NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE Q-THEORY OF MERGERS. Boyan Jovanovic Peter L. Rousseau. Working Paper 8740

Similar documents
The Q-Theory of Mergers: International and Cross-Border Evidence

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS. No 449. Pursuing the Wrong Options? Adjustment Costs and the Relationship between Uncertainty and Capital Accumulation

Group Assignment I. database, available from the library s website) or national statistics offices. (Extra points if you do.)

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

The Macro Determinants of M & A Timing in China

Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MAKING SENSE OF THE LABOR MARKET HEIGHT PREMIUM: EVIDENCE FROM THE BRITISH HOUSEHOLD PANEL SURVEY

Did Wages Reflect Growth in Productivity?

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INTEREST RATES AND INITIAL PUBLIC OFFERINGS. Boyan Jovanovic Peter L. Rousseau

ARTICLE IN PRESS. Investigating the economic role of mergers. Gregor Andrade *, Erik Stafford

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As

Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Appendix A. Mathematical Appendix

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

Appendices For Online Publication

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ARE GOVERNMENT SPENDING MULTIPLIERS GREATER DURING PERIODS OF SLACK? EVIDENCE FROM 20TH CENTURY HISTORICAL DATA

The Macroeconomics of Private Equity

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers

The Gertler-Gilchrist Evidence on Small and Large Firm Sales

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage

Debt/Equity Ratio and Asset Pricing Analysis

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A THEORY OF THE INFORMAL SECTOR. Yoshiaki Azuma Herschel I. Grossman. Working Paper

Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Economics Letters 108 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Economics Letters. journal homepage:

Survival of the Fittest: Natural Selection Revisited*

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. An Unstable Okun s Law, Not the Best Rule of Thumb. Brent Meyer and Murat Tasci

Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

CHAPTER 13. Duration of Spell (in months) Exit Rate

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers

Part III. Cycles and Growth:

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Demand and Supply for Residential Housing in Urban China. Gregory C Chow Princeton University. Linlin Niu WISE, Xiamen University.

1. Logit and Linear Probability Models

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES U.S. GROWTH IN THE DECADE AHEAD. Martin S. Feldstein. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DO SHAREHOLDERS OF ACQUIRING FIRMS GAIN FROM ACQUISITIONS? Sara B. Moeller Frederik P. Schlingemann René M.

The Role of APIs in the Economy

Investment Performance of Common Stock in Relation to their Price-Earnings Ratios: BASU 1977 Extended Analysis

Business cycle volatility and country zize :evidence for a sample of OECD countries. Abstract

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Okun s law revisited. Is there structural unemployment in developed countries?

1 The Solow Growth Model

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow,

Inflation 11/27/2017. A. Phillips Curve. A.W. Phillips (1958) documented relation between unemployment and rate of change of wages in U.K.

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations

Capital Reallocation and Liquidity

Comments on Foreign Effects of Higher U.S. Interest Rates. James D. Hamilton. University of California at San Diego.

Investment 3.1 INTRODUCTION. Fixed investment

Capital reallocation and liquidity

Average and Marginal Tobin s q as Indicators of Future Growth Opportunities, Expected Return, and Risk

The Baumol-Tobin and the Tobin Mean-Variance Models of the Demand

Savings, Investment and the Real Interest Rate in an Endogenous Growth Model

Derivation of zero-beta CAPM: Efficient portfolios

Long Term Performance of Divesting Firms and the Effect of Managerial Ownership. Robert C. Hanson

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

Credit Default Swaps, Options and Systematic Risk

Average Earnings and Long-Term Mortality: Evidence from Administrative Data

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

, the nominal money supply M is. M = m B = = 2400

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

THE FED AND THE NEW ECONOMY

Replacement versus Historical Cost Profit Rates: What is the difference? When does it matter?

We follow Agarwal, Driscoll, and Laibson (2012; henceforth, ADL) to estimate the optimal, (X2)

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

A Synthesis of Accrual Quality and Abnormal Accrual Models: An Empirical Implementation

The data definition file provided by the authors is reproduced below: Obs: 1500 home sales in Stockton, CA from Oct 1, 1996 to Nov 30, 1998

Do acquirers only break even?

This appendix discusses two extensions of the cost concepts developed in Chapter 10.

MERGER ANNOUNCEMENTS AND MARKET EFFICIENCY: DO MARKETS PREDICT SYNERGETIC GAINS FROM MERGERS PROPERLY?

The effect of different payment methods on M&A performance - An empirical analysis based on the panel data of Shanghai and Shenzhen A-share market

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

The Impact of Model Periodicity on Inflation Persistence in Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models

Challenges For the Future of Chinese Economic Growth. Jane Haltmaier* Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. August 2011.

INFORMATION EFFICIENCY HYPOTHESIS THE FINANCIAL VOLATILITY IN THE CZECH REPUBLIC CASE

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

Discussion of paper: Quantifying the Lasting Harm to the U.S. Economy from the Financial Crisis. By Robert E. Hall

Chapter 6 Firms: Labor Demand, Investment Demand, and Aggregate Supply

How Costly is External Financing? Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Christopher Hennessy and Toni Whited March 2006

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

CHAPTER 11. SAVING, CAPITAL ACCUMULATION, AND OUTPUT

Internal LGD Estimation in Practice

Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment

Economic Growth and Convergence across the OIC Countries 1

The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit

Discussion of The Conquest of South American Inflation, by T. Sargent, N. Williams, and T. Zha

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

An Empirical Examination of Traditional Equity Valuation Models: The case of the Athens Stock Exchange

Transcription:

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE Q-THEORY OF MERGERS Boyan Jovanovic Peter L. Rousseau Working Paper 8740 http://www.nber.org/papers/w8740 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 January 2002 We thank the National Science Foundation for support and Joao Hrotko for comments. The views expressed herein are those of the author and not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. 2002 by Boyan Jovanovic and Peter L. Rousseau. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including notice, is given to the source.

The Q-Theory of Mergers Boyan Jovanovic and Peter L. Rousseau NBER Working Paper No. 8740 January 2002 JEL No. O3 ABSTRACT The Q-theory of investment says that a firm's investment rate should rise with its Q. We argue here that this theory also explains why some firms buy other firms. We find that 1. A firm's merger and acquisition (M&A) investment responds to its Q more -- by a factor of 2.6 -- than its direct investment does, probably because M&A investment is a high fixed cost and a low marginal adjustment cost activity, 2. The typical firm wastes some cash on M&As, but not on internal investment, i.e., the "Free-Cash Flow" story works, but explains a small fraction of mergers only, and 3. The merger waves of 1900 and the 1920's, `80s, and `90s were a response to profitable reallocation opportunities, but the `60s wave was probably caused by something else. Boyan Jovanovic Peter L. Rousseau Department of Economics Department of Economics University of Chicago Vanderbilt University 1126 East 59th Street Nashville, TN 37235 Chicago, IL 60637, and NBER and New York University, peter.l.rousseau@vanderbilt.edu and NBER bjovanov@uchicago.edu

The Q-Theory of Mergers Boyan Jovanovic and Peter L. Rousseau January 2002 The Q-theory of investment says that a firm s investment rate should rise with its Q. We argue here that this theory also explains why some firms buy other firms. We find that 1. A firm s merger and acquisition (M&A) investment responds to its Q more by a factor of 2.6 than its direct investment does, probably because M&A investment is a high fixed cost and a low marginal adjustment cost activity, 2. The typical firm wastes some cash on M&As, but not on internal investment, i.e., the Free-Cash Flow story works, but explains a small fraction of mergers only, and 3. The merger waves of 1900 and the 1920 s, 80s, and 90s were a response to profitable reallocation opportunities, but the 60s wave was probably caused by something else. Two distinct used-capital markets. Used equipment and structures sometimes trade unbundled in that firm 1 buys a machine or building from firm 2, but firm 2 continues to exist. At other times, firm 1 buys firm 2 and thereby gets to own all of firm 2 s capital. In both markets, the traded capital gets a new owner. In a sale of used disassembled capital, the capital also gets a new manager, whereas in the M&A market, capital gets a new manager when a merger entails a restructuring. Such a merger is reallocative in the same sense that a used capital trade is. Mergers as used-capital trades. Our model treats M&As like used-capital-market transactions. This seems apt, since trading volume in the two markets for used capital bundled and disassembled moves together. Figure 1 shows this fact. It plots acquired capital and direct purchases of used capital among exchange-listed firms as percentages of their investment. The series cover all firms common to the University Jovanovic: Department of Economics, University of Chicago, 1126 East 59th Street, Chicago, IL 60637, and New York University; Rousseau: Department of Economics, Vanderbilt University, Nashville, TN 37235. We thank the National Science Foundation for support and Joao Hrotko for comments. 1

35 10 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 Acquisitions (left axis) D=.45 Used capital purchases (right axis) 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 Year 9 8 7 6 5 4 Figure 1: Used and Acquired Capital as Percentages of Total Investment, 1971-2000 of Chicago s Center for Research in Securities Prices (CRSP) database and Standard and Poor s Compustat. 1 The two series do not overlap in coverage, and so they add up to the fraction of investment spent on buying used capital. This fraction was 10 percent in 1975, and a much higher 43.5 percent in 2000. The correlation coefficient between the two series is 0.45. Clearly, the merger waves of the 80s and 90s coincided with waves of trading disassembled used capital. Prior evidence. High-Q firms usually buy low-q firms. Gregor Andrade, Mark Mitchell and Erik Stafford (2001) report that in more than two-thirds of all mergers since 1973, the acquirer s Q exceeded the target s Q. And Henri Servaes (1991) finds that total takeover returns (defined as the abnormal increase in the combined values of the merging parties) are larger when the target has a low Q and if the bidder had ahighq. Thus mergers are a channel through which capital flows to better projects and better management, and our model reflects that fact. 1 Capital sales include property, plant, and equipment (Compustat item 107). Acquisitions include funds used for and costs related to the purchase of another company in the current year or an acquisition in a prior year that was carried over to the current year (item 129). Investment is the sum of acquired capital (item 129) and direct capital expenditures (item 128). We compute the ratios in Figure 1 after summing each data item across active firms in each year. 2

I. Model is A firm s state of technology is z and its capital stock is K. Its production function output = zk. (1) The parameter z follows the Markov process Pr {z t+1 z 0 z t = z} = F (z 0,z), (2) and it is firm-specific. Markets for K. Firms can buy new or disassembled used capital at a price of unity. The cost of disassembly is 1 s per unit of capital, and any firm that disassembles its K gets a salvage value of s<1 per unit of K. The firm can also place itself on the M&A market where all acquired capital trades at a common price of q per unit. If the salvage and the acquired capital markets are both open, we must have q = s, and this is what we shall assume. No markets for z. The firm must accept whatever z draw that nature endows it with each period. Growth of capacity. Let X be the firm s direct investment in capital (new or used but unbundled) and Y its acquisitions of bundled capital. Next period, its capital stockwillbe K 0 =(1 δ) K + X + Y. (3) Costs of growth. Aside from the payment for X and Y,thefirm also faces the following foregone-output cost of growth: C (x, y) K, where x = X K, and y = Y K. (4) Merger gains. The firm transfers its z to all new and all used capital that it buys. The joint gains to a merger are thus largest when the target s z is low, and the buyer s z is high. Let the bidder s state be (z 1,K 1 ) and let the target s state be (z 2,K 2 ). The output of the combined firm would be z 1 (K 1 + K 2 ), which is higher than the sum of the two firms pre-merger outputs by the amount (z 1 z 2 ) K 2. The Q equation. Because (1) and (4) are homogeneous of degree one in K, X, and Y, the aggregation condition (2.8) of Fumio Hayashi and Tohru Inoue (1991) holds. The value of K inside a firm is of the form Q (z) K. The price of new capital is unity, and the price of used capital is q<1. A unit of K has a profit ofz C (x, y) x qy, and a market value of Q (z) = max x 0,y 0 {z C (x, y) x qy +(1 δ + x + y) Q (z)}, (5) 3

where Q (z) is the discounted expected present value of capital tomorrow given the firm s z today. Since the firm has the option of selling its capital in the next period on the merger market at a price of q dollars per unit of capital, Q (z) = 1 Z max {q,q (z 0 )} df (z 0,z). (6) 1+r Interior maxima. At an interior maximum, the optimal x and y satisfy the first order conditions c 1 (x, y) =Q (z) 1. (7) and c 2 (x, y) =Q (z) q. (8) If z is positively autocorrelated, Q is increasing in z, andhigh-z firms will grow faster and, if there are no fixed costs of investment, use both x and y to achieve that growth. If we control for Q, K does not matter. That is, a large firm grows as easily as a small one, and no optimal firm size exists just optimal growth. Fixed costs of mergers. Assume a fixed cost, φ, of acquiring the capital of other firms: ( c (x, y)+φ if y>0, C (x, y) = c (x, 0) if y =0. This cost is per unit of K, and therefore returns to scale remain constant. Let i = x+y be the gross investment rate in efficiency units. A low-i firm will avoid the cost φ by setting y =0and using only x, whereas a high-i firm will use both margins. The value of i, calliti,atwhichthefirm is indifferent between buying in the acquisitions market and staying out of it, solves for i the equation i + c (i, 0) = φ +min y {(i y)+qy + c (i y, y)}. (9) The left-hand side of (9) is lower when i is small, and the right-hand side is lower when i is high. Of course, i itself depends on the firm s z. Disappearance of firms. A firm may disappear either by exiting and disassembling its capital, or by being acquired. Either way, it gets q per unit of K. Letz e be the point of indifference between staying in business and exiting. Then Q (z e )=q. Four regions for z. Figure 2 portrays a steady state in which the distribution of z over firms replicates itself period after period. Sustaining such a steady state requires an entry process as modeled by Hugo A. Hopenhayn (1982). Our focus is on the fate of the incumbents. Each period, firms with z s below z e dissolve or are 4

Frequency distribution of firm-efficiencies, z Q(z) < q Exit: Dissolve, or get taken over z e Invest internally: x>0, y=0 z * x > y > 0 z O Invest internally and externally y > x > 0 z Figure 2: The Four Regions of z acquired. In the region between z e and z firmsremaininthemarketbutinvestonly in x because the fixed cost φ deters them from setting a positive y. Beyondz (the value of z that corresponds to i )theyalsosety>0, and beyond the overtaking level z O, y exceeds x. Investment-expansion path. Figure 3 shows the expansion path for x and y as the efficiency-units-investment rate i, represented by the parallel dashed iso-investment lines, rises. At i, x drops from i to x,andy jumps from zero to y min. The figure reflects the assumption that c y is small relative to c x, so that the share of y in the firm s investment portfolio grows, and the expansion path approaches the 45 0 line. At the overtaking point, x = y = i O /2. Beyondi O,inFigure3,y exceeds x. Engel curves for x and y. Figure 4 shows how investment in x and y varies with i. The two schedules add up to the 45 o line. When i reaches i O, y overtakes x. Evidence on overtaking. The prediction of Figure 4 is confirmed by the evidence in Figure 5. Between 1971 and 2000, small expansions did, indeed, come mainly through x, while large expansions came mainly through y. The vertical axis measures the HP-filtered means of x and y for firms that fall within each percentage point of the range of i. 2 Overtaking occurs at i O =1.12, which,afterdepreciation,isroughly a doubling of capacity. Data on individual years (not shown) indicate that i O has 2 In Figure 5, we pool 118,127 observations from 1971-2000. The sample thins out as i gets large: only 193 observations involve x + y between 1.5 and 2, and 96 observations lie between 2 and 2.5. 5

x io Iso-investment line at which x = y 45 0 i * x * ymin 45 0 i * io y Figure 3: The Expansion Path of x and y, as the Gross Investment-Rate, i = x + y, Rises fallen over the past two decades from 1.43 in 1980, to 1.09 in 1989, and to just 0.5 in 1998. This suggests that φ has also been falling. The M&A deflator. The acquirer s y is its M&A spending divided by q. In the model, q is the targets market values divided by their K s. A measure of q is marketto-book value of the acquired firms but, since firms usually write down the capital on their books as quickly as possible so as to bring the depreciation allowances forward, their market-to-book ratios are often much higher than unity. This is true for each subgroup of firmspicturedinfigure2. InFigure6weplottheaverage Q s for these groups, while pooling the middle two into a single x y group, and we denote these averages by q, Q x>y,and Q y>x respectively. All three averages stay well above 1, probably because the targets books underreport their capital. If so, the q t series plotted in Figure 6 badly overestimates the price of used capital on the acquisitions Another 182 observations, not shown in Figure 5, involve x + y>2.5. Weusebookvalueofassets (Compustat item 6) in the previous year to proxy for K, and linearly interpolate between missing points in the range of i before filtering. We interpolated between 5 annual averages in building x and 10 annual averages in building y. In all cases, the interpolations involved x + y>1.5. 6

x and y 45 0 i * x x * ymin y i * io i Figure 4: The Point of Overtaking, i O market, and we prefer not to use it as a deflator. Instead we assume in Figure 5 and in the regression analysis below that a dollar spent on x buys the same efficiency units of capital as a dollar spent on y. II. Estimates of Investment and Acquisitions Equations Assume that c (x, y) is additively separable. Then (7) and (8) are of the form x = f (Q ), and y = g (Q q). The Q s may all be biased upward, but Q j q should still measure firm j s incentive to acquire the capital from other firms at the price q. Linearized, f and g assume the same form as eq. (30) of Hayashi (1982): x j,t X j,t = α x 0 K + αx 1 Q j,t 1 + α x 2t,and (10) j,t 1 y j,t Y j,t = α y 0 + α y 1 (Q j,t 1 q t 1 )+α y K 2t, j,t 1 where t is a linear time trend. The model predicts that α x 1 and α y 1 should be positive. Table 1 presents the results for our panel of pooled observations from 1971-2000. We 7

2.5 45E 2 1.5 1 y 0.5 0 i O =1.12 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 i x Figure 5: Direct Capital Purchases, x, and Acquired Capital, y, by Investment Ratio, i = x + y, 1971-2000 Table 1-Investment Regressions Dependent variable 100x j,t 100y j,t Q j,t 1 0.746 (35.71) Q j,t 1 q t 1 2.220 (18.42) t -0.120 0.0308 (13.29) (7.32) R 2.0479.0206 N 111,039 26,383 Notes: The table presents estimates for Eq. 10 with T-statistics in parentheses. The regressions include dummy variables for 2-digit SICs (not reported). 8

3.5 3 _ Q y>x _ Q y#x 2.5 2 1.5 _ q 1 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 Year Figure 6: Q s by Investment Subgroup, 1972-2000 use the market-to-book ratio for Q. 3 For q t we use average market-to-book value of disappearing firms the series plotted in Figure 6. The results support the Q-theory. Hayashi had estimated the effect of Q on investment at 0.045. Our dependent variables are multiplied by 100. Our estimate of the effect of Q on x is one-sixth as large as Hayashi s, perhaps because we use total firm assets as the denominator (K) rather than the stock of durable equipment and structures. More to the point, our estimate of the effect of Q q on y is highly significant and nearly three times the coefficient-estimate of Q in the x equation. A. Which Way Does Free Cash Flow? A firm s manager may try to pursue his own objectives growing the size of his 3 To compute market values from the Compustat files,westartwiththevalueofcommonequity at current share prices (the product of items 24 and 25), and then add in the book value of preferred stock (item 130) and short- and long-term debt (items 34 and 9). Book values are computed similarly, but use the book value of common equity (item 60) rather than the market value. We omitted firms with negative values for net common equity from the plot since they imply negative market to book ratios, and eliminated observations with market-to-book values in excess of 100, since many of these were likely to be serious data errors. 9

firm, for example at shareholders expense. Direct investment cannot expand a manager s empire as fast as a merger can, and Michael C. Jensen (1986) argues that managers of firms with excess cash on hand are more likely to spend it on acquisitions than to pay it out in dividends, even if an acquisition has a negative net present value. Do firms spend their extra cash mergers? It seems so. We add cash (Compustat item 1) normalized by firm capital (again proxied by item 6) to the regressions described in (10). The results are in Table 2. Cash has little effect on x, but a positive, significant effect on y. Still, Q retains the lion s share of explanatory power. Table 2-Investment Regressions with Cash Dependent variable 100x j,t 100y j,t Q j,t 1 0.738 (34.41) Q j,t 1 q t 1 1.916 (15.43) 100 cash j,t 1 0.006 0.220 (1.32) (9.82) t -0.121 0.277 (13.38) (6.59) R 2.0479.0241 N 111,039 26,383 Notes: The table presents estimates for Eq. 10 with the ratio of cash to total firm assets as an additional regressor, with T-statistics in parentheses. The regressions include dummy variables for 2-digit SICs (not reported). III. Merger Waves as Reallocation Waves If firms all had the same z, Q would equal q, andnom&a swouldtakeplace. M&A s should rise, says the model, when the interfirm dispersion of Q is high. We now ask: Was Q more dispersed during merger waves? We confirm this in two different ways. The first test is summarized by Figure 7, which shows that Q y>x q leads movements in acquisitions. 4 The correlation between Q y>x q at the end of year t and acquisitions in the following year, which is the timing shown in the Figure 7, is 0.12, but the correlation rises to 0.22 if we lag Q y>x q by another period, and rises to 0.31 if we lag it yet again. 4 We project mergers for 2001 by observing that their value fell by 57 percent between 2000 and 2001 (Wall Street Journal, Jan. 2, 2002) and by assuming that firm assets in our Compustat sample grew at the same rate as GDP between the second quarters of 2000 and 2001. 10

0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0-0.2-0.4-0.6 Acquisitions (% of investment, detrended, right scale) Q y>x - q (detrended, left scale) D=.12 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 Year 15 10 5 0-5 -10-15 Figure 7: Acquired Capital and the Dispersion of Q, 1975-2001 Our second, and less direct test is in Figure 8. The Compustat covers too few book values before 1975 to allow a reliable estimate of the dispersion of Q before then. Instead, we infer the dispersion of Q in year t<1998 by computing the standard deviation of the year-1998 Q s among firms of vintage t, andthenrepeatingthis exercise for each t between 1890 and 1998. Ifthedistributionofentrants Q s is more dispersed in years when the market at large has more dispersion of Q, andifthez process is fairly persistent, this estimate will provide a useful rough guide to waves of dispersion of Q. But because high-z firms are more likely to survive, our estimator is biased increasingly towards zero the older the vintage of the firms. Our estimate of Q-dispersion is the dashed line in Figure 8. This HP-filtered series is indeed upward sloping as a function of vintage. The solid line in Figure 8 shows the HP-filtered acquisition series as a fraction of total capitalization, as a function of time. 5 Thus the two series derive from two different populations. The solid line is a 5 The dashed line in Figure 8 is reproduced from Figure 2 in Jovanovic and Rousseau (2001b, pp. 338, 340). The solid line is based primarily on merger data from CRSP for 1926-1998, and from work sheets for the manufacturing and mining sectors underlying Ralph L. Nelson (1959) for 1890-1930. The series includes the market value of targets acquired by exchange-listed firms in the year prior to merger. Market values after 1925 are from CRSP. Before that, they are from our extension of CRSP 11

4 3 2 4.3% in 1998 Std. Dev. Q (right scale) Target Value % Stock Market (left scale) 0.4 0.3 0.2 1 0.1 0 1890 '00 '10 '20 '30 '40 '50 '60 '70 '80 '90 2000 Year 0 Figure 8: Acquired Capital and the Dispersion of Q by Vintage, 1890-1998 historical series, whereas the dashed line is a vintage representation of the 1998 cross section. Both lines may trend upward for reasons that the model leaves out, but even the detrended series have a correlation coefficient of 0.64! But for the hubris wave of the 1960 s, each merger wave was preceded by a rise in the dispersion of Q. Thus the waves of 1900, the 1920s, 1980s and 1990s were probably reallocation waves. References [1] Andrade, Gregor; Mitchell, Mark and Stafford, Erik. New Evidence and Perspective on Mergers. Journal of Economic Perspectives, Spring 2001, 15(2), pp. 103-120. [2] Compustat database. New York: Standard and Poor s Corporation, 2000. [3] CRSP database. Chicago: University of Chicago Center for Research on Securities Prices, 2000. backward through 1885 using newspaper sources. See footnotes 1 and 4 of Jovanovic and Rousseau (2001a) for a detailed description of these data. 12

[4] Hayashi, Fumio. Tobin s Marginal q and Average q: A Neoclassical Interpretation. Econometrica, January 1982, 50(1), pp. 213-224. [5] Hayashi, Fumio and Inoue, Tohru. The Relation Between Firm Growth and Q with Multiple Capital Goods: Theory and Evidence from Panel Data on Japanese Firms. Econometrica, May 1991, 59(3), pp. 731-753. [6] Jensen, Michael C. The Market for Corporate Control: Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers. American Economic Review, May 1986 (Papers and Proceedings), 76(2), pp. 323-329. [7] Hopenhayn, Hugo A. Entry, Exit, and Firm Dynamics in Long Run Equilibrium. Econometrica, September 1992, 60(5), pp. 1127-1150. [8] Jovanovic, Boyan and Rousseau, Peter L. Vintage Organization Capital. National Bureau of Economic Research (Cambridge, MA) Working Paper No. 8166, March 2001a. [9] Jovanovic, Boyan and Rousseau, Peter L. Why Wait? A Century of Life Before IPO. American Economic Review, May 2001b (Papers and Proceedings), 91(2), pp. 336-341. [10] Nelson, Ralph L. Merger movements in American industry, 1895-1956. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press,1959. [11] Servaes, Henri. Tobin s Q and the Gains from Takeovers. Journal of Finance, March 1991, 46(1), pp. 409-419. [12] Sidel, Robin. Volatile Markets Put a Damper on Deals. Wall Street Journal, January 2, 2002. 13