Political Economy of Economic Sanctions. By William H. Kaempfer and Anton D. Lowenberg. Presented by Celene Chan and Azadeh Khoshaein

Similar documents
THE APPLICATION OF ESSENTIAL ECONOMIC PRINCIPLES IN ARMED FORCES

SOLUTIONS. ECO 209Y - L5101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY Term Test 2 LAST NAME FIRST NAME STUDENT NUMBER. University of Toronto January 26, 2005 INSTRUCTIONS:

Chapter 3. National Income: Where it Comes from and Where it Goes

University of Toronto July 21, 2010 ECO 209Y L0101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #2

University of Toronto January 25, 2007 ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #2 L0101 L0201 L0401 L5101 MW MW 1-2 MW 2-3 W 6-8

University of Toronto July 27, 2006 ECO 209Y - L5101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #2 DO NOT WRITE IN THIS SPACE. Part I /30.

10. Fiscal Policy and the Government Budget

Summary of Macroeconomic Models ECS2602 C O M P I L E D B Y S K E N N E D Y- PA L M E R & T U Y S ( R E V I S E D F E B R U A RY )

Copenhagen Business School, Birthe Larsen, Exam in Macroeconomics, IB and IBP, Answers.

ECO 209Y - L5101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #2

Examination information

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 2 with Solutions

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 10, Question 1

Retake Exam in Macroeconomics, IB and IBP

Chapter 7. Employment protection

Chapter 9 Nontariff Barriers and the New Protectionism

Pre-Test Chapter 9 ed17

PAPER No. : 4 Basic Macroeconomics MODULE No. : 2- Circular Flow of Income and Expenditure

Final Term Papers. Fall 2009 (Session 03a) ECO401. (Group is not responsible for any solved content) Subscribe to VU SMS Alert Service

University of Toronto July 15, 2016 ECO 209Y L0101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #2

Intermediate Macroeconomics-ECO 3203

download instant at

TAMPERE ECONOMIC WORKING PAPERS NET SERIES

UNIT II: THE KEYNESIAN THEORY OF DETERMINATION OF NATIONAL INCOME

Problem Set #1: The Economy in the Long Run Econ 100B: Intermediate Macroeconomics

a) We can calculate Private and Public savings as well as investment as a share of GDP using (1):

Use the following to answer question 15: AE0 AE1. Real expenditures. Real income. Page 3

The Open Economy. (c) Copyright 1998 by Douglas H. Joines 1

5. What is the Savings-Investment Spending Identity? Savings = Investment Spending for the economy as a whole

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls UNIVERSITY OF LONDON

Econ 3 Practice Final Exam

IPR Protection in the High-Tech Industries: A Model of Piracy

MARKING SCHEME. Economics ( ) - SET 2 SECTION-A. Q.No. Value points to answers Marks Allocation SECTION A : MICRO ECONOMICS

Globalization. University of California San Diego (UCSD) Catherine Laffineur.

The Goods Market and the Aggregate Expenditures Model

Econ 223 Lecture notes 2: Determination of output and income Classical closed economy equilibrium

International Linkages and Domestic Policy

ECON Drexel University Summer 2008 Assignment 2. Due date: July 29, 2008

ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY. Term Test #3. February 12, 2018

Problem Set 7 - Answers. Topics in Trade Policy

why how price quantity

GLOBAL MARKETS IN ACTION

3. OPEN ECONOMY MACROECONOMICS

CHAPTER 1 Introduction

Final Examination Semester 2 / Year 2012

ECON Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory

Chapter 7 Economic Growth and International Trade

2. THE KEYNESIAN THEORY OF DETERMINATION OF NATIONAL INCOME

Period 3 MBA Program January February MACROECONOMICS IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY Core Course. Professor Ilian Mihov

Comparative analysis of the BRICS Trade

Chapter 1 Introduction to Economics 1.0 CONTENTS. Introduction to the Series

dr Bartłomiej Rokicki Chair of Macroeconomics and International Trade Theory Faculty of Economic Sciences, University of Warsaw

The World Economy from a Distance

Chapter 4 Specific Factors and Income Distribution

Expansions (periods of. positive economic growth)

Answers to Text Questions and Problems in Chapter 15

AP Econ Day 92.notebook February 04, 2013

Dr. Barry Haworth University of Louisville Department of Economics Economics 202. Midterm #2

Specific Factors Model (2/1/2012) Econ

QUEEN S UNIVERSITY FACULTY OF ARTS AND SCIENCE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. Economics 222 A&B Macroeconomic Theory I. Final Examination 20 April 2009

Determinants of Price Elasticity of Demand... Error! Bookmark not defined. Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand... Error! Bookmark not defined.

3. TFU: A zero rate of increase in the Consumer Price Index is an appropriate target for monetary policy.

file:///c:/users/moha/desktop/mac8e/new folder (13)/CourseComp...

PubPol 201. Module 3: International Trade Policy. Class 2 Outline. Class 2 Outline. Class 2. The Gains and Losses from Trade

IPR Protection in the High-Tech Industries: A Model of Piracy

Chapter 7 Review questions

ECON 3010 Intermediate Macroeconomics Final Exam

Macroeconomics. Part Two: Unemployment and Money. Dr. Ali Moghaddasi Kelishomi. Warwick Economics Summer School 2016

The Macroeconomic Theory of the Open Economy: Chapter 13 Continued Net Capital Outflow: The Link between the two markets

TOPIC 1: IS-LM MODEL...3 TOPIC 2: LABOUR MARKET...23 TOPIC 3: THE AD-AS MODEL...33 TOPIC 4: INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT...41 TOPIC 5: MONETARY POLICY

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

SAMPLE EXAM QUESTIONS FOR FALL 2018 ECON3310 MIDTERM 2

Economic Importance of Keynesian and Neoclassical Economic Theories to Development

Assignment 1: Hand in only Answer. Last Name. First Name. Chapter

ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY. Term Test #2. December 13, 2017

Tutorial letter 204/1/2016. Macroeconomics ECS2602. Department of Economics Semester 1. Answers to Assignment 04

A Macroeconomic Theory of the Open Economy

Question 1: Productivity, Output and Employment (30 Marks)

Test 1 Econ322 Section 002 Chappell February 16, 2009

myepathshala.com (For Crash Course & Revision)

Assignment 2: Due day. This Friday. Send this answer sheet via . Subject: Assignment 2.

Long-Run Economic Growth

Economics 10020/20020 Principles of Macroeconomics International Economics

FINAL EXAMINATION VERSION B

Topic 4: AS-AD Model Dealing with longer run; more variance; look at the role of wages and prices

AGGREGATE DEMAND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

SUMMER TERM 2017 ECON1604: ECONOMICS I (Combined Studies)

The International Financial System

EC and MIDTERM EXAM I. March 26, 2015

L K Y Marginal Product of Labor (MPl) Labor Productivity (Y/L)

The Theory of Everything. Principles of Comparative Advantage and International Economics. Overview Principles Slide 1 of 2

So far in the short-run analysis we have ignored the wage and price (we assume they are fixed).

Introduction to Economic Fluctuations

ECON 222 Macroeconomic Theory I Fall Term 2012/13. Assignment 5 SOLUTIONS

ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY

ECO 403 L0301 Developmental Macroeconomics. Lecture 8 Balance-of-Payment Crises

Introduction. Countries engage in international trade for two basic reasons:

BUSI 101 Capital Markets and Real Estate

Chapter 18 Trade and Development, page 1 of 8

IS-MP: A Short-Run Macroeconomic Model

Transcription:

ECON 840 Fall 2010 N, Schmitt Political Economy of Economic Sanctions By William H. Kaempfer and Anton D. Lowenberg Presented by Celene Chan and Azadeh Khoshaein

Political Economy of Economic Sanctions In their article, The Political Economy of Economic Sanctions, William H. Kaempfer and Anton D. Lowenberg discuss the economic impact of sanctions, focusing primarily on trade sanctions and mandatory disinvestments, and offer two mechanisms through which the nature and extent of sanctions can be explained, the interest group model and game theoretic approaches. Economic Sanctions Since the end of the Cold War, economic sanctions have played an important role in international relations and foreign policy. As an alternative to military conflict, sanctions can influence another government s behaviour. The imposition of a sanction is not necessarily instrumental; often times, a government will impose sanctions in order to satisfy domestic special interest groups, whereby the sanction is merely symbolic. Economic sanctions include trade restrictions, capital flow/investment restrictions and smart sanctions, which are often directed at the ruling elite or government officials of the target nation. Modern political economic theory suggest several models through which economic sanctions can be understood. Trade Embargo Often times, the purpose of a sanction is to gain a competitive edge against producers in other countries. The economic impacts of trade sanctions on the target country are reflected in their terms-of-trade effects. When a sanction is imposed, the specific price ratio between exports and imports (from the perspective of country T)

worsens, due to an increase in the price of their net importable good (move from t 0 to t t ). Economic effect of sanctioning depends on the extent of pre-sanctions trade between the sanctioner and the target and the ease with which the target can find alternative markets for supply and demand of the goods they consume and produce. Kaempfer and Lowenberg use offer curves to measure the effects of trade sanctions on relative prices of imports and exports. Offer curves, or reciprocal demand curves, show the level of trade of imports for exports that some country would desire at various prices. In the graph below, T indicates the offer curve for country T and W, the offer curve for the rest of the world. Point E on the graph below indicates the free trade equilibrium between T and the World. It is where the offer curves and terms-of-trade line meet. The terms-of-trade faced by country T worsen as t 0 moves to t t, as in the case of total embargo. The result is that there is no price at which country T and the rest of the world, W will engage in trade. One important finding is that as more countries participate in the embargo, the more effective the sanction becomes, as the target has fewer trade

partners. Mandatory Disinvestment Disinvestment means that foreigners are selling off assets that they own in the target country and repatriating the proceeds, either to the investor s own country or to another country. A mandatory disinvestment sanction usually implies the sale of any current investments in a country, and injunctions against new investments. The net effect is net capital outflow from the target country. We can observe how the net capital outflow will impact the target country s balance of payments equation. P X NX = F {q, P X MP K (L,K)} where F 1 > 0, F 2 < 0 On the left hand side of the equation, we have an expression for the nominal value of net exports, where P X is the price of the product X and NX is net exports of X. On the right hand side of the equation, we have an expression for net capital outflows which is the outflow of investment funds, net of foreign investment inflows. Net capital outflows is a function of q, the degree of disinvestment, and MP K, the marginal product of capital (for given labour, L and capital, K employed in the target economy). In this model, labour and capital are exogenous and taken as given. The Net Capital Outflows is positive in the degree of disinvestment and negative in the value of the marginal product of capital stock. The foreign currency obtained as a result of selling more goods and services to foreigners than buying from them (Net Exports) is used to finance the purchase of foreign financial and physical assets (Net Capital Investment). Likewise, a trade deficit would need to be financed by net capital inflows. In other words, the target country requires more capital

inflow from foreign investors than investment outflow generated by domestic capital owners. A mass exodus of capital from a country will have several effects on its economy. Interestingly enough, the short term effect of such an outflow is actually beneficial to the target country s domestic investors. By acquiring large amounts of capital at depressed prices, the firm owners experience a windfall gain. This is essentially the fire sale phenomenon. The rate of return on capital can explain the economic impact of disinvestments: r = P X MP K (L,K) / P K (q, K) where P K1 < 0, P K2 < 0 Suppose a universal mandatory disinvestment sanction is enacted. The sharp increase in disinvestments, q will have a negative impact on the price of capital, P K. As such, the rate of return on capital will increase, to the benefit of the domestic capital owners in the target country. The increase in the domestic rate of return will motivate capital owners in the target country to sell their foreign holdings and repatriate the proceeds domestically. In the short run, these capital owners will enjoy higher profits, enlarging the tax base over which the target country s government can tax. The tax proceeds can fund the policy which provoked the sanction in the first place. Kaempfer and Lowerberg also consider the long term effects of mandatory disinvestment sanctions, which can be quite harmful to the target country s economy and the reason that this international relations tool exists. As foreign investors move their investments away from the target country, the inflow of new capital will diminish. The deterioration of capital

stock in the target country will diminish, which will increase the marginal product of capital and increase the price of capital. These two effects act oppositely on the rate of return. The marginal product of capital will increase as capital stock decreases, which will increase the rate of return, while the price of capital will increase due to the scarcity of capital, which will decrease the rate of return. It is presumed inevitable that the effect of price of capital on the rate of return will be greater than the effect of marginal product of capital. Firms in the target country will face higher production costs and experience lower profits. The target country s tax base diminishes and the sanction has effectively removed funding towards the objectionable policy. Aside from a sanctioning government explicitly banning any further transactions with the target country, foreign investors are also motivated to withdrawn their current capital investments, as the outlook on the target country s economy has become both bearish and volatile. Foreign investors expect that firm profits will decrease in the target country if mandatory disinvestment sanctions are in place. Like with trade embargos, the effectiveness of mandatory disinvestments depends on the number and size of countries participating in the sanction. The amount of damage inflicted upon the target country s economy depends on the target s ability to replace or cope without foreign sources of capital. Interest Group Model According to this approach, the decision to implement sanctions against a target country are determined by pressures brought to bear in the domestic political system by interest groups acting on behalf of whom the sanctions would affect. The groups are defined by a

common interest; however, political participation is offset by the desire to free ride on the lobbying efforts of other members within the group. Kaempfer and Lowenberg model the economy in terms of individual profit-maximizers, each of whom is willing to pay for protection of their industry through the presence or absence of sanctions. The implementation of a sanction will either increase or decrease an individual s income. One group is willing to pay for more sanctions (indicated by J in the graph below), while another group is willing to pay fewer sanctions (K). Depending on the level of influence and support for each policy (more sanction or less sanction), the level of sanctions can be determined. The combination of these desires produce a market for sanctions. The support-maximizing governing body will impose sanctions to a level such that the absolute value of the marginal utility to beneficiaries is equal to the marginal disutility to the losers. The dollar amount that one group is willing to pay is offset by the free riders within that group. A similar analysis is done from the perspective of the target; the individuals in the target country are willing to pay for compliance and non-compliance with the sanctions imposed.

Single Rational Actor Approach The earlier observed policies in international relations and their consequences are viewed as outcomes of the configurations of domestic interest group politics within sender and target nations. However, in this game-theoretic model, the relevant unit of analysis is no longer individual interest group members, voters or politicians, but entire nation states. So according to single-rational actor this approach, states are the main players on the international stage and decisions about whether and how to apply sanctions and whether to comply with or resist sanctions are made by states. As rational actors, the states engage in a repeated game, whereby the success of sanctions is determined by the commitment of a sanctioner to actually impose sanctions. A surprising outcome is that, in a world of perfect information, the mere threat of a sanction would be sufficiently effective in eliciting a compliant behaviour from the target nation. However, the fact that sanctions are imposed suggests that either the sender underestimates the target s cost of compliance, whereby the sanction fails, or that the target underestimates the sender s resolve, whereby the sanction succeeds.

Conclusions This paper discusses several models to determine the decision to implement and the effect of trade sanctions. The interest group models shows how national policy choices reflect the interests of constituency groups within the domestic polity. In single-rational actor models, however, one country s international policy decisions both affect and are affected by other national governments decisions. Often, trade sanctions are made for purposes other than protection for domestic industries, who are willing to pay for the political suasion needed to implement the sanction. Therefore, in determining the terms-of-trade effects of the sanctions, the paper suggests that economists and policy makers should take into the account that the actual level of politically-driven sanctions imposed is a function of the relative political influences of the pro-sanctions groups and the anti-sanctions groups within that country. Similarly, in target nations, the compliance with a sanction is determined by the equilibrium of political power between the groups that gain and lose from conforming to the sending states demands. Although there exist reasons other than political motivation for sanctions, such as symbolic sanctions, smart sanctions, and selective sanctions, all sanctions have implications for the level of export and imports and prices of goods in both the sanctioning and target countries. It should be mentioned that in some situations, such as total embargo, sanctions are not harmful just for target country but for the sanctioning country as well.