MACROPRUDENTIAL MEASURES FOR ADDRESSING HOUSING SECTOR RISKS. Dong He, Erlend Nier, and Heedon Kang 1 International Monetary Fund

Similar documents
Reporting practices for domestic and total debt securities

STOXX EMERGING MARKETS INDICES. UNDERSTANDA RULES-BA EMERGING MARK TRANSPARENT SIMPLE

Financial wealth of private households worldwide

Guide to Treatment of Withholding Tax Rates. January 2018

Developing Housing Finance Systems

Fiscal Policy and the Global Crisis

Getting ready to prevent and tame another house price bubble

Open Day 2017 Clearstream execution-to-custody integration Valentin Nehls / Jan Willems. 5 October 2017

EQUITY REPORTING & WITHHOLDING. Updated May 2016

The construction of long time series on credit to the private and public sector

Planning Global Compensation Budgets for 2018 November 2017 Update

TAXATION OF TRUSTS IN ISRAEL. An Opportunity For Foreign Residents. Dr. Avi Nov

Summary of key findings

Summary 715 SUMMARY. Minimum Legal Fee Schedule. Loser Pays Statute. Prohibition Against Legal Advertising / Soliciting of Pro bono

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

FOREIGN ACTIVITY REPORT

Switzerland Country Profile

Global Business Barometer April 2008

Public Pension Spending Trends and Outlook in Emerging Europe. Benedict Clements Fiscal Affairs Department International Monetary Fund March 2013

Switzerland Country Profile

Corrigendum. OECD Pensions Outlook 2012 DOI: ISBN (print) ISBN (PDF) OECD 2012

Sovereign Risks and Financial Spillovers

KPMG s Individual Income Tax and Social Security Rate Survey 2009 TAX

Global Tax Reset Transfer Pricing Documentation Summary. February 2018

DOMESTIC CUSTODY & TRADING SERVICES

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Approach to Employment Injury (EI) compensation benefits in the EU and OECD

Regulatory Arbitrage in Action: Evidence from Banking Flows and Macroprudential Policy

REFORMING PENSION SYSTEMS: THE OECD EXPERIENCE

TAXATION (IMPLEMENTATION) (CONVENTION ON MUTUAL ADMINISTRATIVE ASSISTANCE IN TAX MATTERS) (AMENDMENT OF REGULATIONS No. 3) (JERSEY) ORDER 2017

Double Tax Treaties. Necessity of Declaration on Tax Beneficial Ownership In case of capital gains tax. DTA Country Withholding Tax Rates (%)

Actuarial Supply & Demand. By i.e. muhanna. i.e. muhanna Page 1 of

Other Tax Rates. Non-Resident Withholding Tax Rates for Treaty Countries 1

Non-resident withholding tax rates for treaty countries 1

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Slovenia Country Profile

PENTA CLO 2 B.V. (the "Issuer")

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Financial law reform: purpose and key questions

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

BETTER POLICIES FOR A SUCCESSFUL TRANSITION TO A LOW-CARBON ECONOMY

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

TAXING RESIDENTIAL HOUSING

Households Indebtedness and Financial Fragility

Enterprise Europe Network SME growth outlook

APA & MAP COUNTRY GUIDE 2017 DENMARK

Instruction Deadline. *Settlement Cycle

Sweden Country Profile

Finland Country Profile

Total Imports by Volume (Gallons per Country)

Capital Flows, Cross-Border Banking and Global Liquidity. May 2012

Operationalizing the Selection and Application of Macroprudential Instruments

Double tax considerations on certain personal retirement scheme benefits

NPL resolution in the case of Romania

The Challenge of Public Pension Reform in Advanced and Emerging Economies

San Francisco Retiree Health Care Trust Fund Education Materials on Public Equity

The Global Tax Reset 2017 Audit Committee Symposium

Capital Markets Day 2011

Overview of FSC-certified forests January January Maps of extend of FSC-certified forest globally and country specific

APA & MAP COUNTRY GUIDE 2017 CANADA

Does One Law Fit All? Cross-Country Evidence on Okun s Law

Global Consumer Confidence

When will CbC reports need to be filled?

Definition of international double taxation

World Consumer Income and Expenditure Patterns

Spain France. England Netherlands. Wales Ukraine. Republic of Ireland Czech Republic. Romania Albania. Serbia Israel. FYR Macedonia Latvia

Argentina Bahamas Barbados Bermuda Bolivia Brazil British Virgin Islands Canada Cayman Islands Chile

DANMARKS NATIONALBANK

FY2016 RESULTS. 1 February 2016 to 31 January Inditex continues to roll out its global, fully integrated store and online model.

Setting up in Denmark

Portugal Country Profile

Global Trends in Housing Finance

Table of Contents. 1 created by

Growth has peaked amidst escalating risks

Clinical Trials Insurance

a closer look GLOBAL TAX WEEKLY ISSUE 249 AUGUST 17, 2017

DIVERSIFICATION. Diversification

1.1. STOXX TOTAL MARKET INDICES

AUTOMATIC EXCHANGE OF INFORMATION (AEOI)

Monetary and macroprudential policies exploring interactions 1

Invesco Indexing Investable Universe Methodology October 2017

Dutch tax treaty overview Q3, 2012

ISSUE OF ENDORSEMENTS ATTESTING TO THE RECOGNITION OF A CERTIFICATE OF COMPETENCY

Health Referral Benefit Programme

Circular to SFC s Registered Intermediaries. Financial Action Task Force on Money Laundering Non-cooperative Countries and Territories

Household Debt and Business Cycles Worldwide Out-of-sample results based on IMF s new Global Debt Database

COUNTRY COST INDEX JUNE 2013

Lithuania Country Profile

Auscap Long Short Australian Equities Fund Newsletter June 2018

IMPORTANT TAX INFORMATION

15 Popular Q&A regarding Transfer Pricing Documentation (TPD) In brief. WTS strong presence in about 100 countries

Global Economic Briefing: Global Inflation

Stress Testing: Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP) Experience

Luxembourg Country Profile

Transcription:

MACROPRUDENTIAL MEASURES FOR ADDRESSING HOUSING SECTOR RISKS Dong He, Erlend Nier, and Heedon Kang 1 International Monetary Fund Next Steps in Macroprudential Policies conference Thursday, November 12, 215 Columbia University 1 This note summarizes the presentation of the same title given by Dong He in the conference Next Steps in Macroprudential Policies, organized by IESE and Columbia SIPA in November 12, 215. The views expressed here are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the IMF or IMF policy.

The targeted use of sectoral macroprudential tools can help address the build-up of systemic risk due to excess credit to the housing sector (IMF, 214a and 214b). These tools include sectoral capital requirements (risk weights or loss given default (LGD) floors), limits on loan-to-value (LTV) ratios, and caps on debt-service-to-income (DSTI) or loan-to-income (LTI) ratios. Evidence shows that these tools can be effective in increasing the resilience of borrowers and the financial system to house price or income shocks. They also help contain the procyclical feedback between credit and house prices that can lead a housing boom to end in a costly bust (see Figure 1, and SDN/15/12). The main benefit of a higher risk weight is that it increases the resilience of lenders, while an important benefit of LTV and DSTI caps is to increase resilience of borrowers to asset price or income shocks (SDN/11/2). In particular, by enforcing a minimum down payment, LTV limits reduce borrowers incentive for strategic default and lenders LGD in a bust scenario. Figure 1. Transmission Mechanism of Sectoral Macroprudential Instruments Risk Assessment Actions Transmission channels Intended outcomes Credit supply channel Tighten sectoral capital requirements Banks raise more capital Funding/lending rate Unsustainable increase of core indicators (feedback loops) Household loans Unsecured loans Mortgage loans House prices Price- to- rent Price- to- income Sectoral risk weights LGD floors Capital buffers Tighten limits on LTV ratios Maximum LTV ratios Resilience channel Capital against unexpected losses Probability of default Loss given default Anti- default channel Minimum down payment Default incentives Stabilization of core indicators Household loan growth Share of systemically risky type of loans House prices Price- to- Rent and Price- to- Income ratio goes back to its trend Tighten limits on DSTI ratios Maximum DSTI ratios Expectation channel Anticipating decrease of capital gains or profits Lenders deleveraging Borrowers speculative incentives Credit Demand channel (automatic stabilizer) Borrowing constraints bind Loan availability Source: IMF Staff. All these tools may also dampen mortgage credit growth, even if the effects on house prices are smaller. DSTI or LTI caps can be especially effective as automatic stabilizers becoming more binding when house prices grow faster than disposable income, thereby helping smooth the credit boom and limit the procyclical feedback between credit and house prices. All tools can also reduce speculative demand by containing expectations of future house price increases. A wide range of indicators should be used to assess the need for policy action, especially the growth of mortgage loans and house prices. These are core indicators of housing market vulnerability, since they jointly provide powerful signals of a procyclical build-up of systemic risk (Figure 2). Deviations of house prices from long-term trends can predict financial stress, especially when combined with credit growth (Borio and Drehmann, 29, IMF, 211a ), while house price-to-rent and house price-to-income ratio can indicate over-

or under-valuation of house prices. In addition, other indicators should be closely monitored, such as (i) the average and the distribution of LTV, DSTI, and LTI ratios across new loans over a period, and outstanding loans at a given point in time; (ii) the share of foreign currency denominated mortgage loans or interest-only mortgage loans; and (iii) housing price growth by regions and types of properties. Figure 2. Mortgage Loans and House Prices around the Global Financial Crisis Mortgage loan growth (In percent, Y-o-Y) House price growth (In percent, Y-o-Y) 5 25 4 3 75 percentile 2 15 75 percentile 2 Median 1 5 Median 1 25 percentile - 5 25 percentile - 1-1 - 2 24Q1 25Q1 26Q1 27Q1 28Q1 29Q1 21Q1 211Q1-15 24Q1 25Q1 26Q1 27Q1 28Q1 29Q1 21Q1 211Q1 Source: IMF staff calculation. Note: The sample includes 18 countries that have been in a systemic banking crisis (Laeven and Valencia, 212) and had at least two consecutive quarters of negative nominal house price growth during 27 11, such as Belgium, Denmark, France, Greece, Hungary, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Latvia, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Russia, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, Ukraine, the U.K., and the U.S. Sectoral tools should be activated or tightened when multiple indicators consistently point to rising systemic risk. A single signal, or mixed signals from multiple indicators, may not be sufficient for action. For example, strong growth in mortgage loans without house price growth may simply indicate improving housing penetration rather than an increase in risk. Conversely, a sharp increase in house prices, without strong mortgage loan growth, may reflect a shortage of housing supply requiring structural policies to improve supply rather than a macroprudential response. Policymakers should take a gradual approach when introducing or tightening sectoral tools. When several indicators show signs of a gradual build-up of risk in the housing sector, policymakers should first intensify supervisory scrutiny and step up communication. As a next step, sectoral capital requirements should be tightened to build additional buffers. Tighter limits on LTV and/or DSTI ratios can follow if these former defenses are not expected to fully meet policy objectives (See Figure 3 and Table 1 for country examples). LTV and DSTI caps should always be imposed on the flow of new household loans. Otherwise, it could precipitate distress by forcing existing high LTV or DSTI borrowers to provide more collateral or repay part of their loans. Figure 3. Limits on LTV and DSTI Ratios and Number of Countries at Each Range Limits on LTV ratios (In percent) Caps on DSTI ratios (Number of countries)

12 9 1 8 8 6 4 2 Brazil Bulgaria Canada Chile China Colombia Estonia Finland Hong Kong SAR Hungary India Indonesia Ireland Israel Korea Latvia Lebanon Lithuania Malaysia Netherlands New Zealand Norway Poland Romania Singapore Sweden Thailand Turkey 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 3-4 % 4-45 % 45-5 % Source: IMF staff calculation. Note: Observed limits on LTV ratios are below 8 percent in more than half of 28 sample countries, and most countries with DSTI ratios have imposed 4 45 percent as the limit (eight out of 15 countries), and four countries restrict it to be below 35 percent. Table 1. Use of Sectoral Macroprudential Tools Advanced Economies Emerging Market Economies Total Sectoral Capital Requireme nts Australia (24), Hong Kong SAR (213), Ireland (21), Israel (21), Korea (22), Norway (1998), Spain (28), Switzerland (213) Argentina (24), Brazil (21), Bulgaria (24), Croatia (26), Estonia (26), India (24), Malaysia (25), Nigeria (213), Peru (212), Poland (27), Russia (211), Serbia (26), Thailand (29), Turkey (28), Uruguay (26) 23 Limits on LTV ratio Canada (27), Estonia (215), Finland (21), Hong Kong SAR (1991), Ireland (215), Israel (212), Korea (22), Latvia (27), Lithuania (211), Netherlands (211), New Zealand (213), Norway (21), Singapore (21), Sweden (21) Brazil (213), Bulgaria (24), Chile (29), China (21), Colombia (1999), Hungary (21), India (21), Indonesia (212), Lebanon (28), Malaysia (21), Poland (213), Romania (24), Thailand (23), Turkey (211) 28 Caps on DSTI ratio (including LTI caps) Canada (28), Estonia (214), Hong Kong SAR (1997), Korea (25), Ireland (215, LTI), Lithuania (211), Netherlands (27), Norway (21, LTI), Singapore (213), United Kingdom (214, LTI) China (24), Colombia (1999), Hungary (21), Latvia (27), Malaysia (211), Poland (21), Romania (24), Thailand (24) 18 Source: IMF staff calculation.

Note: Parentheses show the year a jurisdiction introduced currently imposed measures; changes tracked since 199. Combining sectoral tools can reinforce their effectiveness and mitigate the shortcomings of any single tool. For example, LTV limits which cap the size of a mortgage loan relative to the appraised value of a house may become less effective when house prices increase, but DSTI caps which restrict the size of debt service payments to a fixed share of household incomes continue to tie credit to household income. DSTI and LTI caps can also enhance the effectiveness of LTV limits by containing the use of unsecured loans to meet the minimum down payment. In a low interest rate environment, stressed DSTI caps (i.e., where DSTI under a specified stress scenario is capped) can complement LTV limits and mitigate defaults when interest rates eventually rise. During housing busts, sectoral tools can be relaxed to contain feedback loops between falls in credit and house prices. A housing bust can result in a credit crunch that puts further downward pressure on house prices. Strategic default, fire sales and contraction in the supply of credit can create negative economic externalities that can be cushioned by relaxing these tools (IMF, 211b; Geanakopolos, 29; and Shleifer and Vishny, 211). Indicators that inform the tightening phase can also be used for decisions to relax. Fast-moving indicators, such as house transaction volumes and spreads on housing loans, can also guide relaxation decisions. However, a softening housing market is not sufficient alone to justify a relaxation. Evidence of systemic stress is required, such as a simultaneous decline in prices and credit, or an increase in nonperforming loans or defaults. The relaxation would then be targeted to reduce stress in the housing market. Any relaxation needs to respect certain prudential minima to ensure an appropriate degree of resilience against future shocks. If large additional buffers have been built during the tightening phase, they can be released to avoid a credit crunch without jeopardizing banks resilience. However, the relaxation should not go beyond a permanent floor, i.e., a level considered safe in downturns. Policymakers should also communicate clearly that a tightening can be followed by a relaxation so that market participants do not take an adverse view of the relaxation during downturns. A relaxation of these tools can be effective, but may have limited effects when it is pushing on a string. Even if policymakers loosen sectoral instruments, banks may be reluctant to provide credit due to increased risk aversion or capital constraints, and may apply more stringent lending standards than the regulatory thresholds. Potential borrowers may be reluctant to enter the housing market while prices are still falling. Nonetheless, the relaxation would still be useful in containing the spillback from falling prices and credit where it removes a binding constraint on some agents. Policymakers should bear in mind that sectoral tools can create domestic or cross-border leakages, and unintended consequences. An increase in credit by domestic nonbanks and foreign bank branches may render the sectoral tools less effective or even ineffective if they are applied only to the domestic banking sector. Policymakers should then expand the regulatory perimeter to non-banks and foreign branches. Where there are separate regulators, inter-agency cooperation would be needed at the national or cross-border level. Extending the tools to un-regulated entities may require expanding the licensing regime to those institutions. Finally, policymakers may want to tailor limits on LTV and DSTI ratios to contain unintended distributional effects. Containing housing booms and busts may require policy levers beyond macroprudential policy tools. Where fiscal distortions, such as mortgage interest relief, contribute to systemic risks in housing markets, they should be removed (e.g., UK and Netherlands). When supply constraints drive up asset prices (e.g., Hong Kong SAR, Sweden and Australia), structural policies to boost housing supply are needed. ---- ------------ References Borio and Drehmann, 29 Borio, Claudio, and Mathias Drehmann, 29, Assessing the Risk of Banking Crises Revisited, BIS Quaterly Review, March

SDN/11/2 Crowe, Christopher, Giovanni Dell Ariccia, Deniz Igan, and Pau Rabanal, 211, Policies for Macrofinancial Stability: Options to Deal with Real Estate Booms, IMF Staff Discussion Note 11/2 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). SDN/15/12 Cerutti, Eugenio, Jihad Dagher, and Giovanni Dell Ariccia, 215, Housing Finance and Real- Estate Booms: A Cross-Country Perspective, IMF Staff Discussion Note 15/12 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Geanakopolos, 29 Geanakoplos, John, 29, The Leverage Cycle, Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper, No. 1715R, (New Haven: Yale University). Laeven and Valencia, 212 Laeven, Luc and Fabian Valencia, 212, Systemic Banking Crises Database: An Update IMF Working Paper 12/163 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). IMF, 211a, International Monetary Fund, 211a, Toward Operationalizing Macroprudential Policies: When To Act? Chapter 3 in Global Financial Stability Report (Washington, September). IMF, 211b, 211b, Housing Finance and Financial Stability Back to Basics? Chapter 3 in Global Financial Stability Report (Washington, April). IMF, 214a, Staff Guidance Note on Macroprudential Policy, (Washington: International Monetary Fund). IMF, 214b, 214, Staff Guidance Note on Macroprudential Policy Detailed Guidance on Instruments, (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Shleifer and Vishny, 211 Schleifer, Andrei and Robert Vishny, 211, Fire Sales in Finance and Macroeconomics, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 25, No. 1, pp. 29-48.