NEW BELLS & WHISTLES BUT THE SAME ENGINE Pennsylvania s Spending Limit Proposals Are Powered by the Same Formula as Colorado s Failed TABOR

Similar documents
April 26, Senate Joint Resolution 2420). 820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

FUTURE MEDICAID GROWTH IS NOT DUE TO FLAWS IN THE PROGRAM S DESIGN, BUT TO DEMOGRAPHIC TRENDS AND GENERAL INCREASES IN HEALTH CARE COSTS

April 20, and More After That, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, March 27, First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC 20002

PROPERTY TAXES IN PERSPECTIVE. By David H. Bradley

Census Data Show Robust Progress Across the Board in 2016 in Income, Poverty, and Health Coverage

July 23, First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

NON-DEFENSE DISCRETIONARY PROGRAMS WILL FACE SERIOUS PRESSURES UNDER CURRENT FUNDING CAPS

The key differences between the Cooper-LaTourette plan and the Simpson-Bowles commission plan are:

IS MISSOURI S MEDICAID PROGRAM OUT-OF-STEP AND INEFFICIENT? by Leighton Ku and Judith Solomon

RHODE ISLAND S MEDICAID PROPOSAL WOULD PUT BENEFICIARIES AT RISK AND UNDERMINE THE FEDERAL-STATE PARTNERSHIP

Controlling State Spending: A Responsible Alternative to TABOR

Medicare in Ryan s 2014 Budget By Paul N. Van de Water

Notes Unless otherwise indicated, the years referred to in describing budget numbers are fiscal years, which run from October 1 to September 30 and ar

THE CURRENT SERVICES BASELINE: A Tool for Making Sensible Budget Choices By Elizabeth McNichol and Ifie Okwuje

CORRECTING FIVE MYTHS ABOUT THE STIMULUS BILL By James R. Horney, Nicholas Johnson, and Lawrence J. Haas

National Health Expenditure Projections

Cassidy-Graham Would Deeply Cut and Drastically Redistribute Health Coverage Funding Among States

And Jobs Act, November 14, 2017, %20chairman's%20modified%20mark.pdf.

A $7.25 MINIMUM WAGE WOULD BE A USEFUL STEP IN HELPING WORKING FAMILIES ESCAPE POVERTY by Jason Furman and Sharon Parrott

Colorado Legislative Council Staff

HEALTH OPPORTUNITY ACCOUNTS FOR LOW-INCOME MEDICAID BENEFICIARIES: A Risky Approach By Edwin Park and Judith Solomon

Prospects for the Social Safety Net for Future Low Income Seniors

Policy makers and the public frequently debate how fast government spending

29 STATES FACED TOTAL BUDGET SHORTFALL OF AT LEAST $48 BILLION IN 2009 By Elizabeth C. McNichol and Iris J. Lav

House Funding Bill Imposes Further Cuts to Transportation Infrastructure By David Reich

medicaid a n d t h e Aging Out of Medicaid: What Is the Risk of Becoming Uninsured?

820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

HEALTH COVERAGE AMONG YEAR-OLDS in 2003

Revised November 16, 2007

State Responses to Budget Crises in 2004: Michigan John Holahan

How The Chained Consumer Price Index Would Affect Social Security Benefits

BUDGET MONITOR. The Governor s FY 2005 Veto Message. July 2, Overview

THE PRESIDENT S BUDGET: A PRELIMINARY ANALYSIS

Chart Book: Deficit Reduction, the Economy, And the Budget Negotiations By Sharon Parrott, Richard Kogan, Krista Ruffini, and William Chen

Low-Income Programs Are Not Driving The Nation s Long-Term Fiscal Problem

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

H.R Better Care Reconciliation Act of 2017

Student Debt and Consumer Costs

Chart Book: TANF at 20

Medicaid and Entitlement Reform By John Holahan

kaiser medicaid uninsured commission on State Case Study: Medicaid and the Budget Crisis A Look At How Washington Responded

Chart Book: The Far-Reaching Benefits of the Affordable Care Act s Medicaid Expansion

THE HOUSE FY 2014 BUDGET

Changing Policy. Improving Lives.

GOVERNORS NEW BUDGETS INDICATE LOSS OF MANY JOBS IF FEDERAL AID EXPIRES By Nicholas Johnson, Erica Williams, and Phil Oliff

AMENDMENT 23 ECONOMIC MODELING FOR DECISION MAKERS FEBRUARY 2001

820 First Street, NE, Suite 510, Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

May 14, Figure 1 Half of Lower Medicare Drug Spending Due to Lower Than Projected Enrollment

July 17, Summary

Health Economics Program

CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES CONGRESSIONAL BUDGET OFFICE CBO. The Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2013 to 2023

WHAT WOULD IT SAY ABOUT CONGRESS S PRIORITIES TO WAIVE PAYGO FOR THE AMT PATCH? By Aviva Aron-Dine

STATE BUDGET TROUBLES WORSEN By Elizabeth McNichol and Iris J. Lav

CBPP S UPDATED LONG-TERM FISCAL DEFICIT AND DEBT PROJECTIONS

Health Insurance Data

NEW ESTATE TAX RULES SHOULD EXPIRE AFTER 2012 Shrinking the Tax Beyond the 2009 Level Is Unaffordable and Unnecessary By Gillian Brunet

Sources of Health Insurance Coverage in Georgia

Colorado Legislative Council Staff

PRINCIPLES FOR ECONOMIC STIMULUS. By Andrew Lee

75-YEAR PAY-AS-YOU-GO PROPOSAL COULD ADVERSELY AFFECT SOCIAL SECURITY, MEDICARE, SSI, VETERANS DISABILITY, AND OTHER PROGRAMS

Our current fiscal challenge

NORTH DAKOTA'S MEASURE 2 IS IMBALANCED AND WOULD HARM EFFORTS TO SECURE STATE'S ECONOMIC FUTURE By Nicholas Johnson and Elizabeth Hudgins

STATE INCOME TAX BURDENS ON LOW-INCOME FAMILIES IN By Bob Zahradnik and Joseph Llobrera 1

TAX AND EXPENDITURE LIMITATION PROPOSALS IN ARIZONA

Testimony of. Judith Feder, PhD. Before the. Committee on Oversight and Government Reform. U.S. House of Representatives.

Funding Bill and Carryover Funding Should Enable Agencies to Issue More Housing Vouchers in 2019

Tax Cuts and the Recession in the Massachusetts Fiscal Crisis. Elissa Braunstein 1 October Research Brief

TAXES ON MIDDLE-INCOME FAMILIES ARE DECLINING. by Iris J. Lav

kaiser medicaid uninsured commission on State Responses to Budget Crisis in 2004: An Overview of Ten States Case Study - Michigan

September 2013

Notes Numbers in the text and tables may not add up to totals because of rounding. Unless otherwise indicated, years referred to in describing the bud

Washington State s 1930s Tax System Doesn t Work In A 21st Century Economy

Proposed Changes to Medicare in the Path to Prosperity Overview and Key Questions

HUD DATA SHOW HOUSING VOUCHER COSTS LEVELED OFF STARTING IN 2003 AS RENTAL MARKET COOLED by Will Fischer and Barbara Sard Summary

Federal Employees: Pay and Pension Increases Since 1969

tel / fax

What s in the FY 2011 Budget for Health Care?

Economic Security Programs Cut Poverty Nearly in Half Over Last 50 Years, New Data Show

Federal Employees: Pay and Pension Increases Since 1969

Most Workers in Low-Wage Labor Market Work Substantial Hours, in Volatile Jobs

Summary of Healthy Indiana Plan: Key Facts and Issues

Attachment 1 ASSUMPTIONS FOR A MULTI-YEAR BUDGET MODEL

July 31, First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC Tel: Fax:

AUGUST 2012 An Update to the Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2012 to 2022 Provided as a convenience, this screen-friendly version is identic

HUSKY: Importance to the State

THE SLOWDOWN IN MEDICAID EXPENDITURE GROWTH By Leighton Ku

Poverty in Our Time. The Challenges and Opportunities of Fighting Poverty in Virginia. Executive Summary. By Michael Cassidy and Sara Okos

Revised November 21, 2008

Senate Tax Bill Has Same Basic Flaws as House Bill

December 21, Executive Summary

PROPERTY VALUES AND TAXES IN SOUTHEAST WISCONSIN

WHAT YOU NEED TO KNOW ABOUT PREMIUM SUPPORT By Paul N. Van de Water

Trump Budget Gets Two-Thirds of Its Cuts From Programs for Low- and Moderate-Income People

SMALLER DEFICIT ESTIMATE NO SURPRISE New OMB Estimates Do Not Support Claims About Tax Cuts By James Horney

The 2008 Statistics on Income, Poverty, and Health Insurance Coverage by Gary Burtless THE BROOKINGS INSTITUTION

Revised July 25, 2012

Government spending and taxes are the subjects of considerable discussion

2008 Pennsylvania, PA House District 193

2015 Income Tax Trigger

A Long Road Back to Work. The Realities of Unemployment since the Great Recession

Transcription:

820 First Street NE, Suite 510 Washington, DC 20002 Tel: 202-408-1080 Fax: 202-408-1056 center@cbpp.org www.cbpp.org December 6, 2005 NEW BELLS & WHISTLES BUT THE SAME ENGINE Pennsylvania s Spending Limit Proposals Are Powered by the Same Formula as Colorado s Failed TABOR By David Bradley Four new proposals in Pennsylvania Senate Bills 4 and 884 and House Bills 2067 and 2082 would impose tight limits on state expenditures that would shrink available public services such as education and health care in the same way that Colorado s TABOR has led to a deterioration in that state. Colorado has the strictest tax and expenditure limit (TEL) in the country; under TABOR, the annual growth in Colorado s state budget is limited to the rate of growth of state population plus an inflation factor. During the twelve years since TABOR was enacted in that state, there have been substantial reductions in basic public services such as health care, roads, K-12 education and higher education. The problems caused by TABOR led Coloradoans to approve in November 2005 a statewide measure to suspend TABOR s population-growth-plus-inflation formula for five years in order to allow the state to restore a portion of its fundamental public services. The same inflation plus population growth formula that has caused such problems in Colorado is used in the new Pennsylvania proposals. 1 If the proposals are adopted, they will over time result in a sharp deterioration in public services in Pennsylvania. As in Colorado, Pennsylvania families may find themselves paying for educational activities, supplies, and even teachers the Commonwealth can no longer afford under the limit, more Pennsylvanians are likely to become uninsured, the likelihood of public health emergencies will increase, and companies will find Pennsylvania a less hospitable place to do business as infrastructure and education deteriorates. The population-plus-inflation formula is a problem because the cost of many public services, like health care and education, rises faster than inflation, and because populations in need of state services, such as the elderly, are growing faster than the population as a whole. These rising costs normally are manageable because the state s economy is also growing. Indeed, relative to the economy, Pennsylvania state spending has not grown in more than two decades. State General Fund spending was 5.4 percent of personal income in 1986, 5.4 percent of personal income in 2005, and averaged 5.4 percent over the 20-year period. But the normal growth in the cost of services is not manageable under TABOR, because TABOR would require service provision to shrink as a share of the economy each year. 1 The growth formula in House Bill 2067 is more restrictive than the three other proposals. Its formula allows only for an inflation adjustment, rather than a population-plus-inflation adjustment.

Proponents of TABOR in Pennsylvania, such as The Commonwealth Foundation and sponsors of the spending limit legislation, contend that their proposals will avoid the problems that TABOR has brought to Colorado. As Pennsylvania House Republican Majority Caucus spokesman Steve Miskin claimed, We tried to correct what we saw as flaws in Colorado s approach. 2 Yet, the additions and tweaks made by the sponsors of Pennsylvania s legislation are cosmetic and would not change the outcome. The proposed rainy day fund is likely to be insufficient and may not be accessible when needed. Applying the proposal to expenditures rather than revenues has no advantage in a state with a balanced budget requirement. Under a revenue limit, revenues above the limit cannot be spent and thus constitute a limit on expenditures. An expenditure limit directly limits spending; any additional revenues a state collects cannot be spent. The effect is the same. Choosing an inflation measure different from Colorado s does not make the limit less restrictive. In 11 of the last 13 years, the proposed Pennsylvania measure would have yielded a tighter limit than Colorado s measure. Applying the limit only to the General Fund is similarly not significantly less restrictive than Colorado. In Pennsylvania, the proposed limit would cover 67 percent of all non-federal state expenditures. Colorado s TABOR covers 73 percent of all non-federal state expenditures. None of these changes fix the fundamental flaw inherent in the population-plus inflation formula. The Population-Growth-Plus-Inflation Formula Is a Faulty Engine Limiting state budget growth to population change plus inflation shrinks public services over time and severely limits the state s ability to respond to residents needs. Both elements of the formula hinder a state s ability to provide a constant level of public services and prevent the state from meeting current and emerging needs. Inflation Inflation as commonly measured does not accurately reflect growth in the costs to government. The measure of inflation in all four Pennsylvania proposals is the nationwide Consumer Price Index-All Urban Consumers (CPI-U), which is calculated by the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. The CPI-U measures change in the total cost of a market basket of goods and services purchased by a typical urban consumer. Since a typical urban consumer spends a majority of his or her income on housing, transportation, and food and beverages, those items are the primary drivers of the CPI- U. By contrast, Pennsylvania state government spends revenue primarily on education, health care, transportation, and corrections. In short, the market baskets of spending are entirely different. 2 Bureau of National Affairs, Daily Tax Report, November 18, 2005, No. 222, page H-1. 2

The problems with the population-plus-inflation growth formula are described in more detail in a Center on Budget and Policy Priorities paper entitled The Flawed Population Plus Inflation Formula: Why TABOR s Growth Formula Doesn t Work. Available at http://www.cbpp.org/1-13-05sfp3.htm Pennsylvania s basket of public services (and every other state s) is in economic sectors that are less likely to reap efficiency and productivity gains than other sectors of the economy, so it typically faces faster-rising costs than the urban consumers represented by the CPI-U. For example, teachers can only teach so many students, and nurses can only care for so many patients. There is little way to increase those ratios without a significant deterioration in the quality of the services. As it turns out, the items in the basket of goods most heavily purchased by governments such as health care, education, and prescription drugs have seen significantly greater cost increases in the past decade than the items in the basket of goods that consumers purchase, and those faster-growing costs are expected to continue. Limiting the growth in government spending to the rate of growth in general inflation will not push down the rate of growth in the cost of medical care or education. Many factors beyond the control of any one state are causing the growth in costs. Population The second part of the population-growth-plus-inflation formula is inherently flawed as well. The subpopulations that state governments serve tend to grow more rapidly than the overall population growth used in the formula. An example is senior citizens, who already account for a disproportionately large share of Pennsylvania s Medicaid costs. According to U.S. Census Bureau projections, Pennsylvania s total population is projected to increase by only 4 percent from 2000 to 2030, but Pennsylvania s population aged 65 and older is projected to increase by 51 percent from 2000 to 2030. 3 While total population growth, and thus allowable state spending under a population-plus-inflation formula, is projected to grow slowly in Pennsylvania in the coming decades due to a small increase in overall population, the cost of providing current health services to Pennsylvania residents likely will rise rapidly because of an aging population. Changing Priorities and Shifting Costs There is a further problem with the population-plus-inflation formula. Even if existing services could be financed under the formula, the formula would be insufficient to allow funding of new priorities that may be embraced by the public, such as reduced class sizes or more stringent corrections policies. It would not allow states to adapt to federal mandates that require states to spend more in areas such as security and education, and it would not provide for sufficient emergency spending on natural disasters or other unanticipated problems. 4 3 U.S. Census Bureau, State Interim Population Projections by Age and Sex: 2004-2030, Table 4. Available at http://www.census.gov/population/projections/presstab4.xls 4 One of the four Pennsylvania proposals House Bill 2067 specifically excludes from the limit appropriations required by federal law, court orders, pension obligations, and all debt. The three other Pennsylvania proposals do not identify any such exceptions. 3

It is also important to note that all programs in the Pennsylvania general fund not just those with cost pressures exceeding the population-growth-plus-inflation level are threatened by a rigid population-growth-plus-inflation limit. This is because under all four proposals under consideration, a single cap would apply to the General Fund as a whole. So, if one spending area were to grow faster than the rate allowed under the limit (for instance due to court order, federal mandate or popular demand), then another spending area must grow at a slower pace which is to say that in terms of the level of service provided, that second spending area must actually shrink. If state General Fund expenditures were constrained by the tight population-plus-inflation limit, costs might be shifted elsewhere. For example, state policymakers might decide to reduce state aid to local governments and school districts requiring localities to pick up a greater share of the cost of education and local services. Local governments, in turn, would have to cut services or raise taxes to cover the state s actions. The Reality of Spending in Pennsylvania Advocates of TABOR in Pennsylvania claim that the state needs a strict spending limit because there is runaway growth of government spending and the state is not living within our means. 5 These are false claims. Pennsylvania state spending is not out of control. Pennsylvania state government spending has changed little as a share of the economy since at least the 1980s. State General Fund spending was 5.4 percent of personal income in 1986, 5.4 percent of personal income in 2005, and averaged 5.4 percent over the 20-year period. 6 In other words, relative to the ability of the state s citizens to pay for government services, Pennsylvania s spending has not grown in the past two decades (See Figure 1). TABOR would reduce spending relative to the state s means rather than keep it stable. It would require services to be sharply reduced. If state spending had been limited to changes in population plus inflation from 1986 to 2005, spending would have declined from 5.4 percent of personal income to 4.1 percent of personal income. 7 (see Figure 1) The drop would have required General Fund expenditure in 2005 to have been $5.5 billion, or 24 percent, less than actual spending in 2005. Rather than forcing the state to live within its means, TABOR would have forced Pennsylvania to devote fewer and fewer of its resources to public services and to cut deeply into education, health care, public safety and other services on which Pennsylvania residents depend. 5 For example, Steve Miskin, spokesman for the Pennsylvania House Republican Majority Caucus noted, It [TABOR] just means living within our means. quoted in PA Bills Would Cap Budget Increases, Philadelphia Inquirer, November 19, 2005. Quotation on runaway spending is from Dr. Jim Broussard, Citizens Against Higher Taxes, cited in Here s What Supporters Say About the Taxpayer Fairness Act, available at http://www.pasenategop.com/news/tfacharts/tfaquotes.pdf 6 Using personal income as a base for measuring state spending is the best indicator of a state s means. Personal income measures the ability of the state, on average, to pay for government services. 7 Spending data for Figure 1 are from the Commonwealth of Pennsylvania Executive Budget documents, various years. To calculate state spending under a population-plus-inflation TABOR, the previous year s allowable spending limit was multiplied by the sum of the percent growth in population plus inflation. 4

The Derailing of Colorado A growing body of evidence shows that Colorado s Taxpayer Bill of Rights, or TABOR, has contributed to a significant decline in that state s public services. Colorado voters recently chose to suspend TABOR for five years, in part to restore some of the service cuts induced by TABOR. These developments in Colorado have serious implications for the residents of Pennsylvania, because the proposed spending caps would likely lead to similar outcomes. The strict TABOR limits in Colorado have contributed to deterioration in the availability and quality of nearly all major government services. Since its enactment in 1992, TABOR contributed to declines in Colorado K-12 education funding. Under TABOR, Colorado declined from 35 th to 49 th in the nation in K-12 spending as a percentage of personal income. Colorado s average per-pupil funding fell by more than $400 relative to the national average. And Colorado s average teacher salary compared to average pay in other occupations declined from 30 th to 50 th in the nation. TABOR has played a major role in the significant cuts made in higher education funding. Under TABOR, higher education funding per resident student dropped by 31 percent after adjusting for inflation. College and university funding as a share of personal income declined from 35 th to 48 th in the nation. As a result, tuitions have risen. In the last four years, system-wide resident tuition increased by 21 percent after adjustment for inflation. TABOR has led to drops in funding for public health programs. Under TABOR, Colorado declined from 23 rd to 48 th in the nation in the percentage of pregnant women receiving adequate access to prenatal care, as defined by the federal Centers for Disease Control and Prevention. Colorado plummeted from 24 th to 50 th in the nation in the share of children receiving their full vaccinations. Only by investing additional funds in immunization programs was Colorado able to improve its ranking to 43 rd in 2004. At one point, from April 2001 to October 2002, funding was so low that the state suspended its requirement that school children be fully vaccinated against diphtheria, tetanus, and pertussis (whooping cough) because Colorado, unlike other states, could not afford to buy the vaccine. TABOR has hindered Colorado s ability to address the lack of medical insurance coverage for many children and adults in the state. Under TABOR, the share of lowincome children lacking health insurance has doubled in Colorado, even as it has fallen in the nation as a whole. Colorado now ranks last among the 50 states on this measure. TABOR has also affected healthcare for adults. Colorado has fallen from 20 th to 48 th for the percentage of low-income non-elderly adults covered under health insurance. In 2002, Colorado ranked 49 th in the nation in both the percentage of low-income non-elderly adults and low-income children covered by Medicaid. Source: David Bradley and Karen Lyons, A Formula for Decline: Lessons from Colorado for States Considering TABOR, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, October 2005. Available at: http://www.cbpp.org/10-19-05sfp.htm 5

FIGURE 1 How Would TABOR Erode Government in Pennsylvania? 6.0% General Fund Appropriations as % of PA Personal Income 5.5% 5.0% 4.5% 4.0% 3.5% 3.0% 2.5% Actual GF Appropriations GF Appropriations with TABOR 2.0% 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Fiscal Year Source: CBPP analysis of Pennsylvania Legislative Budget and Finance, 2002 Statistical Digest data. Bells and Whistles Do Not Change the Engine of TABOR As part of their campaign to distance the Pennsylvania proposals from Colorado s TABOR, proponents of TABOR in Pennsylvania have made changes to (in Miskin s words) correct the flaws of Colorado s TABOR. These changes include using the TABOR mechanism to finance a rainy day fund, imposing the limit on expenditures rather than revenues, using a different measure of inflation, and applying the TABOR formula to General Fund appropriations rather than all appropriations. Nevertheless, the core feature of Colorado s TABOR the population-plus-inflation limit is not altered in the Pennsylvania bills. For example, House Bill 2082 sets the appropriations limit as the previous year s level of appropriations, adjusted by the lesser of the average percentage change in personal income in Pennsylvania or the average percentage change in inflation plus the average percentage change in state population. 8 Similar language is featured in all four Pennsylvania proposals. That language is simply intended to obfuscate the fact that the inflation plus population change formula will be the operative one under most circumstances. For example, in the past 20 years, there has been only one three-year period 1991 to 1993 in which average personal income growth was slightly lower than population-plus-inflation. 8 The average in the formula refers to a three-year average. This does not affect the restrictiveness of the formula itself, but just smooths its effects out over time. 6

Pennsylvania TABOR supporters claim that the Pennsylvania proposals offer more leeway than Colorado s TABOR because they require a portion of state revenue to go to a rainy day fund. 9 But the rainy day fund created by any of the four Pennsylvania proposals would make little difference. The new rainy day fund is capped at 7.5 percent of the general fund appropriations. The current rainy day fund has rarely if ever exceeded 6 percent of appropriations. The new rainy day fund would effectively replace rather than augment the existing fund. The very small increase in the rainy day fund from 6 percent to 7.5 percent of appropriations is unlikely to be much help during a downturn, particularly a downturn of more than one year. For example, in the most recent downturn, the average state entered the most recent downturn with reserves equivalent to 10.4 percent of a year s expenditures, far more than was on hand in either of the previous two downturns. But those reserves filled only one-fifth of the typical state s cumulative budget gaps over the several years of the downturn. The inadequacy of Pennsylvania's proposed rainy day fund is particularly likely since in economic downturns, expenditures naturally grow as unemployment rises and the need for state services increases at a rate well above population growth plus inflation. Moreover, the proposals would require a two-thirds majority vote from the General Assembly to use money from the rainy day fund; thus the funds may or may not be accessible when needed. A second asserted difference between the Pennsylvania proposals and Colorado s TABOR is that the Pennsylvania TABOR limits state spending growth, not revenue collections. 10 But in a state with a balanced budget requirement, in which expenditures cannot exceed revenues, it makes little difference whether it is revenues or expenditures that are capped. Under a revenue limit, revenues above the limit cannot be spent and thus constitute a limit on expenditures. An expenditure limit directly limits spending; any additional revenues a state collects cannot be spent. The effect is the same. Pennsylvania has a balanced budget requirement, and so would fare the same under a revenue or expenditure limit. A third purported difference is that the inflation factor in the Pennsylvania proposals is higher, and thus more generous, than the inflation factor in Colorado s TABOR. 11 This is a misleading claim. Inflation in Colorado s TABOR is measured by the CPI for the Denver-Boulder-Greeley metropolitan area, whereas the Pennsylvania proposals are based the CPI-U for the U.S. as a whole. Due to a variety of factors, including a booming housing market in Colorado until recently, inflation in the Denver area has been higher than the inflation limit in the Pennsylvania proposals. Since Colorado s TABOR was adopted in 1992, inflation in the Denver metropolitan area has been higher than in the nation as a whole for 11 of 13 years. Only in 2003 and 2004 did the national CPI-U exceed that for the Denver metropolitan area. Contrary to the claims of Pennsylvania TABOR supporters, the proposed inflation limit would have been more, not less, restrictive than the limit used in Colorado. 9 PA Bills Would Cap Budget Increases, Philadelphia Inquirer, November 19, 2005. Also, the Commonwealth Foundation has noted the importance of a rainy day fund in correcting Colorado s problems with TABOR. The proposals vary in their requirements for rainy day fund deposits but all four require some contribution to a fund. 10 Noted by Steve Miskin, Pennsylvania House Republican Spokesman, in Peter L. DeCoursey, House GOP Disputes Comparisons of Spending-Cap Bill to Colorado Law, Capitolwire, October 31, 2005. 11 Ibid. 7

A final difference between Pennsylvania s TABOR proposals and Colorado s TABOR is that the Pennsylvania proposals apply to General Fund appropriations, whereas Colorado s TABOR applies to revenues that fund more than the General Fund. The implication of the different bases is that Pennsylvania s TABOR provides greater leeway since it purportedly covers a smaller base. The breadth of coverage, however, is not as different as it first appears. In fiscal year 2006, general fund appropriations comprise about 67 percent of all non-federal expenditure in Pennsylvania (federal funds are excluded from both the Pennsylvania proposals and Colorado s TABOR). In Colorado, TABOR covers about 73 percent of all non-federal state revenue. So, the Pennsylvania proposals are nearly as restrictive as Colorado s TABOR in their coverage of funding for public services. Conclusion The proposed spending limits in Pennsylvania are based on a formula of population change plus inflation and thus would significantly hinder the state s ability to cope with unanticipated changes, initiate policy changes, accommodate voter and court mandates, or even maintain current service levels. Despite assertions that they have fixed the flaws of Colorado s TABOR, proponents of these measures are pushing legislation that retains TABOR s central flaw its formula. New bells and whistles don t change the fact that if any of these become law in Pennsylvania the fiscal crisis experienced in Colorado is likely to be experienced in Pennsylvania as well. Policymakers would be wise to pause before replacing deliberative, legislative budget processes with an inflexible and unrealistic formula. 8