Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon

Similar documents
Log-Robust Portfolio Management

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle

Why Indexing Works. October Abstract

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( )

Effect of booms or disasters on the Sharpe Ratio

Periodic Returns, and Their Arithmetic Mean, Offer More Than Researchers Expect

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2012, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Week 2 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Hypothesis Testing and Confidence Intervals

Desirable properties for a good model of portfolio credit risk modelling

Dynamic Relative Valuation

1 The continuous time limit

STRATEGY OVERVIEW. Long/Short Equity. Related Funds: 361 Domestic Long/Short Equity Fund (ADMZX) 361 Global Long/Short Equity Fund (AGAZX)

CSC Advanced Scientific Programming, Spring Descriptive Statistics

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management

IDIOSYNCRATIC RISK AND AUSTRALIAN EQUITY RETURNS

Financial Econometrics

The Delta Method. j =.

Bloomberg. Portfolio Value-at-Risk. Sridhar Gollamudi & Bryan Weber. September 22, Version 1.0

Interpreting the Information Ratio

Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2007, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

The Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model

Instantaneous Error Term and Yield Curve Estimation

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

TESTING THE EXPECTATIONS HYPOTHESIS ON CORPORATE BOND YIELDS. Samih Antoine Azar *

Comparison of Estimation For Conditional Value at Risk

Risk management. Introduction to the modeling of assets. Christian Groll

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Assessing Regime Switching Equity Return Models

Inferences on Correlation Coefficients of Bivariate Log-normal Distributions

Course information FN3142 Quantitative finance

Valuation of a New Class of Commodity-Linked Bonds with Partial Indexation Adjustments

Sharpe Ratio Practice Note

arxiv:cond-mat/ v2 [cond-mat.str-el] 5 Nov 2002

Return dynamics of index-linked bond portfolios

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

Equation Chapter 1 Section 1 A Primer on Quantitative Risk Measures

Term Par Swap Rate Term Par Swap Rate 2Y 2.70% 15Y 4.80% 5Y 3.60% 20Y 4.80% 10Y 4.60% 25Y 4.75%

Correlation: Its Role in Portfolio Performance and TSR Payout

Probability in Options Pricing

Common Misconceptions about "Beta" Hedging, Estimation and Horizon Effects 1

8 th International Scientific Conference

Slides for Risk Management

BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income

Roy Model of Self-Selection: General Case

Return Interval Selection and CTA Performance Analysis. George Martin* David McCarthy** Thomas Schneeweis***

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13.

Financial Time Series and Their Characterictics

MTH6154 Financial Mathematics I Stochastic Interest Rates

Correlation vs. Trends in Portfolio Management: A Common Misinterpretation

University 18 Lessons Financial Management. Unit 12: Return, Risk and Shareholder Value

A gentle introduction to the RM 2006 methodology

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

A Multifrequency Theory of the Interest Rate Term Structure

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1

Simple Formulas to Option Pricing and Hedging in the Black-Scholes Model

Retirement. Optimal Asset Allocation in Retirement: A Downside Risk Perspective. JUne W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach

Annual risk measures and related statistics

Asian Economic and Financial Review A REGRESSION BASED APPROACH TO CAPTURING THE LEVEL DEPENDENCE IN THE VOLATILITY OF STOCK RETURNS

Chapter 7 Sampling Distributions and Point Estimation of Parameters

Bias in Reduced-Form Estimates of Pass-through

Volatility Forecasting and Interpolation

Global Currency Hedging

DATA SUMMARIZATION AND VISUALIZATION

Discussion of Lower-Bound Beliefs and Long-Term Interest Rates

OPTIMAL TIMING FOR INVESTMENT DECISIONS

Smooth estimation of yield curves by Laguerre functions

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

Assessing Regime Switching Equity Return Models

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios

VOLATILITY FORECASTING IN A TICK-DATA MODEL L. C. G. Rogers University of Bath

Valuing Early Stage Investments with Market Related Timing Risk

STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY AND OPTION PRICING

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Energy Price Processes

Continuous-Time Pension-Fund Modelling

Global Journal of Finance and Banking Issues Vol. 5. No Manu Sharma & Rajnish Aggarwal PERFORMANCE ANALYSIS OF HEDGE FUND INDICES

A VALUATION MODEL FOR INDETERMINATE CONVERTIBLES by Jayanth Rama Varma

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2011, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam.

2 Control variates. λe λti λe e λt i where R(t) = t Y 1 Y N(t) is the time from the last event to t. L t = e λr(t) e e λt(t) Exercises

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Martingales, Part II, with Exercise Due 9/21

Minimizing Timing Luck with Portfolio Tranching The Difference Between Hired and Fired

Research Factor Indexes and Factor Exposure Matching: Like-for-Like Comparisons

The Estimation of Expected Stock Returns on the Basis of Analysts' Forecasts

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

Amath 546/Econ 589 Univariate GARCH Models: Advanced Topics

The Constant Expected Return Model

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Exploiting Factor Autocorrelation to Improve Risk Adjusted Returns

Allocate Capital and Measure Performances in a Financial Institution

Homework Assignments

Randomness and Fractals

Quantitative relations between risk, return and firm size

Earnings or Dividends Which had More Predictive Power?

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Option Pricing. Chapter Discrete Time

Transcription:

Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon Ziemowit Bednarek, Pratish Patel and Cyrus Ramezani December 8, 2014 ABSTRACT Both building blocks of the Sharpe ratio the expected return and the expected volatility depend on the investment horizon. This raises a natural question: how does the Sharpe ratio vary with horizon? To address this question, we derive an explicit expression of the Sharpe ratio as a function of the investment horizon. Even if returns are independent and normally distributed, we show that the Sharpe ratio is humped shaped it first increases and then decreases as the horizon lengthens. We empirically corroborate our theory by analyzing the Sharpe ratio of various funds. Our analysis has an important implication for investors. Specifically, it is a common practice for investors to rank funds based on their Sharpe ratio. We show that the order of funds ranked by the Sharpe ratio may change with horizon. Namely, it may appear that one fund has a higher Sharpe ratio than other when the horizon is three years, but that the opposite holds true when the horizon increases to five years. Therefore, investors need to consider the Horizon Effect while considering the Sharpe ratio based rankings. California Polytechnic State University

I. Introduction Sharpe ratio is probably the most popular index of measuring a portfolio s reward to risk performance. Its popularity lies in its inherent simplicity: it is the ratio of the expected excess return of an investment to its volatility. Because both the expected return and volatility depend on the investment horizon, the Sharpe ratio depends on the horizon also. That being said, the relationship between the Sharpe ratio and horizon is not well-understood. In this article, we analyze the relationship between the Sharpe ratio and investment horizon. Our analysis has an important implication for investors. While elegantly summarizing the use of the Sharpe ratio, Kidd (2011) offers a simple rule of thumb: Higher is better. That is, in the process of comparing two funds, the fund with the higher Sharpe ratio is preferred. We show that this simple rule of thumb may lead to a bad decision. The error is mechanical in nature: it stems from the impact of horizon on the Sharpe ratio. Specifically, the relative ranking of two funds may change with the investment horizon. We label the change in ranking phenomenon as the Horizon Effect. To motivate our analysis, consider the following example. In Figure 1, we show the Morningstar Sharpe ratio over different horizons for two funds: Vanguard Total Stock Market Index Fund (VTSMX) and Vanguard 500 Index (VFINX). VTSMX is the largest mutual fund in the world with $343 billion in assets under management. VFINX, on the other hand, is the largest passive mutual fund mimicking S&P 500 with $173 billion in assets under management. 1 As expected, the returns of these two funds are almost perfectly correlated (correlation coefficient is 0.98). Inspite of the near perfect correlation, Sharpe ratios are different. The plot raises a few questions. First, why is the 15-year Sharpe-ratio of both funds lower than the 3-year Sharpe ratio? The second question concerns the Horizon Effect: why does the Sharpe ratio ranking change for these two funds? Specifically, the 3-year Sharpe ratio for VFINX is higher than the 3-year Sharpe ratio for VTSMX. However, the 15-year Sharpe ratio for VFINX is lower than the 15-year Sharpe ratio for VTSMX. These two questions point out 1 The assets under management numbers are based on Morningstar estimates as of August 13, 2014. We chose these two funds due to their size our results are more general. 2

the undesirable impact of the horizon on the Sharpe ratio. Lastly, the general shape of the plot directly violates the implication stemming from the Square root T rule commonly used in practice. Under the assumption of serially uncorrelated returns, in an influential article, Sharpe (1998) offers the Square root T rule: Letting S 1 and S T denote the Sharpe Ratios for 1 and T periods, respectively, it follows that: S T = T S 1. The third question concerns the applicability of the Square root T rule. Specifically, under what scenario is the Square root T rule applicable? 1.40 1.20 1.00 Sharpe ratio 0.80 0.60 VTSMX VFINX 0.40 0.20 0.00 3 year 5 year 10 year 15 year Investment Horizon Figure 1: This figure shows the Sharpe Ratio for two funds as calculated by Morningstar as of August 12, 2014. VTSMX is the symbol for Vanguard Total Stock Market Index Fund and VFINX is the symbol for Vanguard 500 Index. This article addresses these questions. For simplicity, we assume that the log-returns are independently and normally distributed. With this assumption, we show that expected return, volatility and in turn the Sharpe ratio are non-linear functions of the investment horizon. Due 3

to non-linearity, Sharpe ratio increases initially and then decreases as horizon lengthens. Nonlinearity also causes a switch in relative rankings (Horizon Effect). To summarize, non-linearity leads to a non-monotonic relationship between the Sharpe ratio and investment horizon. We show that compounding causes the non-monotonic relationship. As defined, Sharpe ratio depends on the moments of simple returns. Unfortunately, due to compounding, statistics of multi-period simple returns is not so simple. To address the compounding issue, we calculate the Sharpe ratio using log-returns. With this simple change, we show three very desirable properties: (i) Sharpe ratio monotonically increases with horizon; (ii) the relative ranking across horizons does not change and (iii) the Square root T is correct. In this manner, we reconcile the seemingly contradictory academic literature. We explain why on one hand, Levy (1972), Hodges et al. (1997) and Lin and Chou (2003) find that the Sharpe ratio is a non-linear function of the horizon and why on the other hand, Lo (2002) finds that the Sharpe ratio should increase with the Square root T rule when returns are serially independent. 2 Lastly, we calculate the Sharpe ratio of various funds using both simple and log-returns and corroborate the impact of horizon. We empirically validate Kidd (2011) s rule of thumb: when Sharpe ratio is calculated using log-returns, higher is [indeed] better. II. Model showing the effect of horizon on the Sharpe ratio This section introduces the model. Traded are an index with time t value denoted by P (t) and a money market account, with time t value denoted by B(t). We start the money market account with a dollar, i.e. B(0) = 1. Without loss of generality, we also assume that the index pays no dividends. 2 To be precise, for expositional clarity, Lo (2002) either ignores compounding or assumes continuous compounding (See footnote 7 in the paper). Additionally, both Sharpe (1998) andlo (2002) recognize the complicated effect of compounding. For instance, Sharpe (1998) recommends using short periods (for example, monthly) to measure risks and returns and then annualizing the data. He believed using multi-period returns complicates the ratio because of compounding or potential serial correlation. 4

We assume that the dynamics of the index are given by: P (t) = P (0) exp{r(t)} t 0. (1) For each t, the random variable r(t) is interpreted as the log-return over t periods. We further assume that the random variable r(t) is normally distributed: ) ] r(t) N [(µ 12 σ2 t, σ 2 t where µ is interpreted as an instantaneous annualized drift rate, σ is interpreted as an instantaneous annualized volatility. Equation (1) implies that the index price, P (t), is log-normally distributed. 3 We also assume that the risk-free rate is constant. That is, the money-market account evolves as: B(t) = B(0) exp{r f t}. (2) Over a span of T periods, the simple return between t and t + T is R(t, t + T ) P (t + T ) P (t) 1, (3) while the log-return over T periods is r(t, t + T ) ln{1 + R(t, t + T )}. (4) Slight algebra shows that the simple returns aggregate as 1 + R(t, t + T ) = T 1 i=0 ( 1 + R(t + i, t + i + 1) ) (5) 3 Equation (1) is the same as assuming that the index price dynamics follow a Geometric Brownian motion. 5

while log-returns aggregate as r(t, t + T ) = T 1 i=0 r(t + i, t + i + 1). (6) Equation (6) indicates that a T period log-return is the sum of T one-period log-returns. As a result, as long as the log-return is stationary, the exact distribution of the T period log-return can be derived with relative ease. Alternatively, central limit theorem can be readily applied. On the other hand, working with simple returns is not so simple. Due to the complicated nature of aggregating simple returns in equation (5), conventional statistics are harder to calculate. Therefore, due to the tractable properties, both academics and practitioners implicitly prefer to work with log-returns. In the appendix, we show that the expected simple and the expected log-return at time t for a T period horizon are E t [R(t, t + T )] = exp{µ T } 1, (7) and E t [r(t, t + T )] = (µ 1 2 σ2 ) T. (8) Similarly, the variance of simple and the variance log-returns at time t for a T period horizon are Var t [R(t, t + T )] = exp{2 µ T } (exp{σ 2 T } 1), (9) and Var t [r(t, t + T )] = σ 2 T. (10) With the expression of the expectation and variance of simple and log-returns, we analyze the Sharpe ratio next. 6

A. Expression for the Sharpe ratio using simple returns The simple return from investing in the money-market account is R f (t, t + T ) B(t + T ) B(t) 1 = exp{r f T } 1. Sharpe ratio over horizon T using simple returns is SR S (T ) E t [R(t, t + T )] R f (t, t + T ) Vart [R(t, t + T )] (11) = exp{µ T } exp{r f T } exp{2 µ T } (exp{σ2 T } 1) (12) For clarity, we include the superscript S indicating that the Sharpe ratio is calculated using simple returns. Upon inspection of equation (12), it is clear that the both the numerator and denominator of the Sharpe ratio are non-linear functions of the horizon T. B. Expression for the Sharpe ratio using log-returns Sharpe ratio over horizon T using log-returns is SR L (T ) E t [r(t, t + T )] r f T + 1 2 Var t [r(t, t + T )] Vart [r(t, t + T )] (13) = (µ r f) σ T = SR L (1) T (14) The variance term in the numerator of equation (13) is a Jensen s inequality adjustment arising from the expectation of log-returns. Effectively, this term converts the expected excess return from a geometric average to an arithmetic average. For more details, see equation 11 of the Consumption based Asset Pricing handbook chapter in Campbell (2003). Again, for clarity, we include the superscript L indicating that the Sharpe ratio is calculated using log returns. Upon inspection of equation (14), the Square root T rule is clearly evident. In fact, this is the precise expression put forth by Sharpe (1998) and derived rigorously in Lo (2002). Next, 7

we compare the Sharpe ratio calculated using both simple and log-returns. C. Comparision of Sharpe ratios calculated using either simple or log-returns By Taylor expanding SR S (T ) as a function of T, we see that SR S (T ) = T (µ r f) [ ] σ + O T 5 2 = SR L (T ) + O [ ] T 3 2 µ r + T 3 f 0.5(µ 2 + rf 2 ) + 0.25σ(r µσ) 2 σ (15) Upon inspection of equation (15), the Sharpe ratio calculated using simple returns approximately follows the Square root T rule for short horizons. As horizon T lengthens, higher order terms of SR S (T ) carry more weight. As a result, departures from the Square root T rule become more evident. Figure 2 shows the Sharpe ratio SR S (T ) calculated using simple returns for two different set of parameters. The solid line plots the ratio assuming the drift rate of the index µ is 8% and the volatility σ is 15%. We label this first set of parameters as Parameter Set 1. These numbers are consistent with S&P 500. The solid line with square markers shows the Sharpe ratio where both drift and volatility are slightly inflated: µ is 12% and σ is 20%. We label this second set of parameters as Parameter Set 2. Additionally, we set the risk free rate to 1%. Two observations are in order. First, as pointed out by Levy (1972), Hodges et al. (1997) and Lin and Chou (2003), the Sharpe ratio calculated using simple returns SR S (T ) does not monotonically increase with the horizon T. In fact, the Sharpe ratio is humped shaped. Second, there is a Sharpe ratio ranking reversal this is the Horizon Effect. Sharpe ratio using Parameter Set 2 outperforms Sharpe ratio using Parameter Set 1 when the horizon is short. However, the ranking reverses at longer horizons. Figure 3 shows the Sharpe ratio SR L (T ) calculated using log-returns for the same set of parameters. The results are dramatically different. The Sharpe ratio is a monotonically 8

Figure 2: This figure compares the Sharpe ratio SR S (T ) calculated by using simple returns as a function of investment horizon T. increasing function of the investment horizon consistent with Lo (2002). Second, there is no ranking reversal. Sharpe ratio using Parameter Set 1 always outperforms Sharpe ratio using Parameter Set 2. Next, we corroborate our theory by analyzing the Sharpe ratio for various funds over different horizons. III. Empirical analysis of the Sharpe ratio of various funds over different horizons To illustrate the effect of horizon, we estimate the Sharpe ratio of several popular portfolios. Specifically, from Ken French s website, we use monthly returns of portfolios sorted by size and book to market. The sample starts from the year 1927 and ends in year 2013. We sample returns at a monthly frequency as it is a common practice among both industry practitioners and academics. 4 4 In the online appendix, we also present results for portfolios formed on earnings-price ratio and five industry portfolios. We also calculate the Sharpe ratio using data from different sample periods our results are robust. 9

Figure 3: This figure compares the Sharpe ratio SR L (T ) calculated by using log-returns as a function of investment horizon T. To improve our estimation, we calculate the Sharpe ratios using bootstrapping with replacement. To calculate the Sharpe ratio for a horizon of T years, we draw with replacement a random sample of T 12 returns from the pool of all available monthly returns. We use equations (5) and (6) to compute either a T period simple return or a T period log-return. By bootstrapping with replacement, we implicitly assume that the returns are serially uncorrelated. To remedy this issue, we also performed our analysis using block bootstrapping as recommended by Lin and Chou (2003). Results do not change both qualitatively and quantitatively. The Sharpe ratio is calculated for each drawn sample, and this procedure is repeated 100,000 times for each T year horizon. The reported Sharpe ratio for T year horizon is an average of 100,000 calculations. Due to the incredible precision, we do not report standard errors for our estimates. Table I shows the Sharpe ratio SR S (T ) calculated using simple returns. The number in the parenthesis is the Sharpe ratio calculated using the Square root T rule ( T SR S (1)). The Sharpe ratios range from 0.37 (Growth portfolio with horizon of one year) to 0.84 (Large portfolio with horizon of ten years). Upon inspection, the basic non-monotonic shape of Figure 1 is evident for all portfolios. The 7-year Sharpe ratio is higher than 25-year Sharpe ratio for 10

all the portfolios. Broadly speaking, the Sharpe ratio increases initially and then decreases as horizon lengthens. Second, the Horizon Effect is also clear: there are several instances of Sharpe ratio ranking reversals. For example, the Growth portfolio looks inferior to the Value portfolio at a horizon of 1-year, but it looks superior at a horizon of 10-years. To summarize, consistent with equation (12), the Sharpe ratios calculated using simple returns are humped shaped and suffer from the Horizon Effect. Horizon T Small Medium Large Growth Medium Value 1 0.38 0.42 0.39 0.37 0.40 0.44 (0.38) (0.42) (0.39) (0.37) (0.40) (0.44) 3 0.55 0.64 0.63 0.58 0.64 0.65 (0.66) (0.73) (0.68) (0.64) (0.69) (0.76) 5 0.62 0.73 0.74 0.70 0.74 0.73 (0.85) (0.94) (0.87) (0.83) (0.89) (0.98) 7 0.62 0.76 0.80 0.75 0.79 0.75 (1.01) (1.11) (1.03) (0.98) (1.06) (1.16) 10 0.57 0.76 0.84 0.79 0.82 0.73 (1.20) (1.33) (1.23) (1.17) (1.26) (1.39) 15 0.53 0.69 0.81 0.80 0.79 0.66 (1.47) (1.63) (1.51) (1.43) (1.55) (1.70) 25 0.38 0.53 0.74 0.71 0.66 0.47 (1.90) (2.10) (1.95) (1.85) (2.00) (2.20) Table I: This table calculates the Sharpe ratio using simple returns for different horizons. The number in parenthesis shows the hypothetical Sharpe ratio calculated using the Square root T rule. Table II shows the Sharpe ratio SR L (T ) calculated using log-returns. These results are quite different from those in Table I. The Sharpe ratios range from 0.28 (Small portfolio with horizon of 1 year) to 1.78 (Value portfolio with horizon of 10 years). Upon inspection, the Sharpe ratios increase with horizon for all portfolios. Furthermore, there are no ranking reversals as predicted by equation (14) the Horizon Effect disappears. As expected from equation (15), the Sharpe ratio calculated using both simple and log-returns are approximately similar for short horizons. Lastly, note the applicability of the Square root T rule. Using simple returns as is the case in Table I, the Square root T becomes an increasingly bad rule as the horizon lengthens. For example, the 1-year Sharpe ratio, SR S (1), for the Growth portfolio is 0.37. Applying the Square root T rule for a horizon of 25 years, 25 0.37, gives a predicted value of 1.85; while 11

Horizon T Small Medium Large Growth Medium Value 1 0.28 0.34 0.32 0.29 0.34 0.35 (0.28) (0.34) (0.32) (0.29) (0.34) (0.35) 3 0.49 0.58 0.56 0.50 0.57 0.62 (0.48) (0.59) (0.55) (0.50) (0.59) (0.61) 5 0.64 0.76 0.71 0.64 0.75 0.80 (0.63) (0.76) (0.72) (0.65) (0.76) (0.78) 7 0.74 0.89 0.83 0.76 0.88 0.94 (0.74) (0.90) (0.85) (0.77) (0.90) (0.93) 10 0.89 1.06 1.00 0.90 1.06 1.13 (0.89) (1.08) (1.01) (0.92) (1.08) (1.11) 15 1.09 1.30 1.23 1.11 1.28 1.38 (1.08) (1.32) (1.24) (1.12) (1.32) (1.36) 25 1.41 1.70 1.59 1.44 1.68 1.78 (1.40) (1.70) (1.60) (1.45) (1.70) (1.75) Table II: This table calculates the Sharpe ratio using log-returns for different horizons. The number in parenthesis shows the hypothetical Sharpe ratio calculated using the Square root T rule. the actual Sharpe ratio, SR S (25), is 0.71. On the other hand, using log-returns as is the case in Table II, the Square root T holds remarkably well. The 1-year Sharpe ratio, SR L (1), for the Growth portfolio is 0.29. Applying the Square root T rule for a horizon of 25 years, 25 0.29, gives a predicted value of 1.45; while the actual Sharpe ratio, SR L (25), is 1.44. In summary, we demonstrate how the behavior of the Sharpe ratio changes when we use either simple or log-returns. We show that using simple returns as is commonly used in practice, the Sharpe ratio is actually humped shaped. On the other hand, using log-returns, the Sharpe ratio increases monotonically with horizon. Furthermore, using log-returns, Square root T rule holds remarkably well. IV. Conclusion Although the Sharpe ratio has gained popularity, its dependence on the investment horizon is not well-understood. In this paper, we remedy this issue by analyzing the effect of horizon on the Sharpe ratio. Under the assumption that log-returns are independently and normally distributed, we derive an explicit expression of the Sharpe ratio. 12

We theoretically and empirically highlight three undesirable features of the Sharpe ratio. First, we show that the Sharpe ratio is not a monotonic function of the horizon. The second feature has an explicit implication for an investor who uses the Sharpe ratio to choose funds. We document the Horizon Effect: Sharpe ratio is subject to a ranking reversal over different horizons. That is, an investor may prefer one fund over short horizon but may prefer another fund over longer horizon. Third, we show that the Square root T rule becomes an increasingly bad rule as horizon lengthens. The undesirable features are due to compounding of simple returns. As noted by both Sharpe (1998) andlo (2002), compounding taints the use of the Sharpe ratio over longer horizons. In this paper, we formally show how compounding taints the Sharpe ratio over longer horizon. We conclude with one suggestion. We recommend a slight change: calculate Sharpe ratio using log-returns. This change remedies the three undesirable features. With this change, Kidd (2011) s rule of thumb regarding the Sharpe ratio is indeed valid: higher is better. 13

References Campbell, J. Y. (2003). Consumption-based asset pricing. Handbook of the Economics of Finance 1, 803 887. Hodges, C. W., W. R. Taylor, and J. A. Yoder (1997). Stocks, bonds, the sharpe ratio, and the investment horizon. Financial Analysts Journal, 74 80. Kidd, D. (2011). The sharpe ratio and the information ratio. Investment Performance Measurement Feature Articles 2011 (1), 1 4. Levy, H. (1972). Portfolio performance and the investment horizon. Management Science 18 (12), B 645. Lin, M.-C. and P.-H. Chou (2003). The pitfall of using sharpe ratio. Finance Letters 1, 84 89. Lo, A. W. (2002). The statistics of sharpe ratios. Financial Analysts Journal, 36 52. Sharpe, W. F. (1998). The sharpe ratio. Streetwise the Best of the Journal of Portfolio Management, 169 185. 14