Theory of the rate of return

Similar documents
1 The Solow Growth Model

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Technical change is labor-augmenting (also known as Harrod neutral). The production function exhibits constant returns to scale:

Midterm Examination Number 1 February 19, 1996

Lecture Notes in Macroeconomics. Christian Groth

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics

2. Aggregate Demand and Output in the Short Run: The Model of the Keynesian Cross

LEC 2: Exogenous (Neoclassical) growth model

1 Chapter 1: Economic growth

14.05 Intermediate Applied Macroeconomics Exam # 1 Suggested Solutions

2014/2015, week 6 The Ramsey model. Romer, Chapter 2.1 to 2.6

Notes on classical growth theory (optional read)

Introduction to economic growth (2)

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

Test Questions. Part I Midterm Questions 1. Give three examples of a stock variable and three examples of a flow variable.

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation.

Macroeconomics I, UPF Professor Antonio Ciccone SOLUTIONS PROBLEM SET 1

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Theories of Growth and Development Fall 2001, Midterm I

Aggregate Implications of Credit Market Imperfections (II) By Kiminori Matsuyama. Updated on January 25, 2010

202: Dynamic Macroeconomics

Reply to the Second Referee Thank you very much for your constructive and thorough evaluation of my note, and for your time and attention.

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints

Simple Notes on the ISLM Model (The Mundell-Fleming Model)

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

Ch.3 Growth and Accumulation. Production function and constant return to scale

Solow instead assumed a standard neo-classical production function with diminishing marginal product for both labor and capital.

TOPIC 1: IS-LM MODEL...3 TOPIC 2: LABOUR MARKET...23 TOPIC 3: THE AD-AS MODEL...33 TOPIC 4: INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT...41 TOPIC 5: MONETARY POLICY

Part III. Cycles and Growth:

IN THIS LECTURE, YOU WILL LEARN:

Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

1. Money in the utility function (continued)

Working Paper No. 807

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

Ageing Population and Implications for Monetary Policy. By Sirawit Woramongkhon (Blink)

11.1 Market economy with a public sector

Macroeconomics. Based on the textbook by Karlin and Soskice: Macroeconomics: Institutions, Instability, and the Financial System

II. Determinants of Asset Demand. Figure 1

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 2013 D. Romer

San Francisco State University ECON 302. Money

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015

Innovations in Macroeconomics

Macroeconomics Review Course LECTURE NOTES

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Business Cycles II: Theories

Ch.3 Growth and Accumulation. Production function and constant return to scale

SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY Department of Economics. Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory Spring PROBLEM SET 1 (Solutions) Y = C + I + G + NX

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Spring Trade and Development. Instructions

In this chapter, you will learn C H A P T E R National Income: Where it Comes From and Where it Goes CHAPTER 3

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

Lesson 8: Aggregate demand; consumption, investment, public expenditure and taxation.

Economics Macroeconomic Theory. Spring Final Exam, Tuesday 6 May 2003

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Problem Set # 7, Questions

Chapter 4. Determination of Income and Employment 4.1 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND ITS COMPONENTS

Trade and Development

ECON 3010 Intermediate Macroeconomics. Chapter 3 National Income: Where It Comes From and Where It Goes

TREATMENT OF INTEREST ON INDEX-LINKED DEBT INSTRUMENTS 1

Options for Fiscal Consolidation in the United Kingdom

Lecture 3 Growth Model with Endogenous Savings: Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

Part 1: Short answer, 60 points possible Part 2: Analytical problems, 40 points possible

Københavns Universitet Exercise Problems for Advanced Macroeconomics.

Investment, Time, and Capital Markets

Comments on Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy, by Cúrdia and Woodford

Money in an RBC framework

Chapter 26 Transmission Mechanisms of Monetary Policy: The Evidence

ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section

International Financial Markets 1. How Capital Markets Work

Chapter 17 (6) Output and the Exchange Rate in the Short Run

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

ECON Chapter 6: Economic growth: The Solow growth model (Part 1)

INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMICS

Gehrke: Macroeconomics Winter term 2012/13. Exercises

1 Four facts on the U.S. historical growth experience, aka the Kaldor facts

Lecture 6 Search and matching theory

I. The Money Market. A. Money Demand (M d ) Handout 9

Economics II/Intermediate Macroeconomics (No. 5025) Prof. Dr. Gerhard Schwödiauer/ Prof. Dr. Joachim Weimann. Semester: Winter Semester 2002/03

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth

Department of Economics Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Intermediate Macroeconomics

Analytical Problem Set

CHAPTER 2 Measurement

Chapter 4. Economic Growth

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

Government spending in a model where debt effects output gap

Consumption and Savings (Continued)

INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMICS

Employment, Unemployment and Turnover

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

Part A: Answer Question A1 (required) and Question A2 or A3 (choice).

Characterization of the Optimum

A Two-sector Ramsey Model

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography

Lectures 13 and 14: Fixed Exchange Rates

Notes on Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification. Lawrence Christiano

Real Business Cycle (RBC) Theory

Chapter 7 Externalities, Human Capital and Endogenous Growth

A Re-examination of Economic Growth, Tax Policy, and Distributive Politics

Transcription:

Macroeconomics 2 Short Note 2 06.10.2011. Christian Groth Theory of the rate of return Thisshortnotegivesasummaryofdifferent circumstances that give rise to differences intherateofreturnondifferent assets. We also provide a brief sketch of what macroeconomics can say about the general level around which these rates of return fluctuate. In non-monetary models without uncertainty there is in equilibrium only one rate of return, If in addition there is perfect competition in all markets and no capital adjustment costs, as in simple neoclassical models (like the Diamond OLG model or the Ramsey model), then the equilibrium real interest rate is at any time equal to the net marginal product of capital ( = standard notation) Moreover, under conditions ensuring well-behavedness of these models, they predict that the capital intensity, and thereby the marginal product of capital, adjusts over time to some long-run level (on which more below). Different rates of return It goes without saying that the link between the real interest rate and the marginal product of capital is loosened by the need for means of payments. Or rather, this link is loosened by many factors among which money is just one. As we will see in Chapter 14, existence of convex capital adjustment costs loosens the link between and. The adjustment costs create a wedge between the price of investment goods and the market value of the marginal unit of installed capital. Besides the marginal product of capital, the possible capital gain in the market value of installed capital as well as the effect of the marginal unit of installed capital on future installation costs enter as co-determinants of the current rate of return on capital. When imperfect competition on the output markets rules, prices are typically set as a mark-up on marginal cost. This implies a wedge between the net marginal product of capital and capital costs. And when uncertainty and limited opportunities for risk spreadingareaddedtothemodel,awidespectrum of expected rates of return on different financial assets and expected marginal products of capital in different production 1

Arithmetic average Standard deviation Geometric average ----------------- Percent ----------------- Nominal values Small Company Stocks 17,3 33,2 12,5 Large Company Stocks 12,7 20,2 10,7 Long-Term Corporate Bonds 6,1 8,6 5,8 Long-Term Government Bonds 5,7 9,4 5,3 Intermediate-Term Government Bonds 5,5 5,7 5,3 U.S. Treasury Bills 3,9 3,2 3,8 Cash 0,0 0,0 0,0 Inflation rate 3,1 4,4 3,1 Real values Small Company Stocks 13,8 32,6 9,2 Large Company Stocks 9,4 20,4 7,4 Long-Term Corporate Bonds 3,1 9,9 2,6 Long-Term Government Bonds 2,7 10,6 2,2 Intermediate-Term Government Bonds 2,5 7,0 2,2 U.S. Treasury Bills 0,8 4,1 0,7 Cash -2,9 4,2-3,0 Table 1: Average annual rates of return on a range of US asset portfolios, 1926-2001. Source: Stocks, Bonds, Bills, and Inflation: Yearbook 2002, Valuation Edition. Ibbotson Associates, Inc. sectors arise, depending on the risk profiles of the different assets and production sectors. Moreover, the presence of taxation, and sometimes differential taxation on different asset returns, complicates the picture. Table 1 reports the nominal and real average annual rates of return on a range of US asset portfolios for the period 1926 2001. The portfolio of small company stocks had an annual real return of 13.8 per cent (the arithmetic average throughout the period). This is more than that of any of the other considered portfolios. Small company stocks are also seen to be the most volatile. The standard deviation of the annual real rate of return of the portfolio of small company stocks is almost eight times higher than that of the portfolio of U.S. Treasury bills (government zero coupon bonds with 30 days to maturity), with an average annual real return of only 0.8 per cent throughout the period. Explanation in terms of risk aversion is in line with the displayed positive relation between high returns and high volatility. Yet, interpreting volatility as a rough measure of risk, the pattern is not without exceptions. The portfolio of long-term corporate bonds has performed better than the portfolio of long-term government bonds, although they have been slightly less volatile as here measured. But the data is historical, expectations are 2

not always met, and risk depends significantly on the correlation of the asset s return with the business cycle, a feature about which Table?? has nothing say; share prices are in fact very sensitive to business cycle fluctuations. The need for means of payment money further complicates the picture. That is, besides differences in risk and expected return across different assets, also dissimilarities in their degree of liquidity are important, not least in times of financial crisis. The expected real rate of return on cash holding is minus the expected rate of inflation and is therefore negative in an economy with inflation, cf. the last row in Table??. When agents nevertheless hold money in their portfolios, it is because the low rate of return is compensated by the liquidity services of money. In the Sidrauski model of Chapter 17 this is modeled in a simple (albeit ad hoc) way by including real money holdings directly as an argument in the utility function. Another dimension along which the presence of money interferes with returns is through inflation. Real assets, like physical capital, land, houses, etc. are better protected against fluctuating inflation than are nominally denominated bonds (and money of course). Without claiming too much we can say that investors facing these multiple rates of return choose a portfolio composition so as to balance the need for liquidity, the wish for a high expected return, and the wish for low risk. Finance theory teaches us that adjusted for differences in risk and liquidity, asset returns tend to be the same. This raises the question: at what level? This is where macroeconomics as a theory about the economy as a whole comes to the fore. Macroeconomic theory of the trend level of rates of return The point of departure is that market forces by and large tend to anchor the rate of return of an average portfolio to the net marginal product of capital in an aggregate production function. Some popular phrases are: the net marginal product of capital acts as a centre of gravitation for asset returns; and movements of the rates of return are in the long run held in check by the net marginal product of capital. Though such phrases seem to convey the right flavour, in themselves they are not very informative. The net marginal product of capital is not a given, but an endogenous vari- 3

able which, via changes in the capital intensity, adjusts through time to more fundamental factors in the economy. The different macroeconomic models we have studied in previous chapters bring to mind different presumptions about what these fundamental factors are. 1. Solow s growth model The Solow growth model (Solow 1956) leads to the fundamental differential equation (standard notation) = ( ) ( + + ) where is an exogenous and constant aggregate saving rate, 0 1 In steady state = 0 ( ) (1) where is the unique steady state value of the (effective) capital intensity, satisfying ( )=( + + ) (2) In society there is a debate and a concern that changed demography and less growth in the source of new technical ideas, i.e., the stock of educated human beings, will in the future result in lower and lower respectively, making financing social security more difficult OnthebasisoftheSolowmodelwefind by implicit differentiation in (2) 1 = = h + + 0 ( )i which is negative since 0 ( ) ( ) = + + Hence, by (1), since 00 ( ) 0 It follows that = = = 00 ( ) + + 0 ( ) 0 or (3) 2. The Diamond OLG model The Diamond OLG model also just concludes that = 0 ( ). Like in the Solow model, the long-run rate of return thus depends on the aggregate production function and on which in turn may depend in a complicated way on the lifetime utility function and the production function. The steady state of a well-behaved Diamond model will nevertheless have the same qualitative property as indicated in (3). 4

3. The Ramsey model In contrast to the Solow and Diamond models, the Ramsey model implies not only that = 0 ( ) but also that the net marginal product of capital converges in the long run to a specific valuegivenbythemodified golden rule formula. In a continuous time framework this formula says: = + (4) where the new parameter, is the (absolute) elasticity of marginal utility of consumption. Because the Ramsey model is a representative agent model, the Keynes-Ramsey rule holds not only at the individual level, but also at the aggregate level. This is what gives rise to this simple formula for. Herethereisnorolefor only for On the other hand, there is an alternative specification of the Ramsey model, namely the discounted average utilitarianism specification. In this version of the Ramsey model, we get = 0 ( ) = + + so that not only a lower but also a lower implies lower Also the Sidrauski model, i.e., the monetary Ramsey model of Chapter 17, results in the modified golden rule formula. 4. Blanchard s OLG model A continuous time model with OLG structure and emphasis on life-cycle aspects is Blanchard s OLG model (Blanchard 1985). In that model the net marginal product of capital adjusts to a value within an interval: + + + where two additional parameters appear, the retirement rate (reflecting how early in life the average person retire from the labor market) and the crude birth rate ( =1for simplicity). The population growth rate is the difference between the crude birth rate, and the crude mortality rate, so that = The qualitative property indicated in (3) becomes conditional. It still holds if the fall in reflects a lower but not necessarily if it reflects a higher. 5. What if technological change is embodied? Themodelsinthelistaboveassume a neoclassical aggregate production function with CRS and disembodied Harrod-neutral technological progress, that is, = ( ) ( ) 0 0 00 0 (5) 5

This amounts to assuming that new technical knowledge advances the combined productivity of capital and labor independently of whether the workers operate old or new machines. In contrast, we say that technological change is embodied if taking advantage of new technical knowledge requires construction of new investment goods. The newest technology is incorporated in the design of newly produced equipment; and this equipment will not participate in subsequent technological progress. Both intuition and empirics suggest that most technological progress is of this form. Indeed, Greenwood et al. (1997) estimate for the U.S. 1950-1990 that embodied technological change explains 60% of the growth in output per man hour. So a theory of the rate of return should take this into account. Fortunately, this can be done with only minor modifications. We assume that the link between investment and capital accumulation takes the form = (6) where is gross investment ( = ) and measures the quality (productivity) of newly produced investment goods. Suppose for instance that = 0 0 Then, even if no technological change directly appears in the production function, that is, even if (5) is replaced by = ( ) = 1 0 1 the economy will still experience a rising standard of living. 1 A given level of gross investment will give rise to a greater and greater additions to the capital stock measured in efficiency units. Since at time capital goods can be produced at the same cost as one consumption good, the price, of capital goods in terms of the consumption good must in competitive equilibrium equal the inverse of that is, =1 In this way embodied technological progress results in a steady decline in the relative price of capital equipment. This prediction is confirmed by the data. Greenwood et al. (1997) find for the U.S. that the relative price of capital equipment has been declining at an average rate of 0 03 per year in the period 1950-1990, a trend that has seemingly been fortifiedinthewakeof the computer revolution. 1 We specify to be Cobb-Douglas, because otherwise a model with embodied technical progress in the form (6) will not be able to generate balanced growth and comply with Kaldor s stylized facts. 6

Along a balanced growth path the constant growth rate of will now exceed that of and thus be falling The output-capital ratio in value terms, ( ) will be constant, however. Embedding these features in a Ramsey-style framework, we find the long-run rate of return to be 2 = + 1 This is of exactly the same form as (4), if we define = (1 ) 6. Adding uncertainty and risk of bankruptcy Although absent from many simple macroeconomic models, uncertainty and risk of bankruptcy are significant features of reality. Bankruptcy risk may lead to a conflict of interest between share owners and managers. Managers may want less debt and more equity than the share owners because bankruptcy can be very costly to managers who loose a well-paid job and a promising carrier. So managers are unwilling to finance all new capital investment by new debt in spite of the associated lower capital cost (there is generally a lower rate of return on debt than on equity). In this way the excess of the rate of return on equity over that on debt, theequitypremium,issustained. A rough, behavioral theory of the equity premium goes as follows. 3 Firm managers prefer a payout structure with a fraction, going to equity and the remaining fraction, 1 to debt (corporate bonds). That is, out of each unit of expected operating profit, managers are unwilling to commit more than 1 to bond owners. This is to reduce the risk of a failing payment ability in case of a bad market outcome. And those who finance firms by loans definitely also want debtor firmstohavesomeequityatstake. We let households preferred portfolio consist of a fraction in equities and the remainder, 1, in bonds. In view of households risk aversion and memory of historical stock market crashes, it is plausible to assume that. As a crude adaptation of for instance the Blanchard OLG model to these features, we interpret the model s as an average rate of return across firms. Let time be discrete and let aggregate financial wealth be = where is the price of capital equipment in terms of consumption goods. In standard versions of the above models we have 1 but under item 5 above relative price. Anyway, given at time the aggregate gross return or payout is (1 + ). Outofthis,(1 + ) constitutes the gross return to the 2 See Appendix. 3 This builds on Baker et al. (2005). 7

equity owners and (1 + ) (1 ) the gross return to the bond owners. Let denote therateofreturnonequityand the rate of return on bonds. Thus, To find and we have (1 + ) = (1+ ) (1 + ) (1 ) = (1+ ) (1 ) 1+ = (1+ ) 1+ 1+ = (1+ ) 1 1+ 1 We may define the equity premium, by 1+ (1 + ) (1 + ) Then = (1 ) (1 ) 1 0 Of course these formulas have their limitations. The key variables and will depend on a lot of economic circumstances and should be endogenous in an elaborate model. Yet, the formulas may be helpful as a way of organizing one s thoughts about rates of return in a world with asymmetric information and risk of bankruptcy. There is evidence that in the last decades of the twentieth century the equity premium had become lower than in the long aftermath of the Great Depression in the 1930s. 4 A likely explanation is that had gone up along with rising confidence; the computer and theworldwidewebhavemadeitmucheasierforindividualstoinvestsinstocksofshares. On the other hand, the recent global financial and economic crisis, the Great Recession 2007-, and the associated rise in mistrust may have halted and possibly reversed this tendency for some time. 4 Blanchard (2003, p. 333). 8