A Baseline Model: Diamond and Dybvig (1983)

Similar documents
Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model

Expectations vs. Fundamentals-based Bank Runs: When should bailouts be permitted?

On Diamond-Dybvig (1983): A model of liquidity provision

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Bailouts, Bail-ins and Banking Crises

A Model with Costly Enforcement

Bailouts, Bail-ins and Banking Crises

M. R. Grasselli. February, McMaster University. ABM and banking networks. Lecture 3: Some motivating economics models. M. R.

Monetary and Financial Macroeconomics

In Diamond-Dybvig, we see run equilibria in the optimal simple contract.

Expectations versus Fundamentals: Does the Cause of Banking Panics Matter for Prudential Policy?

The Diamond-Dybvig Revolution: Extensions Based on the Original DD Environment

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #6 Solutions

A key characteristic of financial markets is that they are subject to sudden, convulsive changes.

A Diamond-Dybvig Model in which the Level of Deposits is Endogenous

PRINCETON UNIVERSITY Economics Department Bendheim Center for Finance. FINANCIAL CRISES ECO 575 (Part II) Spring Semester 2003

Bailouts, Bail-ins and Banking Crises

Revision Lecture Microeconomics of Banking MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports

An agent-based model for bank formation, bank runs and interbank networks

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Microeconomics Comprehensive Exam

Government Guarantees and Financial Stability

Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity

Expectations vs. Fundamentals-driven Bank Runs: When Should Bailouts be Permitted?

Sunspot Bank Runs and Fragility: The Role of Financial Sector Competition

Radner Equilibrium: Definition and Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

Fire sales, inefficient banking and liquidity ratios

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin

Bailouts and Financial Fragility

Banks and Liquidity Crises in Emerging Market Economies

Economia Finanziaria e Monetaria

Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime Chang and Velasco JET 2000 and NBER 6469

MFE Macroeconomics Week 8 Exercises

Global Games and Financial Fragility:

Money, financial stability and efficiency

Section 9, Chapter 2 Moral Hazard and Insurance

SI 563 Homework 3 Oct 5, Determine the set of rationalizable strategies for each of the following games. a) X Y X Y Z

Bailouts, Bank Runs, and Signaling

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Fire sales externalities: how liquidity ratios can help restore the liquidity insurance provided by banks

Revision Lecture. MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I

Global Financial Systems Chapter 8 Bank Runs and Deposit Insurance

Banks and Liquidity Crises in Emerging Market Economies

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Optimal Financial Crises

Macroeconomia 1 Class 14a revised Diamond Dybvig model of banks

FINANCIAL CONTAGION IN THE LABORATORY: DOES NETWORK STRUCTURE MATTER?

PRINCETON UNIVERSITY Economics Department Bendheim Center for Finance. FINANCIAL CRISES ECO 575 (Part II) Spring Semester 2003

Banks and Liquidity Crises in an Emerging Economy

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports

1 Dynamic programming

Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress

Lecture 5 Crisis: Sustainable Debt, Public Debt Crisis, and Bank Runs

Séptimas Jornadas de Economía Monetaria e Internacional La Plata, 9 y 10 de mayo de 2002

Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

COUNTRY RISK AND CAPITAL FLOW REVERSALS by: Assaf Razin 1 and Efraim Sadka 2

Liquidity, moral hazard and bank runs

Government Safety Net, Stock Market Participation and Asset Prices

Bank Runs and Institutions: The Perils of Intervention

Credit Market Competition and Liquidity Crises

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014

Microeconomic Theory May 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A BRAZILIAN DEBT-CRISIS MODEL. Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka. Working Paper

ECE 586BH: Problem Set 5: Problems and Solutions Multistage games, including repeated games, with observed moves

Economics 171: Final Exam

Microeconomics Qualifying Exam

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Institutional Finance

Ilkka Kiema, Research Coordinator, Labour Institute for Economic Research

Econ 8602, Fall 2017 Homework 2

Information Acquisition, Coordination, and Fundamentals in a Financial Crisis

Moral hazard, e ciency and bank crises

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV. If any mistakes or typos are spotted, kindly communicate them to

Part A: Answer Question A1 (required) and Question A2 or A3 (choice).

Interbank Market Liquidity and Central Bank Intervention

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES BAILOUTS, TIME INCONSISTENCY, AND OPTIMAL REGULATION. V.V. Chari Patrick J. Kehoe

Globalization, Exchange Rate Regimes and Financial Contagion

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Illiquidity and Under-Valuation of Firms

Antoine Martin (Federal Reserve Bank of New York) Bank liquidity, Interbank Market and Monetary Policy. le 2 juillet 2009, 14:30 16:00.

Scarce Collateral, the Term Premium, and Quantitative Easing

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

Experimental Evidence of Bank Runs as Pure Coordination Failures

Bank Runs: The Pre-Deposit Game

Discussion Liquidity requirements, liquidity choice and financial stability by Doug Diamond

Advanced Macroeconomics I ECON 525a - Fall 2009 Yale University

International Journal of Economic Theory

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

Discount Window Policy, Banking Crises, and Indeterminacy of Equilibrium 1

Discussion of Calomiris Kahn. Economics 542 Spring 2012

Microeconomics II. CIDE, Spring 2011 List of Problems

FISCAL POLICY AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS. C 1t + S t + B t P t = 1 (1) C 2,t+1 = R tb t P t+1 S t 0, B t 0. (3)

Global Games and Illiquidity

Transcription:

BANKING AND FINANCIAL FRAGILITY A Baseline Model: Diamond and Dybvig (1983) Professor Todd Keister Rutgers University May 2017

Objective Want to develop a model to help us understand: why banks and other financial institutions tend to have a maturity mismatch between their assets and liabilities in what way(s) this maturity mismatch can create the type of financial crises we see in reality and use this model to evaluate policy proposals Our model will be very simple in some dimensions but we will get a remarkable amount of mileage out of it Readings: Diamond & Dybvig (JPE, 1983) Allen & Gale, chapter 3 2

Outline 1. The Environment 2. Autarky 3. The Efficient Allocation 4. Banking 5. Two Views of Financial Fragility 6. Summary 3

1. The Environment 4

1.1 Time and commodities 3 time periods t = 0, 1, 2 Single consumption good in each period 5

1.2 Economic agents Continuum of investors, i 0,1 Each is endowed with 1 unit of the good at t = 0 and nothing at t = 1, 2 Each has utility function u c 1 i u c 2 i a if investor i is denote type by ω i Ω = 1,2 type 1 "impatient" type 2 "patient" At t = 0, investor does not know her type learns type at t = 1 type is private information 6

Uncertainty Each investor will be impatient with probability λ 0,1 λ also = fraction of all investors who will be impatient no aggregate uncertainty here only uncertainty is about which investors will be impatient Consumption plans A consumption plan for investor i is c i = c 1 i, c 2 i R + 2 7

1.3 Technologies Two assets for transforming t = 0 goods to later periods Storage: 1 unit at t = 0 t = 1 a yields 1 at t = 1 1 at t = 2 Investment: 1 unit at t = 0 yields r < 1 at t = 1 R > 1 at t = 2 investment can only be started at t = 0 1 r = liquidation cost 8

2. Allocations under Autarky 9

Suppose there is no trade each investor divides her endowment at t = 0 between storage and investment consumes the proceeds at either t = 1 or t = 2 Let x = amount placed into investment 1 x is placed into storage Investor s objective: Feasibility constraints: max x λλ c 1 + 1 λ u c 2 c 1 = rr + 1 x = 1 1 r x c 2 = RR + 1 x = 1 + R 1 x 10

Restating the investor s maximization problem: max x 0,1 λλ c 1 + 1 λ u c 2 subject to c 1 = 1 1 r x c 2 = 1 + R 1 x c 2 R x = 1 best allocation under autarky 1 x = 0 Q: Is this allocation Pareto optimal? r 1 c 1 11

3. The (full information) efficient allocation 12

3.1 Definitions An allocation is a list of consumption plans: c i i 1, c 2 An allocation is symmetric if i 0,1 c 1 i, c 2 i = c 1 j, c 2 j for all i, j characterized by only two numbers Under full information, investors preference types are observable (to the planner) Q: What is the best symmetric allocation the planner can implement under full information? 13

3.2 Some properties of efficient allocations The efficient allocation of resources in this environment requires: no investment should be liquidated at t = 1 no storage should be held until t = 2 recall that there is no aggregate uncertainty here In our notation: λc 1 = 1 x 1 λ c 2 = RR Combining to eliminate x: λc 1 + 1 λ c 2 R = 1 14

Repeating λc 1 + 1 λ c 2 R = 1 c 2 R 1 λ R 1 set of feasible symmetric allocations The planner can do better than autarky (Why?) r 1 1 λ c 1 15

3.3 Finding the best symmetric allocation The full-information efficient allocation solves max c 1,c 2 λλ c 1 + 1 λ u c 2 subject to λc 1 + 1 λ c 2 R = 1 multiplier = μ First-order conditions: λu c 1 = λλ 1 λ u c 2 = 1 λ μ R or Solution: u c 1 = Ru c 2 c 1, c 2 with c 1 < c 2 16

Depending on the function u, we can have c 2 c 2 c 2 45 o 45 o 45 o R R R 1 c 1 1 c 1 1 c 1 Efficient level of investment: x = (1 λ) c 2 R or 1 x = λc 1 17

Exercises We know c 1, c 2 solves: max c 1,c 2 λλ c 1 + 1 λ u c 2 subject to λc 1 + 1 λ c 2 R = 1 Find c 1, c 2 for the following utility functions: u c = ln c u c = c (risk neutral) A: c 1, c 2 = (1, R) A: c 1, c 2 = (0, R 1 λ ) 18

4. Banking 19

4.1 More on the environment Return to the case where types are private information Investors can meet at t = 0, but are isolated from each other at t = 1 cannot trade with each other Each investor can visit a central location at t = 1 before consuming arrive one at a time must consume when they arrive (ice cream on a hot day) These assumptions aim to capture transaction needs when a consumption opportunity arises, investors cannot quickly sell illiquid assets 20

4.2 A banking arrangement Suppose a bank opens at t = 0, offers the following deal: deposit at t = 0 you can withdraw at either t = 1 or t = 2 (your choice) Bank places a fraction x of its assets into investment Investors who choose t = 1 will receive c 1 as long as the bank has funds available Investors who choose t = 2 will receive an even share of the bank s matured assets These rules create a withdrawal game each investor decides when to withdraw payoffs depend on the choices made by all investors 21

4.3 Withdrawal strategies First: impatient investors will always withdraw at t = 1 do not value consumption at t = 2 We only need to determine what an investor will do in the event she is patient A withdrawal strategy is: y i 1,2 where y i = t means withdraw in period t when patient More notation: y = y i i 0,1 is a complete profile of withdrawal strategies y i = profile of strategies for all investors except i 22

4.4 Best responses Suppose an investor anticipates y i = 2 that is, all other investors will withdraw at t = 2 when patient What is her best response? if she withdraws at t = 1: c 1 if she withdraws at t = 2: even share of matured investment what is this even share worth? matured investment patient depositors Rx 1 λ = 1 λ c 2 1 λ = c 2 We know c 2 > c 1 best response y i = 2 23

4.5 Equilibrium A Nash equilibrium is a profile of withdrawal strategies y such that, for all i, y i is a best response to y i. focus on symmetric equilibria in pure strategies Result 1: There is a Nash equilibrium with y i = 2 for all i. In this equilibrium: impatient investors withdraw at t = 1, receive c 1 patient investors withdraw at t = 2, receive c 2 implements the (full information) efficient allocation even though types are private information (!) 24

4.6 Interpretations Notice what the bank is doing in this model issuing demand deposits while holding (some) illiquid assets Why is this activity socially desirable? because investors face uncertainty about their liquidity needs bank allows all investors to hold liquid claims This activity is often called maturity transformation emphasize that this a productive activity bank is producing liquidity also called fractional reserve banking 25

Suppose we construct the balance sheet of this bank Assets Liabilities Investment Rx Deposits c 1 Storage 1 x Equity E note that investment is valued at hold to maturity price Equity (or bank capital ) is defined as Assets Liabilities E Rx + 1 x c 1 A bank is said to be solvent if E 0 by design, our banking arrangement is solvent even though some of the bank s assets are illiquid 26

5. Two views of financial fragility 27

So far: it can be socially useful to have banks doing maturity transformation allows all investors to hold liquid claims while (partially) benefitting from the higher return on illiquid investment In practice, maturity transformation appears to be at the center of many financial crises What does our model say about the fragility of this banking arrangement? We can see two views of what happens during a crisis 28

5.1 Self-fulfilling bank runs Q: Does the withdrawal game have other equilibria? Suppose investor i anticipates: y i = 1 everyone else will run and withdraw at first opportunity What is her best response? the bank will start liquidating investment should she join the run? More generally: Find the best response of investor i to any profile y i 29

For any y i, define: e y i = number of t = 1 withdrawals that will be made by patient investors ( extra withdrawals at t = 1) equals number of investors who have y i = 1 and are patient note: e 0,1 λ To find best response of investor i: compare expected payoffs of withdrawing at t = 1 and t = 2 both of these payoffs will depend on e 30

If a patient investor chooses t = 1, she receives c 1 if (and only if) bank has funds available when she arrives If she chooses t = 2, she receives: an even share of the bank s remaining (matured) assets critical question: what is this even share worth? At t = 2, the bank will have: 1 x λc 1 + R x e c 1 r storage first λ withdrawals = 0 investment liquidated for extra t = 1 withdrawals 31

Repeating: the bank will have R x e c 1 r Number of remaining investors: 1 λ e An even share is worth: c 2 e = max R x e c 1 r 1 λ e, 0 Q: What does this function look like? Note: c 2 0 = Rx 1 λ = c 2 (as before) 32

Assume c 1 > 1 1 r x (A1) this condition implies the bank is illiquid it cannot afford to give c 1 to all investors at t = 1 Then (you can verify): dc 2 (e) < 0 dd and c 2 e = 0 for some e < 1 λ and c 2 e is strictly concave on (0, e B ) 33

Graphically: c 2 (e) c 2 c 1 Define: e T ( threshold ) so that c 2 e T = c 1 e T e B 1 λ e Define: e B ( bankruptcy ) so that c 2 e B = 0 34

Summarizing investor i s payoffs: e < e T e T < e < e B e > e B t = 1: c 1 c 1 c 1 or 0 t = 2: c 2 e > c 1 c 2 e < c 1 0 For any y i, the best response of investor i is: if e y i e T 2, then y i = 2 1 1 If y i = 1, then e y i = 1 λ > e T, so best response is y i = 1 Result 2: There is also a Nash equilibrium with y i = 1 for all i. 35

This second equilibrium resembles the bank runs we have seen during financial crises a panic, but with fully rational investors nothing fundamental is wrong; bank is still solvent the crisis is (simply) a result of self-fulfilling beliefs Another look at the balance sheet: Assets Liabilities Investment rx Deposits c 1 Storage 1 x Equity E If assets are valued at liquidation prices, equity becomes E rx + 1 x c 1 < 0 36

hold to maturity prices Assets Liabilities Investment Rx Deposits c 1 Storage 1 x Equity E liquidation prices Assets Liabilities Investment rx Deposits c 1 Storage 1 x Equity E A bank is solvent if E 0; otherwise it is insolvent A bank is liquid if E 0; otherwise it is illiquid (repeat) (new) Results 1 and 2: When a bank is solvent but illiquid, the withdrawal game has (at least) two equilibria: y i = 2 for all i: implements the planner s allocation c 1, c 2 y i = 1 for all i: a bank run self-fulfilling financial fragility 37

Properties of the bank-run equilibrium: Fraction of investors served: total assets 1 1 r x q = < 1 amount per investor c 1 c 1 Expected utility in the bank-run equilibrium: qq c < u qc 1 + 1 q u 0 1 + 1 q 0 = u 1 1 r x < u 1 u autarky (! ) Outcome is worse than having no bank at all 38

5.2 Bad news and bank runs Suppose at t = 1 investors learn the return on investment has fallen to R L < R unexpected shock (for simplicity) banking contract (that is, x, c 1 ) is already fixed An investor who withdraws at t = 2 now receives c 2 e = max R L x e c 1 r 1 λ e, 0 Focus on: c 2 0 = R Lx 1 λ 39

Consider two possibilities: R LL < R L < R c 2 (e) c 2 c 1 At R L, there are two equilibria, as before At R LL, withdrawing at t = 1 is a dominant strategy! A bank run is the unique Nash equilibrium e T L < 0! e L T e T e B 1 λ e 40

How low must R L be for withdrawing at t = 1 to become a dominant strategy? Start with c 2 0 = R Lx 1 λ Using x = (1 λ) c 2, we have R c 2 0 = R L R c 2 Withdrawing at t = 1 is a dominant strategy if: c 2 0 < c 1 or R L < c 1 c R R L 2 41

Another view Assets Liabilities Investment R L x Deposits c 1 Storage 1 x Equity E hold to maturity value of investment has fallen equity is now: E = R L x + 1 x c 1 (Verify:) R L < R L E < 0 if the loss is large enough to make the bank insolvent withdrawing at t = 1 is a dominant strategy 42

Result 3: If R L < R L, the unique Nash equilibrium strategy profile is y i = 1 for all i. If the bank is insolvent, arrangement necessarily collapses if c 1 is close to c 2, the required losses would be very small Fraction of investors served in the run: q = 1 1 r x c 1 independent of R L! Why? Because during a run, all investment is liquidated same as when the run was based on self-fulfilling beliefs 43

An example: u c = ln(c) verify: c 1, c 2 = (1, R) also: r = 1 2, λ = 1 2 verify: x = 1 2 then (verify) R L = 1 Suppose R L = 0.99 it is socially feasible to give all investors (almost) 1 unit The equilibrium allocation gives 1 to a fraction q = 1 1 r x = 3 c 1 4 and nothing to the remaining 1/4 (much worse!) 44

6. Summary 45

Takeaways from Diamond & Dybvig (1983) Maturity transformation is socially useful D&D gave us a good model for thinking about where the value comes from banks are in the business of creating liquidity but makes banks fragile Two ways of thinking about this fragility a bank that is solvent but illiquid is susceptible to a run a loss of confidence for whatever reason leads to a run a bank that is insolvent will necessarily have a run small losses on a bank s assets can have large consequences 46

References and further reading Franklin Allen and Douglas Gale (2007) Understanding Financial Crises, Oxford University Press. see especially Chapters 3 and 5 Diamond, Douglas W. and Phillip H. Dybvig (1983) Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity, Journal of Political Economy 91: 401-419. Diamond, Douglas W. (2007) Banks and Liquidity Creation: A Simple Exposition of the Diamond-Dybvig Model, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 93: 189-200. 47