The Mystery of TFP. Nicholas Oulton

Similar documents
Outline of Presentation. I. Trends in Revenue Mobilization. II. Measuring Tax Gap. III. IMF s Approach RA-GAP

Can employment be increased only at the cost of more inequality?

The Mystery of TFP. Nicholas Oulton London School of Economics and National Institute of Economic and Social Research 1

Outlook Overview: OECD Countries UN LINK Conference, Bangkok October, 2009

Earnings related schemes: Design, options and experience. Edward Whitehouse

THE TAX SYSTEM IN BELGIUM COMPARED TO OTHER OECD COUNTRIES

HOUSING MARKETS, BUSINESS CYCLES AND ECONOMIC POLICIES

education (captured by the school leaving age), household income (measured on a ten-point

The Challenge of Public Pension Reform in Advanced and Emerging Economies

Income support for older persons in the Republic of Korea : a perspective of older persons

Capital Access Index 2006 Gauging Entrepreneurial Access to Capital

Pensions at a Glance: Europe and Central Asia

Revenue Statistics Tax revenue trends in the OECD

The Challenge of Public Pension Reform

axia Axia Economics Civil-service pension schemes Edward Whitehouse Civil-Service World Bank core course Washington DC, April 2016

Slovak Competitiveness: Fundamentals, Indicators and Challenges

The Economic Contribution of Older Workers

COVERAGE OF PRIVATE PENSION SYSTEMS AND MAIN TRENDS IN THE PENSIONS INDUSTRY IN THE OECD

UK Economic Performance since 1997: Growth and Productivity

ICT and Knowledge Based Capital: Productivity Growth and New Policy Challenges

Entrepreneurship at a Glance 2018 Highlights

Structural perspectives on European employment, productivity and growth in a global context Sintra, Portugal, 23 May 2015

TAX REFORM TRENDS IN OECD COUNTRIES

Nero Meeting: Alain de Serres OECD Economics Department. 21 June 2013

Hyunbae Chun (Sogang University) Hak K. Pyo (Seoul National University) Keun Hee Rhee (Korea Productivity Center)

Swedish Lessons: How Important are ICT and R&D to Economic Growth? Paper prepared for the 34 th IARIW General Conference, Dresden, Aug 21-27, 2016

Potential value of processing of telecom metadata for the European economy

Corrigendum. Page 41, Table 1.A1.1. Details of pension reforms, September 2013-September 2015 : Columns on Portugal should read as follows:

Extract from Divided We Stand: Why Inequality Keeps Rising

High Debt, Slow Growth, Financial Instability, Growing Inequality: What Role for Economic Policy?

Why is Japan s inward FDI so low?

London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine. Affording Our Future Conference Wellington, December, 2012

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

THE BENEFITS OF EXPANDING THE ROLE OF WOMEN AND YOUTH IN ECONOMIC ACTIVITIES

Disentangling demographic and nondemographic drivers of health spending: a possible methodology and data requirements

Primary Health Care Needs-Based Resource Allocation through Financing of Health Regions

Trade and long term unemployment: aquantitativeassessment

RESILIENCE IN A TIME OF HIGH DEBT

Discussion Papers. Faculty of Management Science and Engineering. The Growth Disease at 50: Baumol after Oulton

EFFICIENCY OF EDUCATION EXPENDITURE IN OECD COUNTRIES

Fiscal Policy and Income Inequality. March 13, 2014

MINIMUM WAGES ACROSS OECD COUNTRIES: BACK TO THE FUTURE?

NATIONAL COMMUNICATIONS FROM PARTIES INCLUDED IN ANNEX I TO THE CONVENTION

REVERSE MORTGAGES: A TOOL TO IMPROVE LIVING STANDARDS OF THE ELDERLY? A EUROPEAN PERSPECTIVE

Cyclical Convergence and Divergence in the Euro Area

IMPROVING TAX COMPLIANCE. 6th IMF-Japan High-Level Tax Conference For Asian Countries Tokyo; April 7, 2015

UNITED KINGDOM TRADE AND INVESTMENT STATISTICAL NOTE

The Norwegian Economy

OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK Moving forward in difficult times. 3 rd December Mauro Pisu OECD Senior Economist

Research Reports 387. International Fragmentation of Production, Trade and Growth: Impacts and Prospects for EU Member States

NEW ZEALAND TRADE AND INVESTMENT STATISTICAL NOTE

Private pensions. A growing role. Who has a private pension?

FDI drops 18% in 2017 as corporate restructurings decline

SEE macroeconomic outlook Recovery gains traction, fiscal discipline improving. Alen Kovac, Chief Economist EBC May 2016 Ljubljana

The Northern Ireland labour market is characterised by relatively. population of working age are not active in the labour market at

What is the economic outlook for OECD countries?

Public Pension Spending Trends and Outlook in Emerging Europe. Benedict Clements Fiscal Affairs Department International Monetary Fund March 2013

EU KLEMS Growth and Productivity Accounts March 2011 Update of the November 2009 release

ITALY TRADE AND INVESTMENT STATISTICAL NOTE

Conference Presentation

Current Challenges in Revenue Mobilization: Improving Tax Compliance. CEPAL Regional Tax Seminar March 10, 2015

OECD Science, Technology and Industry Scoreboard 2013

Alternative measures of well-being

ICELAND TRADE AND INVESTMENT STATISTICAL NOTE

MMGPI 2016 Outcomes. Dr David Knox Senior Partner, Mercer

From GDP to average household income: A look at the transmission channels

STRUCTURAL POLICIES AND THE DISTRIBUTION

Promoting Industrialisation in SADC through Quality Infrastructure SADC Industrialisation Week 2017

NORWAY TRADE AND INVESTMENT STATISTICAL NOTE

Gross domestic product of Montenegro for period

CANADA EUROPEAN UNION

Extended Supply-Use Tables for Internationally Integrated Economic Accounts

AUSTRIA TRADE AND INVESTMENT STATISTICAL NOTE

2017 OECD ECONOMIC SURVEY OF SWITZERLAND

HUNGARY TRADE AND INVESTMENT STATISTICAL NOTE

Investments in green and social sectors can create 2.8 million jobs in the EU

Self-employment Incidence, Overall Income Inequality and Wage Compression

Understanding the World Economy Master in Economics and Business. Fiscal policy. Nicolas Coeurdacier

SWITZERLAND TRADE AND INVESTMENT STATISTICAL NOTE

FINLAND TRADE AND INVESTMENT STATISTICAL NOTE

PROGRESSIVITY IN TAX DESIGN. Michael Keen International Monetary Fund

EUROPA - Press Releases - Taxation trends in the European Union EU27 tax...of GDP in 2008 Steady decline in top corporate income tax rate since 2000

ECONOMIC POLICY CHALLENGES FOR DENMARK FROM AN INTERNATIONAL PERSPECTIVE

Development Assistance for HealTH

Europe in the World Economy: Economic Recovery and Europe 2020

DENMARK TRADE AND INVESTMENT STATISTICAL NOTE

Gross domestic product of Montenegro in 2011

Decomposition of Poland s Bilateral Trade Imbalances by Value Added Content

CANADA TRADE AND INVESTMENT STATISTICAL NOTE

POLAND TRADE AND INVESTMENT STATISTICAL NOTE

GERMANY TRADE AND INVESTMENT STATISTICAL NOTE

From Here to Eternity: The Outlook for Fiscal Adjustment in Advanced Economies. Carlo Cottarelli Director, Fiscal Affairs Department

Welfare in Slovakia and the EU an alternative to GDP per capita

SLOVAK REPUBLIC TRADE AND INVESTMENT STATISTICAL NOTE

CZECH REPUBLIC TRADE AND INVESTMENT STATISTICAL NOTE

Gross domestic product of Montenegro in 2016

Waiting for the Recovery: OECD Labour Markets in the Wake of the Crisis

Fiscal Policy and Inequality: What Do We Know? Benedict Clements International Monetary Fund

Insurance Markets in Figures

FRANCE TRADE AND INVESTMENT STATISTICAL NOTE

Transcription:

The Mystery of TFP Nicholas Oulton Centre for Macroeconomics, London School of Economics and National Institute of Economic and Social Research Email: n.oulton@lse.ac.uk GGDC 25 th Anniversary Conference, June 28-30, 2017

Causes of (measured) aggregate TFP growth 1. Technical and scientific progress (including improvements in management techniques). 2. Learning effects, either learning by doing or learning from others, or more broadly externalities; economies of scale. 3. Reallocation of inputs towards more (or less) productive uses, either at the firm or the industry level. 4. Measurement error, e.g. if increases in the quality of human or physical capital are wrongly ignored or if output is mis-measured or when some types of asset (such as intangibles) are wrongly omitted. Solow (REcStats 1957); Hulten (2001) 2

Causes of (measured) aggregate TFP growth 1. Technical and scientific progress (including improvements in management techniques). 2. Learning effects, either learning by doing or learning from others, or more broadly externalities; economies of scale. 3. Reallocation of inputs towards more (or less) productive uses, either at the firm or the industry level. 4. Measurement error, e.g. if increases in the quality of human or physical capital are wrongly ignored or if output is mis-measured or when some types of asset (such as intangibles) are wrongly omitted. 5. Shifts in the structure of output and demand leading to changes in the aggregate growth rate of TFP and hence of aggregate labour productivity. These shifts could be favourable or unfavourable. Baumol (AER, 1967); Oulton (OEP, 2001) 3

Questions considered in this presentation Has structural change been favourable or unfavourable to growth? Is capital mis-measured? Is the true elasticity of output with respect to capital (the capital elasticity) higher than capital s share? If so, TFP growth is overstated. Does TFP growth cause capital growth? Is TFP growth persistent? 4

Data Source: EU KLEMS (www.euklems.net). 18 countries with data on TFP growth. Maximum period for TFP growth: 1971-2007. 10 industry groups collectively making up the market (business) sector. So imputed rent of home-owners, health, education and government excluded (25% of GDP). O Mahony and Timmer (EJ, 2009) 5

Countries and periods Code Country name First year Last year Number of years AUS Australia 1983 2007 25 AUT Austria 1981 2007 27 BEL Belgium 1981 2006 26 CZE Czech Republic 1996 2007 12 DNK Denmark 1981 2007 27 ESP Spain 1981 2007 27 FIN Finland 1971 2007 37 FRA France 1981 2007 27 GER Germany 1992 2007 16 HUN Hungary 1996 2007 12 IRL Ireland 1989 2007 19 ITA Italy 1971 2007 37 JPN Japan 1974 2006 33 NLD Netherlands 1980 2007 28 SVN Slovenia 1996 2006 11 SWE Sweden 1994 2007 14 UK United Kingdom 1971 2007 37 USA United States 1978 2007 30 6

The 10 sectors included in the study Sector code Sector description Value added share of GDP, % Share of total (whole economy) hours, % A & B Agriculture, hunting and forestry. Fishing 4.3 8.3 C Mining & quarrying 1.4 0.5 D Manufacturing 22.1 21.1 E Electricity, gas & water 2.4 0.9 F Construction 6.6 8.0 G Wholesale & retail trade; repair of motor vehicles, motorcycles, and personal and household goods 11.9 15.3 H Hotels & restaurants 2.4 4.1 I Transport, storage and communications 7.3 6.6 J Financial intermediation 5.1 2.9 K (exc. 70) Business services 7.1 7.0 A-K (exc. 70) Market sector 70.6 74.6 A-Q Whole economy (GDP) 100.0 100.0 Shares are unweighted means across 18 countries and time. 7

Why industry data from EU KLEMS? The industry data is consistent with the national accounts of each country. In EU KLEMS labour and capital are measured in a detailed and consistent way. Labour is measured by hours worked broken down by education, age and sex. Capital, measured by the PIM, is broken down into 7 types (3 ICT and 4 non-ict). In micro data labour and capital are often crudely measured, e.g. heads not hours for labour and no breakdown by type. Capital is often measured by book value, with no breakdown by type. 8

Structural change In all countries, resources have been shifting towards industries with lower than average TFP growth (Finance) or even negative TFP growth (Business services). But TFP growth in the market sector generally shows no long run tendency to decline. How is this possible? 9

10

Value added share of Business services (K, exc. 70) in market sector GDP 0.300 AUS AUT BEL CZE DNK 0.200 0.100 0.000 0.300 ESP FIN FRA GER HUN 0.200 0.100 0.000 0.300 IRL ITA JPN NLD SVN 0.200 0.100 0.000 1970 1980 1990 20002007 1970 1980 1990 2000 2007 0.300 SWE UK USA 0.200 0.100 0.000 1970 1980 1990 2000 2007 1970 1980 1990 2000 2007 1970 1980 1990 2000 2007 Source: EU KLEMS. Note: Dashed lines denote country means. 11

Mean TFP growth rates, % p.a., by country 4 D. Manufacturing 3.94 3 3.08 3.24 3.11 3.42 3.51 2.41 2 1.33 1.63 1.93 1.46 2.15 1.89 1.83 2.15 1 0.77 0.62 0.19 0 AUS AUT BEL CZE DNK ESP FIN FRA GER HUN IRL ITA JPN NLD SVN SWE UK USA 1 K (exc. 70). Renting and business activities 0.52 0-0.16-1 -1.08-0.51-0.80-0.81-1.49-1.24-0.87-1.11-1.06-0.90-1.43-1.07-0.67-2 -2.04-3 -3.01-3.30 AUS AUT BEL CZE DNK ESP FIN FRA GER HUN IRL ITA JPN NLD SVN SWE UK USA 12

Growth of TFP in the market sector (A-K), % p.a. AUS AUT BEL CZE DNK 5.00 0.00-5.00 ESP FIN FRA GER HUN 5.00 0.00-5.00 IRL ITA JPN NLD SVN 5.00 0.00-5.00 1970 1980 1990 20002007 1970 1980 1990 2000 2007 SWE UK USA 5.00 0.00-5.00 1970 1980 1990 2000 2007 1970 1980 1990 2000 2007 1970 1980 1990 20002007 Actual Trend Mean Source: EU KLEMS. Note: Trend growth rate is that of HP-smoothed TFP level. Dashed lines denote country means of actual TFP growth rate. 13

Baumol s (AER, 1967) cost disease model Suppose output grows at the same rate in all industries but some industries (e.g. services) have lower TFP growth than others (e.g. manufacturing). Then resources shift to slowproductivity-growth services and overall TFP (and LP growth) slows down. But this argument is couched in terms of final services (private or public). What about intermediate services? (Oulton, OEP, 2001). 14

Aggregate and industry TFP growth Aggregate (top down) measure of TFP growth: : Vˆ Kˆ (1 ) Lˆ V : real value added (GDP); :TFP growth 15

Aggregate and industry TFP growth Top down measure of aggregate TFP growth: : Vˆ Kˆ (1 ) Lˆ V : real value added (GDP); :TFP growth Bottom up measure of aggregate TFP growth is a Domar-weighted sum (not average) of industry TFP growth rates: N i 1 d i GO i GOi where di :, the Domar weights GDP and : ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ GO C D N i Yi 1 ik Kik k l 1 il Lil m j 1 ijm ij Simple algebra shows that top down and bottom up measures are identically equal. Domar (EJ, 1961); Hulten, RES, 1978; Jorgenson et al. (1987); Gabaix, Econometrica, 2011. 16

Aggregate and industry TFP growth, cont. Alternatively, we can use the value added concept of TFP growth: ˆ ˆ ˆ VA C VA D VA i : Vi 1 ik K k ik l 1 il L il Simplealgebra shows that: VA i GO VAi i GO i Hence we get the alternative aggregation scheme: N i 1 v v VA i i i : value added share of ith industry in GDP 17

Implications of Domar aggregation N i 1 d i GO i 1. The Domar weights do not sum to 1 (generally the sum is between 2 and 3). 2. One Domar weight can increase without any other weight necessarily decreasing. 3. For given TFP growth rates, a rise in the Domar weight for the ith industry will raise the aggregate TFP growth rate, provided TFP growth in the ith industry is positive. 4. A shift in resources from high TFP growth to low (but positive) TFP growth industries can raise, not lower, the aggregate TFP growth rate. 18

Simple two-sector model Closed economy, two sectors: Cars and Business services (BuS) Car industry makes only final sales. Business services makes only intermediate sales (to the car industry). Cars uses K, L, and BuS as inputs. BuS uses only K and L as inputs. 19

Growth accounting in the simple two-sector model where and GO GO GO GO d d 0, 0 d d Cars BuS Cars Cars BuS BuS Cars BuS GOCars Final sales of cars 1 GDP GDP GO Intermediate sales to Cars GO VA GDP GDP GO VA 1 GO BuS Cars Cars Cars Cars Cars 20

Increased outsourcing as a source of growth Suppose there is increasing outsourcing by the car industry, i.e. GO/VA is rising in cars. Then d BuS is rising even though d Cars is constant. I.e. the sum of the Domar weights increases. So for given (gross output) TFP growth in Cars and Business services, aggregate μ rises. And this is true even if TFP growth in BuS is lower than in Cars. (Using the value added concept, TFP growth is rising in cars, constant in BuS, and rising overall since contribution of Cars is constant). 21

In summary Domar weight on BuS can rise, with everything else on RHS constant. So μ rises. GO GO GO ( dcars ) Cars ( d ) BuS BuS 0 BuS Baumol (AER, 1967); Oulton (OEP, 2001); Baumol in Krueger (JEP, 2001) 22

Intuition As long as TFP growth in Business services is positive, the price of providing these services is falling relative to the price in the Car industry of providing them in-house. If demand for Business services is elastic then their share in total costs of the car industry will rise. In practice, Business services includes some very sophisticated and high-tech products (design, accountancy, legal, management, computer, etc). 23

Changes in Domar weights between first year and last year Sections A-F G,H I,J,K Sum Australia -0.255 0.151 0.227 0.123 Austria -0.086 0.035 0.275 0.224 Belgium -0.104 0.117 0.371 0.384 Czech Republic 0.179 0.005 0.124 0.308 Denmark -0.308-0.024 0.369 0.037 Spain -0.525 0.050 0.192-0.283 Finland -0.022 0.050 0.272 0.300 France -0.290 0.062 0.297 0.069 Germany 0.130-0.008 0.177 0.299 Hungary 0.152 0.011 0.086 0.249 Ireland -0.246-0.027 0.306 0.033 Italy 0.003 0.182 0.369 0.554 Japan -0.507 0.042 0.222-0.243 Netherlands -0.356 0.065 0.268-0.023 Slovenia -0.043-0.017 0.090 0.030 Sweden 0.054 0.011 0.079 0.144 United Kingdom -0.697 0.118 0.452-0.127 United States -0.458 0.003 0.300-0.155 A-F: production G,H: consumer services I,J,K: business-related services Mean -0.188 0.046 0.249 0.107 No. negative 13 4 0 5 24

But now there s a problem Mean TFP growth rates, % p.a., by country 4 D. Manufacturing 3.94 3 3.08 3.24 3.11 3.42 3.51 2.41 2 1.33 1.63 1.93 1.46 2.15 1.89 1.83 2.15 1 0.77 0.62 0.19 0 AUS AUT BEL CZE DNK ESP FIN FRA GER HUN IRL ITA JPN NLD SVN SWE UK USA 1 K (exc. 70). Renting and business activities 0.52 0-0.16-1 -1.08-0.51-0.80-0.81-1.49-1.24-0.87-1.11-1.06-0.90-1.43-1.07-0.67-2 -2.04-3 -3.01-3.30 AUS AUT BEL CZE DNK ESP FIN FRA GER HUN IRL ITA JPN NLD SVN SWE UK USA 25

Calculating the effect on TFP TFP growth in Business services is negative ---very implausible. Good price indices are lacking. So set it equal to mean TFP growth rate in the market sector in each country in each year. Adjust the TFP growth rates of other industries so that average is unchanged. (Conservative assumption: aggregate TFP growth rate is correct, offsetting errors at industry level). Now calculate what TFP growth in the market sector would have been if the Domar weights had been constant at (a) those of the beginning of the sample period or (b) those of the end of the sample period. The difference [(b) minus (a)] is the effect of structural change. 26

The effect of structural change on TFP growth: contribution of Business services and total Country Business services Total Australia 0.04-0.01 Austria 0.15 0.13 Belgium 0.05-0.05 Czech Republic 0.03 0.40 Denmark 0.06 0.31 Spain 0.01-0.24 Finland 0.18 0.18 France 0.11 0.08 Germany 0.04 0.15 Hungary 0.07 0.16 Ireland 0.08 0.13 Italy 0.06-0.17 Japan 0.09 0.02 Netherlands 0.07 0.08 Slovenia 0.03-0.17 Sweden 0.09 0.25 United Kingdom 0.16-0.33 United States 0.09-0.37 TFP growth in Business services set equal to market sector average in each country. Other sectors adjusted to keep market sector average the same. Mean (unweighted) 0.08 0.03 27

Results 11 out of 18 countries show a positive effect of structural change. And the average boost to growth for these 11 was 0.17% per year. The actual TFP growth rate amongst these 11 was 1.4% per year, so the boost is significant. 7 countries show a negative effect. 28

Conclusions The shift to Business services has had a positive effect on TFP growth in all countries (+0.08% per year). Overall, structural change has been positive in 11/18 countries. So the positive effect of Business services was offset by negative effects in 7/18 countries. These conclusions rely on upwardly adjusting TFP growth rates in Business services to the market sector average. This highlights the need for better measurement of industry output. Similar considerations apply to Finance. 29

THE END 30

31

Questions considered in this paper Is the empirical evidence on TFP consistent with the causes that theory considers important? How important is each source of TFP growth, particularly the fifth? 32

The Domar sum d i GO GO VA i i i GDP VA i GDP GO VA N N i i d i 1 i i 1 VA i GDP So the Domar sum is a weighted average of the degree of outsourcing (GO/VA) in the economy. 33

Sum of Domar weights 3.500 AUS AUT BEL CZE DNK 3.000 2.500 2.000 3.500 ESP FIN FRA GER HUN 3.000 2.500 2.000 3.500 IRL ITA JPN NLD SVN 3.000 2.500 2.000 1970 1980 1990 20002007 1970 1980 1990 2000 2007 3.500 SWE UK USA 3.000 2.500 2.000 1970 1980 1990 2000 2007 1970 1980 1990 2000 2007 1970 1980 1990 2000 2007 Source: EU KLEMS. Note: Domar weights are for market sector GDP. Dashed lines denote country means. 34

Outsourcing in sectors D, E, F, G, H and I: unweighted cross-country means of GO/VA ratio 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1970 1980 1990 2000 2007 Source: EU KLEMS. D E F G H I 35

Persistence of TFP TFP growth is positively serially correlated at the aggregate (market sector) level but not at the industry level. This is a problem for theories which ascribe TFP growth to innovation: innovations take time to spread. 36

(Lack of) persistence in TFP growth Dependent variable is TFP growth 18 countries, 1970-2007 10 sectors Market sector TFP growth (lagged once) 0.0180 0.2310 *** (0.0280) (0.0549) Observations 4,450 425 R squared 0.057 0.325 Country and year dummies included; sector dummies included in 10 sectors regression. OLS estimates with robust standard errors. *** significant at 1% level. 37

Persistence of TFP TFP growth is positively serially correlated at the aggregate (market sector) level but not at the industry level. This is a problem for theories which ascribe TFP growth to innovation: innovations take time to spread. Explanation: there are errors in the measurement of industry nominal value added which cancel out in the aggregate. 38

g g v ijt ijt ijt ijt Errors-in-variables model : Measured TFP growth in j-th sector of i-th country in year t : True TFP growth : Measurement error : Value added share 1. g g Controls (Hypothesis) ijt ijt 1 ijt 2. g g, E ijt ijt ijt ijt ijt s N i 1 MS N it v j 1 ijt g ijt 0 (Measurement error) 3. v 0 (Errors cancel out in aggregate) ijt ijt 4. g (Aggregation to MS level) 39

Errors in variables model, cont. Then the regression equation g g Controls ijt ij, t 1 ijt has the classic errors-in-variables form: the independent variable is correlated with the error term, so the estimate of beta is biased towards zero. But there is no such bias if we run the regression at the aggregate (market sector) level: g g Controls MS MS MS it i, t 1 it 40

Where do the errors come from? The growth of industry value added is much more volatile than the growth of industry input (K and L). If the national accounts on the income/output side are balanced year-by-year using a control total from the expenditure side, this could lead to errors in industry-level nominal value added. Conclusion: TFP is probably persistent at the sector level too. 41

Mismeasurement of capital Mismeasurement of quality change Missing assets Increasing variety 42

Mismeasurement of quality change in capital goods At the aggregate level this may not matter much in large, rich countries. Reason: 1. GDP growth: Yˆ w Yˆ w Yˆ w ( w ) : shares of C ( I) in GDP C C I I C I 2. Aggregate TFP growth: w Yˆ w Yˆ Kˆ (1 ) Lˆ C C I I 3. Error in capital measurement: ˆ ˆ ˆ e K K K : true growth rate of K 4.Then assuming Yˆ Kˆ, TFP error = ( w ) e 0 if e 0 and > w I I I But at industry level or in an open economy importing high-tech capital goods, the error could be larger 43

44