantial variation in tax rates between and within countries. Between countries, Portugal taxes CO 2 more heavily than any other country, at around 50 per cent more than Poland or France. Within countries, the discrepancy in implied carbon tax rates is largest within the UK and Greece. This suggests further significant revenue raising potential from energy taxes in these countries as well. EU ETS reform is a similar opportunity There is a similar opportunity to reduce deficits through reform of the EU Emissions Trading System (EU ETS). Up to now, the debate on whether the EU should increase its emissions reduction target 1 has centred on whether the additional emissions reductions are worth the additional cost, given the wider international context. An alternative perspective is to ask whether the macroeconomic impacts of raising government revenues in this way are better or worse than the alternatives. However, without a global agreement on emissions reduction which requires other economies to introduce comparable measures, further tightening of the cap will be hard to implement without additional measures. Some sectors have legitimate concerns about carbon leakage and declining competitiveness. Adjustments to the prices of traded goods, based on a measure of the greenhouse gases embodied in the goods, sometimes known as border carbon adjustments (BCAs), could alleviate these concerns. At present concerns over competitiveness are addressed by giving free allowances to potentially affected sectors. As mentioned above, a fiscal prize of up to 30 billion is thereby foregone; a cost which might be avoided partly by replacing free allocation with BCAs as the policy instrument to address competitiveness issues. BCAs could also preserve competitiveness more effectively than free allowance allocation: the modelling indicates that BCAs might cut output losses from carbon leakage in affected sectors by up to two thirds. This report examines that question, and yields important insights. First, substantial revenues are available. By tightening the EU ETS cap and thus raising the carbon price, a further 30bn (0.20 per cent of 2013 EU GDP) of additional auction revenues might be raised across Europe on average per annum. Second, the macroeconomic costs of raising revenue in this way may be smaller than the costs of levying direct taxes of the same size: over the period 2013-2020 modelling analysis suggests that the cumulative loss in GDP from raising direct taxes could be around 50 per cent greater than from reforming the EU ETS. Employment losses from a tightening of the EU ETS might be only around one third of those that would result from higher direct taxes. BCAs in their currently-discussed forms are not welcomed by some of Europe s major trading partners. Their concerns may be addressed through better design. This report proposes a new smart form of BCAs. Smart BCAs are calibrated to a trading partner s income level and take into account capacity to mitigate emissions. They also benchmark against other countries, comparing their carbon prices. The report explains some relatively simple mechanisms that could achieve these benefits. Beyond 2020: Longer term EU ETS reform options The main focus of this report is on options for deficit reduction in the period to 2020. But carbon pricing can be used to raise revenues beyond 2020, indeed through to 2050. The EU s ambitious objectives for 80-95 per cent decarbonisation by 2050 will involve further tightening of the EU ETS cap. Already, the EU ETS Directive states the intention of moving to full auctioning of allowances by 2027. This is a significant fiscal prize: were it possible to introduce full auctioning earlier, by 2020, the amount of revenues raised by the EU ETS in 2020 would be more than 30 billion greater per annum (around 0.17 per cent of 2020 EU GDP). 2 1 From a 20 per cent reduction of greenhouse gases compared to 1990 levels by 2020, to a 30 per cent reduction by 2020. 2 In the case that the EU ETS cap was also tightened. 3

Company Profile Vivid Economics is a leading strategic economics consultancy with global reach. We strive to create lasting value for our clients, both in government and the private sector, and for society at large. We are a premier consultant in the policy-commerce interface and resource- and environment-intensive sectors, where we advise on the most critical and complex policy and commercial questions facing clients around the world. The success we bring to our clients reflects a strong partnership culture, solid foundation of skills and analytical assets, and close cooperation with a large network of contacts across key organisations. Contact us 306 Macmillan House Paddington Station London W2 1FT T: +44 (0)844 8000 254 E: enquiries@vivideconomics.com