Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls

Similar documents
Labor-dependent Capital Income Taxation That Encourages Work and Saving

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals

WORKING PAPER NO OPTIMAL CAPITAL INCOME TAXATION WITH HOUSING. Makoto Nakajima Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ON THE OPTIMAL PROGRESSIVITY OF THE INCOME TAX CODE. Juan Carlos Conesa Dirk Krueger

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO)

Retirement Financing: An Optimal Reform Approach. QSPS Summer Workshop 2016 May 19-21

Optimal Public Debt with Life Cycle Motives

Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System

Aging, Social Security Reform and Factor Price in a Transition Economy

No. 2006/21 Taxing Capital? Not a Bad Idea After All! Juan Carlos Conesa, Sagiri Kitao, and Dirk Krueger

The Budgetary and Welfare Effects of. Tax-Deferred Retirement Saving Accounts

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TAXING CAPITAL? NOT A BAD IDEA AFTER ALL! Juan Carlos Conesa Sagiri Kitao Dirk Krueger

This work is distributed as a Discussion Paper by the STANFORD INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC POLICY RESEARCH

Optimal Capital Income Taxes in an Infinite-lived Representative-agent Model with Progressive Tax Schedules

Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HIGH MARGINAL TAX RATES ON THE TOP 1%? LESSONS FROM A LIFE CYCLE MODEL WITH IDIOSYNCRATIC INCOME RISK

High Marginal Tax Rates on the Top 1%?

Home Production and Social Security Reform

Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Inflation, Nominal Debt, Housing, and Welfare

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

High Marginal Tax Rates on the Top 1%?

The Macroeconomics e ects of a Negative Income Tax

A Historical Welfare Analysis of Social Security: Who Did the Program Benefit?

. Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective. May 10, 2013

Aging and Pension Reform in a Two-Region World: The Role of Human Capital

Capital Income Tax Reform and the Japanese Economy (Very Preliminary and Incomplete)

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Can Removing the Tax Cap Save Social Security?

Optimal Public Debt with Life Cycle Motives

CAN CAPITAL INCOME TAX IMPROVE WELFARE IN AN INCOMPLETE MARKET ECONOMY WITH A LABOR-LEISURE DECISION?

Welfare-maximizing tax structure in a model with human capital

Wealth inequality, family background, and estate taxation

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Heterogeneity in Labor Supply Elasticity and Optimal Taxation

Reforming the Social Security Earnings Cap: The Role of Endogenous Human Capital

Optimal Capital Taxation with Entrepreneurial Risk

The Japanese saving rate between 1960 and 2000: productivity, policy changes, and demographics

Health Insurance Reform: The impact of a Medicare Buy-In

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Fiscal Cost of Demographic Transition in Japan

Optimal Progressive Income Taxation in a Bewley-Grossman Framework

Optimal Public Debt with Life Cycle Motives

The Macroeconomics of Universal Health Insurance Vouchers

Unfunded Pension and Labor Supply: Characterizing the Nature of the Distortion Cost

Taxing capital along the transition - Not a bad idea after all?

Fiscal Policy in an Incomplete Markets Economy

Health Insurance and Tax Policy

Essays on Optimal Taxation and the Life Cycle

The Japanese Saving Rate between : Productivity, Policy Changes, and Demographics

Social Security Reforms in a Life Cycle Model with Human Capital Accumulation and Heterogeneous Agents

TAKE-HOME EXAM POINTS)

A Historical Welfare Analysis of Social Security: Who Did the Program Benefit?

The Macroeconomics Effects of a Negative Income Tax

Can Removing the Tax Cap Save Social Security?

Altruism. Fang Yang. State University of New York at Albany. March Abstract

Demographic Change, Relative Factor Prices, International Capital Flows, and Their Differential Effects on the Welfare of Generations 1

Elimination of Social Security in a Dynastic Framework

A simple wealth model

Public Investment, Debt, and Welfare: A Quantitative Analysis

Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Understanding the Distributional Impact of Long-Run Inflation. August 2011

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

Higher Taxes at the Top: The Role of Entrepreneurs

Policy Uncertainty and the Cost of Delaying Reform: A case of aging Japan

APPENDIX A: Income inequality literature review

Capital Taxation, Intermediate Goods, and Production

OPTIMAL CAPITAL TAXATION WITH INCOMPLETE MARKETS AND SCHUMPETERIAN GROWTH

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation

Endogenous employment and incomplete markets

Amaintained assumption of nearly all macroeconomic analysis is that

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 9: Dynamic Taxation II Optimal Capital Taxation

Policy e ects of the elasticity of substitution across labor types in life cycle models

Optimal Capital Income Taxes in A Representative-agent Model with Progressive Tax Schedules

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ON THE OPTIMAL PROVISION OF SOCIAL INSURANCE: PROGRESSIVE TAXATION VERSUS EDUCATION SUBSIDIES IN GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM

The Lost Generation of the Great Recession

Optimal Public Debt with Life Cycle Motives

Fiscal Policy in an Incomplete Markets Economy

Optimal Spatial Taxation

Asian Development Bank Institute. ADBI Working Paper Series IMPACTS OF UNIVERSAL HEALTH COVERAGE: FINANCING, INCOME INEQUALITY, AND SOCIAL WELFARE

Intergenerational transfers, tax policies and public debt

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

The Implications of a Graying Japan for Government Policy

Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete

Social Security, Life Insurance and Annuities for Families

A Historical Welfare Analysis of Social Security: Whom Did the Program Benefit?

Tobin s Q and Inequality

Capital Taxation with Entrepreneurial Risk

Retirement Financing: An Optimal Reform Approach

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

Intergenerational Policy and the Measurement of the Tax Incidence of Unfunded Liabilities

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth

Retirement Financing: An Optimal Reform Approach

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

On the Optimality of Age-Dependent Taxes and the Progressive U.S. Tax System

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

Transcription:

Lucas (1990), Supply Side Economics: an Analytical Review, Oxford Economic Papers When I left graduate school, in 1963, I believed that the single most desirable change in the U.S. structure would be the taxation of capital gains as ordinary income. I now believe that neither capital gains nor any of the income from capital should be taxed at all. Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls Those responsible for shaping the best possible tax system for the nation would be wise to give serious attention to the relatively new principle of public finance demonstrated here: taxing capital income is a bad idea.

Taxing Capital Income: Not a Bad Idea After All! Juan Carlos Conesa Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Sagiri Kitao New York University Dirk Krueger Goethe University Frankfurt Murcia, June 2007

Introduction In models with infinitely lived households capital taxes should be zero in the long run Chamley (1985), Judd (1985) Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (2000) show that this result is very robust: some heterogeneity, endogenous growth, open economy But, in OG, capital income taxes only zero in general if taxes can be conditioned on age Erosa and Gervais (2002), Garriga (2003)

Our own previous work Conesa and Krueger (2006): optimal tax code in a large scale OG is roughly flat with substantial deduction Intuition: deduction provides desired level of insurance / redistribution, flat minimizes distortionary impact Question: Does the optimal tax system mimic zero capital income taxes? This paper: allow capital income to be tax differently than labor income

Goal and main assumptions of this paper Quantitatively characterize optimal capital and labor income tax code when Households are finitely lived Income heterogeneity and risk induce insurance and redistribution role of tax code Taxes have incentive effects on labor supply and capital accumulation

Main findings Optimal capital income tax is high: 36% Main driving force: life-cycle structure Optimal labor income tax is flat with deductible Main driving force: labor supply incentives vs insurance and redistribution

Related Literature on Optimal Taxation Equity vs. labor supply efficiency: Mirrlees (1971). Labor supply efficiency vs. social insurance: Mirrlees (1974), Varian (1980), (and with savings) Reiter (2004) Optimal capital taxation: Judd (1985), Chamley (1986), Jones et al (1997) vs. Aiyagari (1995), Imrohoroglu (1998), Golosov et al. (2002), Erosa and Gervais (2002), Garriga (2003).

Related Literature Desirability of flat taxes: Hall and Rabushka (1995), Saez (2001). Quantitative analyses of tax reform with heterogeneous population: Ventura (1999), Castañeda et al. (1999), Domeij and Heathcote (2001). Optimal progressivity of the tax code: Conesa and Krueger (2006), Bohacek and Kejak (2004)

Outline of the talk Model description The computational exercise Results: - Separable preferences - Non-separable preferences and labor supply elasticity - The role of government debt Conclusions

The model: overview Large-scale OG model with uninsurable mortality and labor productivity risk. Endogenous labor supply and capital accumulation. Flexible income tax system that allows progressivity and discrimination between labor and capital income. Balanced budget of the government (see sensitivity analysis)

The Model: Demographics J overlapping generations. In each period a continuum of new agents is born, whose mass grows at rate n. Conditional survival probability from age j to age j + 1 equals ϕ j with ϕ J = 0. Law of large numbers apply. Exogenous retirement age jr < J

The Model: Endowments Households start life with zero assets and have one unit of time every period until age jr 1. Households productivity is given by αiεη: j - α i is a fixed effect realized at labor market entry (ability, education, ). Probability of drawing α i is p i. - { ε } j is deterministic average age productivity profile - η E = { η } 1, η2,..., ηn is stochastic and follows Markov chain with transition matrix Q( η, η ). Labor market entry at η = η

The Model: Preferences Benchmark: Preferences over { } 1, J j j j c l = given by 1 1 1 1 ( (1 ) ) 1 1 J j j j j c l E γ γ σ β σ = Sensitivity analysis to study quantitative impact of labor supply elasticity 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 2 (1 ) 1 1 J j j j j c l E σ σ β φ σ σ = +

The Model: Technology Aggregate production function Y = F( K, N ) t t t Aggregate resource constraint Ct + Kt+ 1 (1 δ ) Kt + Gt F( Kt, Nt)

The Model: Government Policy Exogenous sequence of government expenditures { G } t t= 1 Social security system: Exogenous payroll tax τ ss, t, maximum taxable income y t and lump-sum benefits SS t. Set to satisfy period-by-period budget balance. Exogenous proportional consumption tax rates τ ct, Endogenous income tax code. Anonymity (taxes can only depend on income), but discrimination by source of income.

The Model: Market Structure Households can trade one-period risk free asset (physical capital). Tight borrowing constraints: agents cannot borrow. Idiosyncratic risks not directly insurable (only self-insurance). Accidental bequests are lump-sum redistributed among households alive tomorrow.

The Model: Competitive Equilibrium At any given time an agent is characterized by assets, a t, idiosyncratic labor productivity η t, the group it belongs to, i, and age, j. Individual state is ( a, η, i, j). t t Aggregate state is cross-sectional distribution Φ t( at, ηt, i, j) over individual states.

The Model: Household Problem t j t ca, ', l { } + 1 v ( a, η, i, j) = max u( c, l) + βϕ v ( a, η, i, j+ 1) Q( η, η ) { } s.. t (1 + τ ) c+ a wαεηl τ min wαεηl, y + (1 + r)( a + TR ) ct, t i j sst, t i j t t t t ( { }) K αεη τ ( ), αεη N T w l 0.5 min w l, y T r( a + TR ), j < j t t i j ss t t i j t t t t t r (1 + τ ) c+ a SS + (1 + r)( a + TR ) T r( a + TR ), j j ( ) K ct, t t t t t t t t r c 0, a 0,0 l 1.

The Computational Experiments * N K Define the Optimal Tax Code T = ( T, T ) as the tax code (within the parametric class chosen) with highest ex-ante steady state expected lifetime utility of a newborn: SWF ( T ) = v T( a, η, i, j ) d ΦT {( a, η, i, j): a= 0, η= η, j= 1} where Φ T is the stationary distribution associated with tax system T and v T is corresponding value function. In addition: Compare allocations and welfare under optimal tax code with that of benchmark economy (calibrated to US).

Calibration: Demographics Table I: Demographics Parameters Parameter Value Target Ret. Age: j r 46(65) Comp.Retirement Max Age: J 81(100) Certain Death Surv. Prob: ϕ j Bell and Miller (2002) Data Pop. Growth: n 1.1% Data

Calibration: Labor Productivity Labor productivity is given by αiεη j Deterministic age profile { ε } j j= 1 J : Hansen (1993) σα Two ability types of mass 0.5, α1 = e, α2 = e σ α

Stochastic component η follows 7 state Markov chain that approximates an AR(1) process with persistence parameter ρ and unconditional variance σ 2 2 3 free parameters to calibrate: σα, ρ, σ η chosen to match empirical facts reported by Storesletten et al. (2004): 2 η Age 22 cross-sectional variance of labor income: 0.2735 This variance increases linearly as a function of age Age 60 cross-sectional variance of labor income: 0.9 2 2 ( σ, ρ, σ )=(0.14,0.98,0.0289) α η

Calibration: Preferences Benchmark period utility function: γ 1 γ 1 σ ( cj (1 lj) ) 1 1 σ Table II: Preference Parameters Parameter Value Target Discount factor: β 1.001 K / Y = 2.7 Cons. share: γ 0.377 Avg. Hours=1/3 Curvature: σ 4.0 Fixed (IES 0.5) Frisch Elasticity of Labor Supply 1

Calibration: Technology Cobb-Douglas production function depreciation rate δ Y = K N with constant α 1 α t t t Table III: Technology Parameters Parameter Value Target Capital share: α 0.36 Data Deprec. rate: δ 0.0833 I/Y=0.255

Calibration: Government Policy Consumption tax rate is τ c = 5%, as estimated in Mendoza et al. (1994). Government spending level G is set so that in stationary equilibrium G/Y=17%. Social security payroll tax is set to 12.4% ss τ = (up to income of $87,000). Benefits determined by budget balance of social security system.

Calibration: Government Policy Income tax code: functional form from Gouveia and Strauss (1994): ( ) 1/ a a 1 1 T( y) = a 0 y y + a 2 Note: nests poll tax a 1 = 1; purely proportional tax a 1 0; and large number of progressive tax systems (for a 1 > 0). Benchmark: Gouveia and Strauss approximate the current US income tax code by a0 = 0.258, a1 = 0.768 ( a 2 depends on the units of measurement)

Results: The Optimal Tax Code Optimal tax code is N N N T = ( a, a ) = (0.23,7) 0 1 K K K 0 1 T = ( a, a ) = (0.36,0.0) Represents roughly a proportional tax with marginal labor income tax rate of 23% and deduction of 17% of per capita GDP ($6,000 relative to an average income of $35,000), and a proportional tax on capital income of 36%

Table IV: Comparison across Tax Codes. Non-Separable Preferences Variable Benchmark Optimal Avg. Hours 33.3-0.56% Labor Supply - -0.11% Cap. Stock - -6.64% Output - -2.51% Consumption - -1.63% Gini Wealth 0.636 0.659 Gini Cons. 0.273 0.269 Eq.Var.Cons. - 1.33%

Discussion of the Results: Decomposing the Welfare Gains Total Welfare Gain 1.33% Total 1.29% Consumption Level -1.63% Distribution 2.97% Total 0.04% Leisure Level 0.41% Distribution -0.37%

Discussion of the Results: The Role of Various Sources of Uncertainty Elements E1 E2 E3 BENCH Annuities yes no no no idios. Risk no no no yes type heterog. no no yes yes K tax 36.5% 29.7% 32.0% 36.0% L tax 16.0% 19.4% 18.3% 23.0% L deductible $ 0 $ 0 $ 3,200 $ 6,000 Capital Income Taxes still High! Davila et al (2005)

Robustness of the Results: Separable Preferences E J β j 1 c (1 l ) + φ 1 σ 1 σ 1 σ1 1 σ2 j j j= 1 1 2 We fix σ1 = 2, σ 2 = 3 consistent with empirically estimated Intertemporal Elasticities of Substitution in Consumption and a Frisch Labor Supply elasticity around 2/3. Calibrate β = 0.9717, φ = 1.92 in order to match same empirical targets for K/Y and average hours worked, as before.

Optimal tax code is T = ( a, a ) = (0.34,18) N N N 0 1 K K K 0 1 T = ( a, a ) = (0.21,0.001) Again, labor income tax is roughly a flat tax of 34% with a deduction of $9,000 (relative to average income of $35,000). Optimal capital income tax is a proportional tax of 21%. Compared to benchmark: higher marginal tax on labor income, higher deduction, and lower capital income tax.

Table V: Comparison across Tax Codes. Separable Preferences Variable Benchmark Optimal Avg. Hours 33.3 32.4 Labor Supply - -2.14% Cap. Stock - -7.44% Output - -4.08% Consumption - -3.75% Gini Wealth 0.697 0.699 Gini Cons. 0.288 0.271 Eq.Var.Cons. - 3.40%

Our results vs theory Comparison to Erosa and Gervais (2002) and Garriga (2003): Standard OG with tax instruments ( τ, τ, τ, ) c l k B Us: τ c given, B=0, idiosyncratic risk and ex-ante heterogeneity, PAYG social security Optimal k τ =0 in Steady State if Preferences are Separable... But need 2*GDP of NEGATIVE DEBT!!! Little need for any form of taxation.

Conclusion: What we learned High Capital Income Taxes are optimal, even if labor supply elasticity is small. Life cycle structure drives results Desire for insurance and redistribution calls for progressive labor income taxes Is taxing capital really a bad idea?