Entropic Derivative Security Valuation

Similar documents
Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

Optimal Option Pricing via Esscher Transforms with the Meixner Process

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Construction of a BRICS index and option price evaluation relative to constituent indexes

Pricing Implied Volatility

SADDLEPOINT APPROXIMATIONS TO OPTION PRICES 1. By L. C. G. Rogers and O. Zane University of Bath and First Chicago NBD

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching

Dynamic Portfolio Choice II

Corporate Finance, Module 21: Option Valuation. Practice Problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 7, 2005

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY AND OPTION PRICING

Risk Neutral Pricing. to government bonds (provided that the government is reliable).

Preference-Free Option Pricing with Path-Dependent Volatility: A Closed-Form Approach

Risk Measures for Derivative Securities: From a Yin-Yang Approach to Aerospace Space

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I)

1. What is Implied Volatility?

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

How Much Can Marketability Affect Security Values?

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Advanced Stochastic Processes.

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

EE266 Homework 5 Solutions

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Optimal Investment for Generalized Utility Functions

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION

Dynamic Hedging in a Volatile Market

Hedging the Smirk. David S. Bates. University of Iowa and the National Bureau of Economic Research. October 31, 2005

A Simple Utility Approach to Private Equity Sales

Probability in Options Pricing

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Dynamic Asset Pricing Model

Modeling of Price. Ximing Wu Texas A&M University

We discussed last time how the Girsanov theorem allows us to reweight probability measures to change the drift in an SDE.

Comparison of Pricing Approaches for Longevity Markets

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Walter S.A. Schwaiger. Finance. A{6020 Innsbruck, Universitatsstrae 15. phone: fax:

Canonical Valuation of Mortality-linked Securities

Distortion operator of uncertainty claim pricing using weibull distortion operator

TEACHING NOTE 00-03: MODELING ASSET PRICES AS STOCHASTIC PROCESSES II. is non-stochastic and equal to dt. From these results we state the following:

Effectiveness of CPPI Strategies under Discrete Time Trading

Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle?

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems

Youngrok Lee and Jaesung Lee

The Pennsylvania State University. The Graduate School. Department of Industrial Engineering AMERICAN-ASIAN OPTION PRICING BASED ON MONTE CARLO

************************

EMPIRICAL STUDY ON THE MARKOV-MODULATED REGIME-SWITCHING MODEL WHEN THE REGIME SWITCHING RISK IS PRICED

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers. Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel)

Math 5760/6890 Introduction to Mathematical Finance

by Kian Guan Lim Professor of Finance Head, Quantitative Finance Unit Singapore Management University

Pricing Dynamic Guaranteed Funds Under a Double Exponential. Jump Diffusion Process. Chuang-Chang Chang, Ya-Hui Lien and Min-Hung Tsay

non linear Payoffs Markus K. Brunnermeier

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

A Robust Option Pricing Problem

Path-dependent inefficient strategies and how to make them efficient.

Lecture 17: More on Markov Decision Processes. Reinforcement learning

Edgeworth Binomial Trees

Mean-Variance Optimal Portfolios in the Presence of a Benchmark with Applications to Fraud Detection

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2012, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis

Chapter 8. Markowitz Portfolio Theory. 8.1 Expected Returns and Covariance

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

OULU BUSINESS SCHOOL. Ilkka Rahikainen DIRECT METHODOLOGY FOR ESTIMATING THE RISK NEUTRAL PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTION

Real-World Quantitative Finance

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

The Black-Scholes Model

Principal Component Analysis of the Volatility Smiles and Skews. Motivation

Multi-armed bandit problems

CLAIM HEDGING IN AN INCOMPLETE MARKET

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Point Estimation. Stat 4570/5570 Material from Devore s book (Ed 8), and Cengage

1 Implied Volatility from Local Volatility

( 0) ,...,S N ,S 2 ( 0)... S N S 2. N and a portfolio is created that way, the value of the portfolio at time 0 is: (0) N S N ( 1, ) +...

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

INSTITUTE OF ACTUARIES OF INDIA

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Learning Martingale Measures to Price Options

Financial Giffen Goods: Examples and Counterexamples

-divergences and Monte Carlo methods

Advanced. of Time. of Measure. Aarhus University, Denmark. Albert Shiryaev. Stek/ov Mathematical Institute and Moscow State University, Russia

Optimal Investment with Deferred Capital Gains Taxes

Computing Bounds on Risk-Neutral Measures from the Observed Prices of Call Options

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13.

Characterization of the Optimum

Optimization Models in Financial Mathematics

Factor Models for Option Pricing

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

Markowitz portfolio theory

Defined contribution retirement plan design and the role of the employer default

Alternative Tilts for Nonparametric Option Pricing

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

WEIDONG TIAN. Department of Finance Belk College of Business University of North Carolina at Charlotte Tel: (704)

Option Pricing. Chapter Discrete Time

On the Calibration of Mortality Forward Curves

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Transcription:

Entropic Derivative Security Valuation Michael Stutzer 1 Professor of Finance and Director Burridge Center for Securities Analysis and Valuation University of Colorado, Boulder, CO 80309 1 Mathematical Framework Let x denote a (vector) of random variable(s), β a (vector) of parameter(s), and f(x, β) a (column vector) of real-valued function(s). Let E P [f(x, β)] denote its expectation computed with probability measure P. For a specific value of β, define the set of probability measures: (1) P(β) {P : E P [f(x, β)] = 0} which additionally are absolutely continuous with respect to a distinguished measure µ that is determined by the application. Selection of a particular probability measure in P(β) is called a linear inverse problem. Many applications of entropy make use of the following solution (when it exists): (2) min P P(β) D(P µ) min P log(dp/dµ)dp s.t. E P [f(x, β)] = 0. In (2), D(P µ) = log(dp/dµ)dp is the Kullback-Leibler measure of discrepancy between the measure P and the distinguished measure µ, a.k.a. the relative entropy. When µ is a discrete probability measure with H possible values, D(P µ) = H h=1 P h log(p h /µ h ), and it can be shown 1

that D 0, with equality when and only when P h = µ h, h = 1,..., H. When in addition µ h 1/H, i.e. the uniform distribution, the constrained minimization of D(P µ) is equivalent to maximization of the Shannon entropy h P h log P h. 2 The solution to (2) is well-known [5, sec.3(a)] to have the following Gibbs Canonical or Esscher Transformed density: (3) dp(β) dµ = e γ(β) f(x,β) E µ [e γ(β) f(x,β) ]. To compute the coefficient vector γ(β) in (3), solve the following problem : (4) γ(β) = argmax I(β, γ) loge µ [e γ f(x,β) ] γ Finally, D(P(β) µ) = I(β, γ(β)) defined above. This numerical value has a frequentist interpretation from the large deviations theory of IID processes that is quite useful in asset pricing model parameter estimation [11] and optimal portfolio choice [14]. 2 Application to Derivative Security Valuation Consider the simplest problem of option pricing: value a European call option, written on a single underlying stock that pays no dividends, whose price at expiration T-periods ahead is denoted x(t). The riskless, continuously compounded gross interest rate r is constant between now and expiration. Under the familiar assumptions of complete and frictionless markets that do not admit arbitrage opportunities, there is a risk neutral probability measure P under which the call option s price C is the expected value of its risklessly discounted payoff at expiration, i.e. 2

(5) C = E P [ max[x(t) K, 0]/r T] where the risk-neutral probabilities P satisfy the martingale constraint x(0) = E P [ x(t) ], rewritten r T (6) E P [ x(t) x(0) /rt 1] = 0 Conventional risk-neutral pricing of options proceeds by specifying a parametric model for the risk-neutral stochastic price process of the underlying stock. Parameter values are found that make the model s computed stock prices and/or option prices close (e.g. in the least squares sense) to observed stock and/or option prices [3]. In the simplest case (the Black-Scholes model), this procedure requires an estimate of the volatility parameter, found either from past stock returns (i.e. historical volatility) or from market option prices (i.e. a best-fitting implied volatility). But suppose one has doubts about the correct parametric model. The formalism of the previous section provides an alternative. Let the scalar function f(x, β) = x(t) x(0) /rt 1, where β = r. The distribution µ is the forecast distribution of x(t). To estimate this, one could just use a histogram of past T-period stock returns as in [13] and [16], a conditional histogram [15], or a more complex forecasting model [7]. The distribution is then substituted into (4) and solved to find the γ(β) needed to estimate the density P(β) in (3), which is required to compute the option valuation (5). It is possible to extend the approach to handle stochastic dividends and interest rates. Another approach presumes a particular form for µ, and defines a vector f(x, β) with ith component max[x(t) K i, 0]/r T C i, where C i is the observed market price for a call with exercise price K i, as in [10] and [4]. Then, (3)-(4) are used to study the nature of the measure P(β) implied by those options market prices, while (5) could be used to value options other than those present in f. See [2] for some theoretical and applied extensions of this approach. 3

Further refinements were developed by Gray, et.al [9], showing that the associated dynamic hedge (i.e. entropic hedge ratio) outperformed hedging benchmarks, and by Alcock and Carmichael [1], extending the concept to enable valuation of American options. The entropic approaches are not necessarily inconsistent with the conventional approach. In fact, extant closed form option pricing models can be analytically derived by specification of the process generating the stock price distributions, and systematically applying the Esscher Transform (3) as in [8] and [6]. 4

Notes 1 The limited length of this entry precludes writing a survey describing all uses of entropy in finance and that cites all papers using it. Instead, focus is placed on its use in derivative security valuation, arguably the most relevant application for readers of this book, and citations are limited to early or illustrative papers. 2 Perhaps the first published use of this in finance was in Osborne [12], who rationalized assumption of a lognormal stock price distribution as that maximizing Shannon entropy subject to a vector of two constraints (1), constraining the mean and variance of the observed continuously compounded returns to observed values. 5

References [1] J. Alcock and T. Carmichael. Nonparametric American option pricing. Journal of Futures Markets, 28:717 748, 2008. [2] Marco Avellanada. Minimum relative-entropy calibration of asset-pricing models. International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance, 1:447 472, 1998. [3] David S. Bates. Testing option pricing models. In G.S. Maddala and C.R. Rao, editors, Handbook of Statistics, Volume 15: Statistical Methods in Finance, pages 567 611. North- Holland, Amsterdam, 1996. [4] Peter W. Buchen and Michael Kelly. The maximum entropy distribution of an asset inferred from option prices. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 31:143 159, 1996. [5] Imre Csiszar. I-divergence geometry of probability distributions and minimization problems. Annals of Probability, 3(1):146 58, 1975. [6] E. Eberlein, U. Keller, and K Prause. New insights into smile, mispricing, and value at risk: The hyperbolic model. Journal of Business, 71:371 405, 1998. [7] F. D. Foster and C.H. Whiteman. An application of Bayesian option pricing to the soybean market. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 81:222 272, 1999. [8] Hans Gerber and Elias Shiu. Option pricing by Esscher Transforms. Transactions of the Society of Actuaries, 46:99 140, 1994. [9] P. Gray, S. Edwards, and E. Kalotay. Canonical pricing and hedging of index options. Journal of Futures Markets, 27:771 790, 2007. 6

[10] R.J. Hawkins, Mark Rubinstein, and G.J. Daniell. Reconstruction of the probability density function implicit in option prices from incomplete and noisy data. In K. Hanson and R. Silver, editors, Maximum Entropy and Bayesian Methods. Kluwer, 1996. [11] Yuichi Kitamura and Michael Stutzer. Connections between entropic and linear projections in asset pricing estimation. Journal of Econometrics, 107:159 174, 2002. [12] M.F.M. Osborne. Brownian motion in the stock market. In Paul Cootner, editor, The Random Character of the Stock Market. MIT Press, 1970. [13] Michael Stutzer. A simple nonparametric approach to derivative security valuation. Journal of Finance, 51(4):1633 1652, 1996. [14] Michael Stutzer. Portfolio choice with endogenous utility: A large deviations approach. Journal of Econometrics, 116:365 386, 2003. [15] Michael Stutzer and Muinul Chowdhury. A simple nonparametric approach to bond futures option pricing. Journal of Fixed Income, 8:67 76, 1999. [16] Joseph Zou and Emanuel Derman. Strike adjusted spread: A new metric for estimating the value of equity options. Quantitative Strategies Research Note, Goldman, Sachs and Co., July 1999. 7