Optimal Perception of Inflation Persistence at an Inflation-Targeting Central Bank

Similar documents
The Optimal Perception of Inflation Persistence is Zero

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont)

Volume 35, Issue 4. Real-Exchange-Rate-Adjusted Inflation Targeting in an Open Economy: Some Analytical Results

Discussion of Limitations on the Effectiveness of Forward Guidance at the Zero Lower Bound

The science of monetary policy

The benefits and drawbacks of inflation targeting

DP2005/03. A happy halfway-house? Medium term inflation targeting in New Zealand. Sam Warburton and Kirdan Lees. October 2005

Output Gaps and Robust Monetary Policy Rules

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

Monetary Policy in a Small Open Economy with a Preference for Robustness

EC3115 Monetary Economics

Monetary Policy and Model Uncertainty in a Small Open Economy

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

Parameter Uncertainty and Non-Linear Monetary Policy Rules

Inflation Persistence and Relative Contracting

Interest Rate Smoothing and Calvo-Type Interest Rate Rules: A Comment on Levine, McAdam, and Pearlman (2007)

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Monetary Policy Frameworks and the Effective Lower Bound on Interest Rates

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

Speed Limit Policies: The Output Gap and Optimal Monetary Policy

1 The empirical relationship and its demise (?)

Unemployment Persistence, Inflation and Monetary Policy in A Dynamic Stochastic Model of the Phillips Curve

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination

Optimal Monetary Policy Rule under the Non-Negativity Constraint on Nominal Interest Rates

Implications of a Changing Economic Structure for the Strategy of Monetary Policy

Monetary Policy Trade-offs in the Open Economy

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Teaching Inflation Targeting: An Analysis for Intermediate Macro. Carl E. Walsh * September 2000

Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle

Monetary Policy, Financial Stability and Interest Rate Rules Giorgio Di Giorgio and Zeno Rotondi

Robust Discretionary Monetary Policy under Cost- Push Shock Uncertainty of Iran s Economy

Price level targeting versus inflation targeting in a forward looking model

Thom Thurston Queens College and The Graduate Center, CUNY

Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve

Teaching Inflation Targeting: An Analysis for Intermediate Macro. Carl E. Walsh * First draft: September 2000 This draft: July 2001

Monetary Policy and Stock Market Boom-Bust Cycles by L. Christiano, C. Ilut, R. Motto, and M. Rostagno

On the new Keynesian model

Price-level or Inflation-targeting under Model Uncertainty

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

New-Keynesian Models and Monetary Policy: A Reexamination of the Stylized Facts

Science of Monetary Policy: CGG (1999)

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014

UNIVERSITY OF TOKYO 1 st Finance Junior Workshop Program. Monetary Policy and Welfare Issues in the Economy with Shifting Trend Inflation

Comment on: The zero-interest-rate bound and the role of the exchange rate for. monetary policy in Japan. Carl E. Walsh *

Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India

Collateralized capital and News-driven cycles

Careful Price Level Targeting

Speed Limit Policies: The Output Gap and Optimal Monetary Policy

Monetary policy in real time: the role of simple rules 1

Assignment 5 The New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Is the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Flat?

Optimal Monetary Policy

Chasing the Gap: Speed Limits and Optimal Monetary Policy

Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

The Impact of Model Periodicity on Inflation Persistence in Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models

Risk shocks and monetary policy in the new normal

Can a Time-Varying Equilibrium Real Interest Rate Explain the Excess Sensitivity Puzzle?

Monetary and Fiscal Policy

CONSERVATIVE CENTRAL BANKS: HOW CONSERVATIVE SHOULD A CENTRAL BANK BE?

The introduction of the so-called targeting

MONETARY POLICY, PRICE STABILITY AND OUTPUT GAP STABILISATION

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

Do Sticky Prices Need to Be Replaced with Sticky Information?

Monetary Policy, Price Stability and Output Gap Stabilization*

Recent analyses by Clarida, Galí, and

Review of the literature on the comparison

Monetary policy, leaning and concern for financial stability

Measuring the sacrifice ratio Some international evidence

Collateralized capital and news-driven cycles. Abstract

Shocks, frictions and monetary policy Frank Smets

Oil and macroeconomic (in)stability

Monetary credibility problems. 1. In ation and discretionary monetary policy. 2. Reputational solution to credibility problems

Inflation Target Uncertainty and Monetary Policy

The Liquidity Effect in Bank-Based and Market-Based Financial Systems. Johann Scharler *) Working Paper No October 2007

Robust Monetary Policy with Competing Reference Models

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

Monetary policy regime formalization: instrumental rules

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Fiscal Activism and the Zero Nominal Interest Rate Bound

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Which Price Level to Target? Strategic Delegation in a Sticky Price and Wage Economy

Effi cient monetary policy frontier for Iceland

Reputation and Optimal Contract for Central Bankers

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

Inflation Targeting under Commitment and Discretion *

Optimal Monetary Policy Instrument in Setting Monetary Policy Reaction Function in Nigeria

Monetary policy, asset prices, and uncertainty

Concerted Efforts? Monetary Policy and Macro-Prudential Tools

A New Keynesian Phillips Curve for Japan

IMES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

UC Santa Cruz Recent Work

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

MEASURING THE OPTIMAL MACROECONOMIC UNCERTAINTY INDEX FOR TURKEY

Output gap uncertainty: Does it matter for the Taylor rule? *

Monetary Policy: Rules versus discretion..

Journal of Central Banking Theory and Practice, 2017, 1, pp Received: 6 August 2016; accepted: 10 October 2016

Transcription:

Optimal Perception of Inflation Persistence at an Inflation-Targeting Central Bank Kai Leitemo The Norwegian School of Management BI and Norges Bank March 2003 Abstract Delegating monetary policy to a Governor with a particular view of the monetary transmission mechanism may improve the discretionary policy equilibrium. This note argues that the optimal Governor should believe that inflation persistence is (much) greater than it actually is. Keywords: Monetary policy, time inconsistency, inflation persistence. JEL classification codes: E52,E61,E63. Comments from Hilde C. Bjørnland, Sheetal Chand, Dag Morten Dalen, Tron Foss, Takako Greve, Erik Grønn, Arne Jon Isachsen, Halvor Mehlum, Tommy Sveen and seminar participants at the Norwegian School of Management BI and the National Research Meeting for Economists are gratefully acknowledged. Views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of Norges Bank. Address of the author: Department of Economics, Norwegian School of Management BI, PO Box 580, 1302 Sandvika, Norway. Tel/Fax:+47 67 55 74 77/76 75. E-mail: kai.leitemo@bi.no

1. Introduction Since the seminal article of Kydland and Prescott (1977), it has been known that there is a time-inconsistency problem in monetary policymaking. If the central bank lacks commitment technology, policies are restricted to the set of sub-optimal, but time-consistent policies. Researcher s have suggested ways of reducing the policy inefficiency by appointing a Governor with some specific preferences for policy. 1 This article argues that instead of the Government choosing a Governor with appropriate preferences, it may choose a Governor with a particular view of the transmission mechanism. More spesifically, this note argues that the Governor should believe that there is more inflation persistence than there actually is. Given that the literature has found estimates of inflation persistence in the entire zero-unity interval, 2 there should in principle be several candidates to choose from. Section 2 presents the model and sets up the policy problem. Section 3 analyses what determines the optimal inflation persistence perception and Section 4 offers some concluding remarks. 2. Model and policy problem The model of the economy is given by a simple expectations-augmented Phillips curve which allows for both forward-looking and backward-looking expectations formation, π t+1 =(1 θ) E t π t+2 + θπ t + γe t x t+1 + ε t+1, (1) where π is inflation, x is the output gap, ε t is a white-noise cost-push shock, θ is the degree of inflation persistence, and E t is the conditional rational expectations operator. The central bank is assigned a quadratic, inflation-targeting 3 social loss function, L t =(π t π ) 2 + λx 2 t, (2) where π is the inflation target which is normalized to zero in the remainder of the paper and 1 λ 0 is the weight placed on output-gap stabilization. The central bank objective is to minimize the expected value of the periodic loss function, i.e., min E t0 L t, t=t 0 subject to the Governor s view of the transmission mechanism and using the output gap as the policy instrument. The Governor, by selection, believes that inflation is determined by π t+1 =(1 θ g ) E t π t+2 + θ g π t + γe t x t+1 + ε g t+1, (3) 1 See, e.g., Rogoff (1985), Walsh (1995), Svensson (1997) for proposals within the New Classical framework, and Walsh (2002), Woodford (1999) and Söderström (2001) for proposals in the New Keynesian framework. 2 See, e.g., Fuhrer (1997), Rudebusch and Svensson (1999), Rudebusch (2002), Gali and Gertler (1999) and Gali et al. (2001). 3 See, e.g.,??. 1

where θ g may be different from θ. The Lagrangean to this policy problem is given by { L = E t0 π 2 t + λx 2 ( t + µ t πt+1 (1 θ g ) π t+2 θ g π t γx t+1 ε g )} t+1. t=t 0 The first-order conditions for a discretionary equilibrium, taking private-sector expectations about future inflation as given, are L = E g [ ] t 2πt+1 µ π t θ g µ t+1 =0, t t0, t+1 L = E g t x [2λx t+1 γµ t ]=0, t t 0. t+1 By substituting out the Lagrange mulitiplier, the first-order condition is given by E g t x t+1 = θ g E g t x t+2 γ λ Eg t π t+1, (4) where Governor s expectations, denoted E g, are evaluated using equations (3) and (4). The complete model now consists of the Phillips curve (1), and the policy rule (4) evaluated using (3). Expected social loss, Ω=minE t0 L t, t=t 0 will be a function of the perceived and true model parameters and the variance of the cost-push shock, Ω = f(θ g ; θ, β, γ, σ 2 ε). The problem of the Government is to choose a Governor with optimal inflation persistence perception, that is, θ g = θ g where θ g =argminf(θ g ; θ, β, γ, σ 2 ε). The analytical solution is unfortunately intractable, and we need to resort to numerical methods in finding θ g. 4 Parameters in the benchmark case are set at γ =0.05, λ=1andσ ε =0.01. 3. Analysis Woodford (1999) showed that persistence (inertia) in policymaking is welfare improving. If a policy stance is expected to prevail, then it will have a stronger influence on future inflation expectations and reduce firms insentive to increase prices when facing a cost-push shock. If inflation is persistent, then providing a stronger link between the policy instrument and inflation will induce greater policy persistence. Hence, inflation persistence offers a channel through which output can be made more persistent. Figure 1 plots for different configurations of θ and λ, the optimally perceived inflation persistence (θ g), social loss improvement on the discretionary equilibrium, the percentage of the policy inefficiency removed 5 and the change in the variability of inflation and output relative to the discretionary equilibrium. Some interesting observations can be made. 4 We used a grid search with steps of 0.005 in finding the optimal parameter. 5 L The percentage of policy inefficiency removed is computed as dis Ω L dis L com 100, where L dis is expected loss under the discretionary equilibrium (where θ g = θ) andl com is expected loss in the timeless commitment equilibrium. 2

Figure 1: The upper diagrams show θ g (left) and the improvement on the discretionary equilibrium (right), the lower diagrams show percentage of the policy inefficiency improved (left) and the change in inflation and output-gap variability from the discretionary equilibrium (right), for different configurations of θ and λ. If θ is close to unity, privat-sector price setters are predominately backward-looking and the time-inconsistency problem is unimportant and the discretionary equilibrium is efficient. If, on the other hand, θ is low, inflation persistence is low and it does not provide an efficient channel for which output may become persistent. It will not be beneficial to have the Governor believe that inflation is persistent since his forecasts are expected by the private agents to be revised considerably in every period as inflation shifts, inducing only a small degree of output persistence. Consequently, the degree of optimal inflation persistence misperception (θ g θ) reaches a maximum for θ in its inner region. We also note that θ g θ. The reason is that only a higher perceived inflation persistence that provides more output persistence and thus a welfare increase. θ g will be equal to θ for θ = {0, 1}. Interestingly, θ g increases rapidly in θ and reaches unity for θ 0.4 ifλ 0.1. That is, θ g is unity also when society cares only a little about output variability. If the true degree of inflation persistence is in the inverval θ [0.5, 0.95], and λ>0.1, the by believeing that inflation is fully persistent, more than 70 percent of the policy inefficiency is removed. In the case where λ is equal to unity, more than 85 percent of the policy inefficiency is removed. Moreover, the analysis suggests that as λ decreases towards zero, and inflation persistence is moderate to high, the benefits from misperception decreases. A larger λ implies that the response on output to a cost-push shock should be smaller. Since a larger θ g implies a stronger response, however, such a change will only be beneficial if the benefits from the inflation per- 3

Figure 2: The upper diagrams show θ g (left) and the improvement on the discretionary equilibrium (right), the lower diagrams show percentage of the policy inefficiency improved (left) and the change in inflation and output-gap variability from the discretionary equilibrium (right), for different configurations of θ and γ. sistence channel on output is large enough to outweigh the effects of a sub-optimally strong output response. This will be the case when true inflation persistence is high enough to provide large enough benefits. In the limit, where inflation stability is the only concern for policy (λ = 0), the discretionary equilibrium is efficient as inflation variability is at its minimum, var(π) =σ 2 ε, and there are no benefits from inflation persistence misperception. Figure 2 shows the same information as Figure 1 under different configurations of θ and γ. We see that θ g is not sensitive to the choice of γ. However, it has important effects on the efficiency of our solution. As γ decreases, the policymaker faces a worse trade-off between inflation and output variability and the inefficiency of a discretionary policy increases. Since a smaller γ implies that the output response to a cost-push shock should be smaller (as with a larger λ), and higher percieved inflation persistence implies stronger responses, our solution will only provide greater improvement to the discretionary equilibrium if inflation persistence is large enough to create enough output persistence. 4. Concluding remarks We find by using an expectations-augmented Phillips curve that the Governor should believe that inflation is more persistent than it actually is. For a wide range of parameter configurations, the optimal perception of inflation persistence should be unity. This would considerably improve 4

on the policy inefficiency. Given that there is uncertainty about θ around some intermediate to high level, there is an additional advantage of misperception; the true value may not matter for policymaking. 5

References Fuhrer, J. C. (1997). The (Un)Importance of forward-looking behaviour in price specification. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 29:3, 338 350. Gali, J. and M. Gertler (1999). Inflation dynamics: A structural econometric analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics, 44, 195 222. Gali, J., M. Gertler, and J. D. López-Salido (2001). European inflation dynamics. European Economic Review, 45:7, 1237 1270. Kydland, F. E. and E. C. Prescott (1977). Rules rather than discretion: The inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy, 85(3), 473 91. Rogoff, K. (1985). The optimal degree of commitment to an intermediate monetary target. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100(4), 1169 89. Rudebusch, G. and L. E. Svensson (1999). Policy rules for inflation targeting. In J. B. Taylor (Ed.), Monetary Policy Rules, chap. 5, 203 262. University of Chicago Press, Chicago. Rudebusch, G. D. (2002). Assessing nominal income rules for monetary policy with model and data uncertainty. Economic Journal, 112, 1 31. Söderström, U. (2001). Targeting inflation with a prominent role for money. Manuscript, Sveriges Riksbank. Svensson, L. E. (1997). Optimal inflation targets, conservative central banks, and linear inflation contracts. American Economic Review, 87(1), 98 114. Walsh, C. E. (1995). Optimal contracts for central bankers. American Economic Review, 85(1), 150 67. Walsh, C. E. (2002). Speed limit policies: The output gap and optimal monetary policy. Forthcoming American Economic Review. Woodford, M. (1999). Optimal monetary policy inertia. Working Paper, Princeton University. 6