Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Microeconomics, Questions 1-2

Similar documents
AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally.

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Strategy -1- Strategy

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

INTRODUCTORY ECONOMICS

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

Games of Incomplete Information ( 資訊不全賽局 ) Games of Incomplete Information

Francesco Nava Microeconomic Principles II EC202 Lent Term 2010

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Today. Applications of NE and SPNE Auctions English Auction Second-Price Sealed-Bid Auction First-Price Sealed-Bid Auction

Microeconomics I. Undergraduate Programs in Business Administration and Economics

Bayesian Nash Equilibrium

S 2,2-1, x c C x r, 1 0,0

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

Economics Honors Exam Review (Micro) Mar Based on Zhaoning Wang s final review packet for Ec 1010a, Fall 2013

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals.

Honors General Exam PART 1: MICROECONOMICS. Solutions. Harvard University April 2013

Economics 101A (Lecture 21) Stefano DellaVigna

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

Economics 212 Microeconomic Theory Final Exam. April 24, Faculty of Arts and Sciences Queen s University

Game Theory Lecture #16

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Second Midterm Examination Answers

Noncooperative Market Games in Normal Form

Economics 335 Problem Set 6 Spring 1998

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 4

Economics 101A (Lecture 21) Stefano DellaVigna

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 4

HE+ Economics Nash Equilibrium

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik ( December 29, 2008

2 Maximizing pro ts when marginal costs are increasing

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 26, Lecture 28. Oligopoly

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 2 with Solutions

ECO 426 (Market Design) - Lecture 8

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 10, Question 1

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours

AS/ECON AF Answers to Assignment 1 October Q1. Find the equation of the production possibility curve in the following 2 good, 2 input

Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. a 2bQ c = 0, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated price is. P (Q) = a b

MA300.2 Game Theory 2005, LSE

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

Chapter 10: Price Competition Learning Objectives Suggested Lecture Outline: Lecture 1: Lecture 2: Suggestions for the Instructor:

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

Simon Fraser University Spring 2014

Microeconomics, IB and IBP. Regular EXAM, December 2011 Open book, 4 hours

ECON 102 Boyle Final Exam New Material Practice Exam Solutions

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

Answer Key for M. A. Economics Entrance Examination 2017 (Main version)

A folk theorem for one-shot Bertrand games

B w x y z a 4,4 3,3 5,1 2,2 b 3,6 2,5 6,-3 1,4 A c -2,0 2,-1 0,0 2,1 d 1,4 1,2 1,1 3,5

A monopoly is an industry consisting a single. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two. An oligopoly is an industry consisting of a few

Notes on Auctions. Theorem 1 In a second price sealed bid auction bidding your valuation is always a weakly dominant strategy.

Strategy -1- Strategic equilibrium in auctions

Advanced Microeconomic Theory EC104

Economics Honors Exam 2008 Solutions Question 1

Open Math in Economics MA National Convention 2017 For each question, E) NOTA indicates that none of the above answers is correct.

Oligopoly Games and Voting Games. Cournot s Model of Quantity Competition:

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

EconS Games with Incomplete Information II and Auction Theory

Copenhagen Business School Regular Exam. Please answer all questions. All questions carry equal marks and are equally weighted.

Microeconomics I - Midterm

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

2. $ CHAPTER 10 - MONOPOLY. Answers to select-numbered problems: MC ATC P * Quantity

Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Principles of Microeconomics Final Exam Wednesday, October 10th, 2007

HW Consider the following game:

Auction is a commonly used way of allocating indivisible

Problem 3,a. ds 1 (s 2 ) ds 2 < 0. = (1+t)

ECS2601 Oct / Nov 2014 Examination Memorandum. (1a) Raymond has a budget of R200. The price of food is R20 and the price of clothes is R50.

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Graduate School of Management and Economics

0 $50 $0 $5 $-5 $50 $35 1 $50 $50 $40 $10 $50 $15 2 $50 $100 $55 $45 $50 $35 3 $50 $150 $90 $60 $50 $55 4 $50 $200 $145 $55 $65

Problems on game theory and pricing practices (chapters 14 and 15)

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

ECO 426 (Market Design) - Lecture 9

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Final Exam Suggested Solutions

Consumer surplus is zero and the outcome is Pareto efficient since there is no deadweight loss.

Answer ALL questions from Section A and ONE question from Section B. Section A weighs 60% of the total mark and Section B 40% of the total mark.

PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM Welfare Analysis

In Class Exercises. Problem 1

Economics 111 Exam 1 Fall 2005 Prof Montgomery

MS&E HW #1 Solutions

Microeconomics 2nd Period Exam Solution Topics

ANSWERS FINAL 342 VERSION 1

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #9 - Monopoly

EC303 Economic Analysis of the EU. EC303 Class Note 5. Daniel Vernazza * Office Hour: Monday 15:30-16:30 Room S109

Game Theory Problem Set 4 Solutions

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017

PRISONER S DILEMMA. Example from P-R p. 455; also 476-7, Price-setting (Bertrand) duopoly Demand functions

Auctions and Common Property

Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma

There are 10 questions on this exam. These 10 questions are independent of each other.

Exercise Chapter 10

ECON 310 Fall 2005 Final Exam - Version A. Multiple Choice: (circle the letter of the best response; 3 points each) and x

LECTURE NOTES ON GAME THEORY. Player 2 Cooperate Defect Cooperate (10,10) (-1,11) Defect (11,-1) (0,0)

Transcription:

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Microeconomics, Questions 1-2 Question 1 (Microeconomics, 30 points). A ticket to a newly staged opera is on sale through sealed-bid auction. There are three bidders, Alice, Bert and Carl. Alice values the ticket at $10, Bert at $20, and Carl at $30. The bidders are free to submit a bid of any positive amount. a. (6 points) Show that there is no dominant strategy for any bidder if the highest bidder wins the ticket and pays his own bid. If the highest bidder wins the object and pays his bid, then any bid below his own valuation can be the optimal bid. For example, for Alice who has a valuation of $10, bidding $5 is better than $9 if the other two bidders bid below $5, since she wins the ticket with either bid but the lower bid means she pays less and gives her a higher payoff. However, if the other two bidders bid between $5 and $9, bidding $5 makes her to lose the ticket, while bidding $9 makes her to win the auction and get the ticket at a price less than the valuation which yield a positive payoff. The same logic applies to all other bids below the bidder s valuation for all three bidders. There isn t any bid which will always yield a higher payoff for the bidder than all other bids. 6 points for a well-illustrated answer, preferably with examples. Partial credit at the grader s own judgement. b. (5 points) From now on, assume this is a second-price auction, that is, the highest bidder wins the ticket and pays the second-highest bid. If everyone bids his or her own valuation, what is the payoff of each bidder? If everyone bids his or her own evaluation, Carl wins the object and pays $20. Hence his payoff is 30 20 = $10. The other two bidders get 0. 2 points for Carl winning. 1 point each for the 3 bidders payoff. 1

c. (4 points) Show that everyone bids his or her own valuation is a Nash Equilibrium. To see if this is a Nash Equilibrium, we see if any bidder wants to change their bids. If everyone bids his or her own valuation, both Alice and Bert get a payoff of zero since they will not win the auction. If they change their bids to below $30, they will still not win the auction; if they change their bids to higher than $30, they will win the ticket but will have to pay at least $30 for it, which is higher than their valuation and give them negative payoffs. Therefore both Alice and Bert have no incentive to change their bids. Carl gets a payoff of $10 since he values the ticket at $30 but only has to pay $20 for it. If he changes his bid to a value about $20, his payoff will not change; if he changes his bid to a value below $20, he will not win the auction and will only get a payoff of 0 which is less than what he is getting before. Since no change will give him a higher payoff, Carl has no incentive to change his bid. Since all the bidders have no incentive to change their bids, this is a Nash Equilibrium. 2 points to show the high bidder will not deviate. 2 points to show the low bidders will not deviate. d. (7 points) Now suppose that there is a large number of tickets on sale and a large number of bidders, with 1 of them valuing the ticket at $10, 1 at $20 and 1 3 3 3 at $30. Each ticket is sold at a second-price sealed-bid auction independent of other auctions, and each auction has 3 bidders attending, where each of them can be any of the three types. Knowing that each bidder will still bid his or her own valuation, what is the expected revenue from a single auction? (Note: if there is a tie, for example: (20, 20, 10), the second highest bid will be 20) Since each of the 3 bidders can be of any type, there will be a total of 3 3 3 = 27 outcomes. To calculate the expected revenue, we need to count the number of outcomes that yields a particular value of revenue. To get $10, we need the second-highest bid to be $10, hence we have the bids being: (10, 10, 10) 1 case (10, 10, 20) 3 cases (10, 10, 30) 3 cases for a total of 7 cases. 2

To get $20, we need the second-highest bid to be $20, hence we have the bids being: (10, 20, 30) 6 cases (20, 20, 30) 3 cases (20, 20, 20) 1 case (20, 20, 10) 3 cases for a total of 13 cases. To get $30, we need the second-highest bid to be $30, hence we have the bids being: (30, 30, 30) 1 case (30, 30, 20) 3 cases (30, 30, 10) 3 cases for a total of 7 cases. Hence the expected revenue is 7 13 10 + 27 27 20 + 7 30 = $20 27 3 points for the correct method. 1 point each for each correct probability. 1 point for the correct answer. e. (8 points) The auctioneer knows that if the tickets are not sold, they can be sold later for $15 each. Therefore he sets a minimum bids of $15 for each auction. That is, if the second-highest price is less than $15, the highest bidder will be asked to pay $15. Bidders may choose to bid $0, in which case they will not win the ticket even if all the other bidders bid $0 (the ticket will not be sold if all 3 bidders bid $0. However, for example, if the bids are (20, 0, 0), the second highest bid is 0, and the bidder who bids $20 will win the ticket and pay $15). How much will each type of bidders bid in the Nash Equilibrium, and what is the expected revenue from a single auction, not counting the later sale if the ticket is not sold? The bidders who have a valuation of $10 always get a payoff of 0 in (d) whether they win the auction or not. With a minimum price of $15, they may get a negative payoff if they bid a positive value and win the auction. Hence the bidders with $10 valuation will bid 0. The bidders with $20 and $30 valuation will still bid their own valuation, by the same logic as in (c). To calculate the expected revenue, we need to count the number of outcomes that yields a particular value of revenue. There are still a total of 27 outcomes. The ticket is not sold if all bidders have a valuation of $10, which is 1 case. To get $15, we need the second-highest bid to be 0, hence we have the bids being: (0, 0, 20) 3 outcomes (0, 0, 30) 3 outcomes for a total of 6 cases. 3

To get $20, we need the second-highest bid to be $20, hence we have the bids being: (10, 20, 30) 6 cases (20, 20, 30) 3 cases (20, 20, 20) 1 case (20, 20, 10) 3 cases for a total of 13 cases. To get $30, we need the second-highest bid to be $30, hence we have the bids being: (30, 30, 30) 1 case (30, 30, 20) 3 cases (30, 30, 10) 3 cases for a total of 7 cases. Hence the expected revenue is 6 13 15 + 27 27 20 + 7 30 = $560 27 27 4 points to explain the new bids. 2 points to note when the ticket will not be sold. 1 point for using the same probabilities as in (d). 1 point for the correct answer. 4

Question 2 (Microeconomics, 30 points). The demand function in a particular industry is of the form q = 100, where q is the quantity demanded and p p 2 is the price. The technology in the market is such that each unit can be produced at the constant cost of $5. a. (4 points) If the industry is supplied by perfectly competitive firms, what is the equilibrium price and industry output? What is the price elasticity of demand faced by a single firm at this price if the firm increases its price? When the industry is perfectly competitive, we have p = M C. Therefore the equilibrium price is $5, and industry output is 100 25 = 4 For any perfectly competitive firm, if it wants to increase its price above the equilibrium price, it will lose all its customers. Therefore the price elasticity it faces is infinity. 1 point for the correct method. 1 point each for price, quantity, and elasticity. b. (10 points) If the industry is supplied by a monopolist, what is the equilibrium price and industry output? What is the price elasticity of demand faced by the monopolist at this price if the firm increases its price? A monopolist will equate its marginal revenue to the marginal cost. We calculate the total revenue as: And marginal revenue is: T R = pq = ( 100 q ) 1 1 2 q = 10q 2 MR = dt R dq = 5q 1 2 Equate this to MC = 5, we have q = 1, and p = 100 = 10. 5

The price elasticity of demand is calculated as dq dp p q = 200p 3 p = 2 100p 2 which is constant at any position on the demand curve. 2 points for noting MR=MC. 2 points for TR. 2 points for MR. 2 points for p and q. 2 points for elasticity. c. (11 points) If the industry is supplied by two identical oligopolists engaged in Cournot (simultaneous quantity setting) competition, what is the equilibrium price and industry output? From firm 1 s point of view, the price may be expressed as: 100 p = ( ) 1 2 q 1 + q 2 = 10(q1 + q 2 ) 1 2 Hence firm 1 s total revenue is T R 1 = 10q 1 (q 1 + q 2 ) 1 2 Its marginal revenue is calculated as the following, taking q 2 as given: MR 1 = dt R 1 dq 1 = 10(q 1 + q 2 ) 3 1 2 ( 2 q 1 + q 2 ) Since the two firms are identical, we must have q 1 = q 2. Substitute this into the marginal revenue expression and equate it to 5, we get 10(2q 1 ) 3 2 ( 3 2 q 1) = 5 Solving, we get q 1 = 9 8. Since q 2 = q 1, we must have total output being 2q 1 = 9 4. And industry price is 10 9 4 1 2 = 20 3. 6

2 points for price (first equation). 2 points for TR. 2 points for MR. 1 point for noting q 1 = q 2. 2 points for q. 2 points for p. d. (5 points) If the industry is supplied by two identical oligopolists engaged in Betrand (simultaneous price setting) competition, what is the equilibrium price and industry output? If there are n Betrand oligopolists, what is the equilibrium price and industry output? In Betrand competition, price will fall to the marginal cost at equilibrium. Otherwise, a firm can always cut prices to capture the entire market. Hence we will have p = 5, q = 4. This result is the same for any number of Betrand oligopolists. 1 point for the correct argument. 1 point each for each answer (price/quantity two firms/n firms). 7