Housing Market and Family Relations in a Welfare State

Similar documents
PF1.7: Intergenerational solidarity

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

FINANCIAL STABILITY (Extract and summary for the OECD WPFS 2011) D A N M A R K S N A T I O N A L B A N K

METHODOLOGICAL ISSUES IN POVERTY RESEARCH

Balancing informal and formal care: Perspectives of older users and family caregivers (Based on the OASIS Study)

Inheritances and Inequality across and within Generations

Savings, Consumption and Real Assets of the Elderly in Japan and the U.S. How the Existing-Home Market Can Boost Consumption

Households' economic well-being: the OECD dashboard Methodological note

Housing and Neoliberalism: Growing inequality in Australia

Inequality and Social Mobility. Econ 101

AGEING AND THE FINANCIAL BEHAVIOUR OF ELDERLY PEOPLE IN ROMANIA

Pension Reform, Population Ageing and Distributive Conflicts: Analysis of Age-Based Distributive Divisions in Six European Countries

Sustainable pensions and retirement schemes in Hong Kong

Mind the Generation Gap. Brewin Dolphin Family Wealth Report. Part 1 The Baby Boomers

Housing prices, household debt and household consumption. Inquiry into housing policies, labour force participation and economic growth PEER REVIEWED

Debt in Norwegian households within a life-cycle perspective: an analysis using household-level data

Home Ownership and use of Housing Capital 1

THE GROSS AND NET RATES OF REVENUES REPLACEMENT WITHIN THE RETIRING PENSIONS

Distributional Implications of the Welfare State

5 Social and Family Context

Universal Social Protection

Private monetary transfers and altruism: an empirical investigation on Italian families

Wealth and Welfare: Breaking the Generational Contract

Distributive Impact of Low-Income Support Measures in Japan

Intergenerational Transfers and Old-Age Security in Korea

Investment Company Institute and the Securities Industry Association. Equity Ownership

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Income Inequality Matters, but Mobility Is Just as Important. Daniel R. Carroll and Anne Chen

Sustainability and Adequacy of Social Security in the Next Quarter Century:

The Financial Literacy Initiative. Annamaria Lusardi (Dartmouth College andnber)

Two Cheers for Piketty

who needs care. Looking after grandchildren, however, has been associated in several studies with better health at follow up. Research has shown a str

Economic Life Cycle Deficit and Intergenerational Transfers in Italy: An Analysis Using National Transfer Accounts Methodology

Influence of demographic factors on the public pension spending

Wealth inequality: causes and consequences A project proposal

How the Financial Sector Could Fight The Increasing Generational Divide (1)

Differentials in pension prospects for minority ethnic groups in the UK

Economic Standard of Living

Dynamic Demographics and Economic Growth in Vietnam. Minh Thi Nguyen *

Demographics and Secular Stagnation Hypothesis in Europe

THIRD EDITION. ECONOMICS and. MICROECONOMICS Paul Krugman Robin Wells. Chapter 18. The Economics of the Welfare State

Poverty and Inequality Commission Priorities and Work Plan

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries

THE EVOLUTION OF SOCIAL INDICATORS DEVELOPED AT THE LEVEL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION AND THE NEED TO STIMULATE THE ACTIVITY OF SOCIAL ENTERPRISES

DYNAMIC DEMOGRAPHICS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN VIETNAM

What happens next? Contact. Website:

FEBRUARY Silver Spenders

Household Balance Sheets and Debt an International Country Study

The Future of Retirement Why family matters

DISPOSABLE INCOME INDEX

ANALYSIS OF PENSION REFORMS IN EU MEMBER STATES

AGE contribution to the European Commission s consultation on Europe s Social Reality : a stocktaking. 14 February 2008

Executive Summary. Chapter 2 - Intergenerational fairness and solidarity today and challenges ahead

Svein Gjedrem: Housing finance in Norway

The intergenerational divide in Europe. Guntram Wolff

Lifetime consumption smoothing

Exit Rate: Men Aged (cohort adjusted)

Measuring Sustainability in the UN System of Environmental-Economic Accounting

Lecture 10. Welfare State Expenditure ANDREEA STOIAN, PHD DEPARTMENT OF FINANCE AND CEFIMO

Key strategic issues for the wider social development sector

The Global Savings Gap

The Influence of Managers Characteristics on Risk Management Practices in Public Listed Companies (PLCs) Of Malaysia

Economic Activity Report

Economic Standard of Living

A brief commentary on József Banyár s OLG-paper*

CHAPTER 8 LONG-TERM CARE IN EUROPE

Intergenerational Solidarity in the 21st Century a Growing Challenge for Governments and NGOs

Øystein Olsen: The economic outlook

Age friendly goods and services an opportunity for social and economic development (Warsaw, October 2012)

Svein Gjedrem: The economic outlook in Norway

Consumption Inequality in Canada, Sam Norris and Krishna Pendakur

Living with austerity how is it affecting the better-off half of the 99%?

The evolving retirement landscape

151 Slater Street, Suite 710 Ottawa, Ontario K1P 5H , Fax

UNINTENDED CONSEQUENCES OF A GRANT REFORM: HOW THE ACTION PLAN FOR THE ELDERLY AFFECTED THE BUDGET DEFICIT AND SERVICES FOR THE YOUNG

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

The impact of an ageing world on our society and economy

Economics and Ethics of the Welfare State

ESTIMATING THE LIFE COURSE DYNAMICS OF ASSET POVERTY *

The Impact of Globalisation on Systems of Social Security

Egil Matsen: The equity share in the Government Pension Fund Global

For adviser use only not approved for use with clients. Aegon Adviser Attitudes Report A spotlight on advisers clients

Basic Income as a policy option: Can it add up?

Volume Title: The Economic Consequences of Demographic Change in East Asia, NBER-EASE Volume 19

Currently throughout the world most public

Pensions and Taxation in the EU

Dual Income Polarization by Age Groups in Korea:

Behavioral characteristics affecting household portfolio selection in Japan

Pensions for Women Presentation to Irish Women Lawyers Assocation 4th July 2009 Rachel Doyle NWCI Head of Outreach and Support

EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM

Università degli Studi di Roma Tor Vergata Facoltà di Economia Area Comunicazione, Stampa, Orientamento. Laudatio.

National Programme for Ageing Workers in Finland. Peer review: Sweden

Consumption, Income and Wealth

How s Life in France?

Preventing Early Exit from Labour Market Indicators. Sustainable Ageing Societies: Indicators for Effective Policy-Making

ENGLISH SUMMARY Chapter I: Economic Outlook

Baby Boomers and Housing Markets. Presentation by Clare Wall, SGS Associate 7 th National Housing Conference October 2012

Active Ageing. Fieldwork: September November Publication: January 2012

How large are the financial margins of Nor wegian households? An analysis of micro data for the period

Saving energy. by Per Hedberg and Sören Holmberg

Study on the Global Trends of Delay Retirement and Potential Demand in China

Transcription:

Housing Market and Family Relations in a Welfare State Lars Gulbrandsen (corresponding author) Researcher, Norwegian Social Research, Oslo and Akershus University College of Applied Sciences, Stensberggata 26, 0170 Oslo lars.gulbrandsen@hioa.nova.no Hans Christian Sandlie Researcher, Norwegian Social Research, Oslo and Akershus University College of Applied Sciences, Stensberggata 26, 0170 Oslo hans.c.sandlie@nova.hioa.no Abstract: One idea widespread in current discourse on the ageing population speaks of the intergenerational inequity between the elderly and the young. This assumption overlooks the extensive lifetime financial transfers from older to younger generations that occur within families. Housing wealth may reinforce inequalities over generations, but this wealth also provides an opportunity to assist offspring in entering the housing market. The increase in house prices in recent years has put parents in an even better position to provide financial support. Instead of following the distributional principles that guides redistribution within the welfare state, this distribution may reproduce or even increase social inequalities. Intergenerational inequalities in economic prosperity may therefore also lead to intragenerational inequalities between those who have parents that can help and those who do not. However, this type of inequality may strengthen rather than weaken family solidarity. Keywords: housing wealth; intergenerational transfers; family solidarity; social inequality. 74

Introduction Housing, with its dual capital-cum-service nature, has a special position within the welfare state (Fahey and Norris 2010). On the one hand, housing provides a service (accommodation) but, on the other hand, an owner-occupied dwelling is also a capital asset. As an asset, housing provides an important means of saving or allocating resources within the family. Facilitated through a growing number of financial products, housing wealth provides a welfare resource that can be accessible across different stages of the life course. Thus wealth accumulation through homeownership deserves more attention, as it represents an increasingly important source of economic wellbeing and prosperity and challenges the design of the traditional welfare state. Traditionally, the welfare state provides insurance against health risks and individual income risks, and the tax and social security system redistributes income, both over the individual s life course and between individuals at the same stage of the life course. While a significant part of the public transfers go from adult wage earners to the elderly, financial transfers within the family normally take the opposite direction from older to younger family members. Such family insurance may lead to greater inequality. Consequently, the growth of homeownership in many nations raises questions about the role of housing as an important welfare resource for its residents and the possibilities it offers for intergenerational transfers of financial resources within families. As a counterargument to the popular idea that today s elderly will spend their children s inheritance, our main argument is that the growing housing wealth has provided new opportunities for transfers between adult family generations and strengthened family relations. The increase in house prices in some countries, for instance Norway, has put parents in an even better position to provide financial support, but has at the same time increased their offspring s need for such support. Internationally, the size of yearly inheritance relative to national income has been rising in the recent past in many developed countries and is expected to rise further in the next decades (Piketty 2014). This has led to concerns that received inheritances may become a stronger determinant of life chances. Long periods of capital gain in the housing market may lead to substantial inheritances in the near future unless current and future elderly households behave egoistically and spend most of their accumulated housing wealth on themselves. In this paper we ask the simple questions: How will current and future generations of elderly deal with their housing wealth? Will they consume the capital on high days and holidays or transfer financial resources to their descendants? We will take Norway as the model case. A key goal of the Norwegian welfare state has been to secure homeownership for all. This has been achieved by regulation and by allowing mortgage-financed housing to be a tax-favoured asset in the income and wealth systems. We will start by giving a brief presentation of the development in Norwegian house prices in recent decades and then summarise how the literature on intergenerational relations and transfers can offer insight into the meaning of this wealth accumulation for family relationships and solidarity. Intergenerational inequity on the housing market In Norway, as in many other countries, increasing house prices have raised the profile of housing and housing wealth on the political agenda. There is an increasing amount of rhetoric devoted to the generational conflict between housing poor young people and the housing 75

1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 Volume 2 Issue 1 2015 74-81 rich middle aged and elderly. Despite the fact that homeownership has been promoted as a policy instrument to fight poverty and encourage social mobility, it may also play a central role in driving inequalities probably more so within than across generations. Consequently, there may be an increase in inequalities of access to homeownership and in benefits from ownership for both younger and older generations. In the past two decades or so house prices in Norway have been on the rise. Figure 1 shows the development in prices as reported by the Association of Real Estate Agents and for the last couple of years by Eiendom Norge (a Norwegian property broker). The chart shows the development both in nominal and real prices. We present the mean price for each year and in addition the mean price for the years when the prices turned. Over the past 20 years (from the low point in 1992), house prices in Norway have increased 5.5-fold in nominal prices and more than tripled in real prices. The global financial crises in 2008 and 2012 have so far had a very modest effect on the Norwegian housing market. Figures presented so far in 2014 indicate that house prices are still increasing. Figure 1: House price fluctuation in Norway (1985-2014). Price per square meter in NOK (1 Euro = approx. 8.50 NOK) 35000 30000 25000 20000 15000 10000 5000 0 Price per square meter Price in 1985 NOK The consequences of high and increasing house prices are that all homeowners become richer and richer while the threshold for first-home buyers continues to rise. One idea prevalent in current discourse on an ageing population speaks of the intergenerational inequity between old and young people (cf. Thane 2012). Older cohorts have had the opportunity to accumulate wealth, especially that which resides in the value of their homes, while the barriers to housing market entry have become higher and higher for today s youth. High and increasing wealth among the elderly has led to the assumption that they are seizing the resources for themselves. Instead of saving money as a form of family insurance against various types of negative shocks or leaving it to their children as a precautionary buffer, the expectation is that the elderly will expend the money on their own comfort and leisure. Accordingly, today s elderly are labelled the greediest generation. This assumption presents a risk of intergenerational conflict based on intergenerational inequality. An important premise, however, is that the 76

elderly will behave in an egoistic way. If they instead take care of the welfare of their younger descendants, the inequality may result in greater solidarity between the generations within each family. Crowding out family solidarity? The popularity of the idea of the elderly spending their children s inheritance is in many ways related to the crowding out hypothesis. This hypothesis predicts that generous welfare systems will not only reduce the actual exchanges of support within families but also undermine feelings of responsibility and solidarity between family members (Künemund and Rein (1999). In this context, housing wealth can be a supplementary pension. Both paying off one s mortgage and increasing house prices can create room for the adjustment of spending and consumption patterns. Assuming the existence of institutional arrangements able to turn such real assets into liquid assets, housing wealth may affect the homeowners economy, either by enabling people to spend more of their assets when house prices are rising or by inhibiting consumption when house prices are falling. The combination of substantial public pensions and growing housing wealth make it possible for the elderly to enjoy their postretirement life by consuming housing capital on high days and holidays. On this basis, we can ask the two following questions: Does the combination of high housing wealth and the provision of public pensions for the elderly crowd out family solidarity in general? Does increasing housing wealth also increase the willingness of the elderly to spend their money? Results from previous research lend little support to the crowding out hypothesis. On the contrary, these studies point to the opposite conclusions (Kohli 1999; Attias-Donfut and Wolff 2000; Kohli et al 2000; Attias-Donfut et.al. 2005): Transfers between adult generations in the family still occur, and both practical and financial resources flow from the elderly to their adult children. Furthermore, this family support has been stimulated and empowered by welfare state provisions. Public pension incomes and health coverage are what make it possible for elderly parents to provide their adult descendants with financial support. Therefore, these intergenerational resource flows in the family in many ways depend on and are crowded in by public support (Künemund and Rein 1999; Albertini et al 2007). On the second question, previous research also shows little evidence in support of the assumption that the elderly are spending their housing wealth on comfort and leisure. In the UK, Smith and Searle (2008) found a large increase in the number of people who were remortgaging or taking further advances against an existing mortgage account. They found a strong inclination among respondents to reinvest their extracted housing equity in their homes. Grouped together, home improvements and home extensions were still the reasons most often mentioned for equity extraction, clearly ahead of other specified reasons. Respondents less often mentioned the desire to purchase cars and other consumer goods as reasons. Therefore, depleting housing wealth on high days and holidays seems to be the exception rather than the rule. This is consistent with the findings of Lauridsen and Skak (2009) concerning middle-aged and elderly citizens in ten EU countries. They found that the rate of mortgage to house value was very low; it was only above ten in Sweden and the Netherlands and was close to zero in Southern Europe. Haffner (2008) has concluded that for the elderly in the Netherlands housing wealth still functions as unused savings. In Norway, the banks quite often offer flexible loan arrangements that allow elderly homeowners gradually to consume substantial parts of their housing wealth. In the past few 77

years a steadily increasing proportion of Norwegian homeowners have taken the opportunity to borrow money with their net housing capital as collateral (Gulbrandsen and Sandlie 2014). Like other international studies, we observe no change in their attitudes as regards egoistic spending. In keeping with the crowding in hypothesis, we find that the middle aged and elderly use some of the banks financial products to help their children and grandchildren in becoming homeowners. The private pillar of the generational contract The generational contract is a crucial dimension of contemporary European welfare systems: protecting the old and investing in the young within a balance between financial sustainability and the principles of social justice and fairness (Albertini et al. 2007). This contract has both a public (state- and market-provided) and a private (family) dimension, and it is important to know how these two dimensions interact. Based on the recent trend where the distribution of housing is less regulated by the state and more dependent on the market, it seems reasonable to ask the questions (cf. Kohli et al 2010): Can intergenerational family support compensate for the retreat of the welfare state and act as informal insurance against life-course risks? Can intergenerational support from parents to their adult children help the latter to enter the housing market (e.g. through financial support)? The simple answer to these questions is yes. In response to harsh market conditions, parents may, for example, donate wealth to children to facilitate a home purchase (Cirman 2008). There is empirical support for this in the Norwegian case. As shown in Figure 1, Norwegian house prices have been increasing since the start of the 1990s. However, the rate of home ownership among young families has not decreased in this period. At first sight this is something of a surprise. Alongside the increase in house prices, the housing finance system has become more rigorous in recent years. The award criteria for a public start-up loan are more stringent, and the Financial Supervisory Authority of Norway has introduced new rules for equity in connection with house purchases. These rules prevent banks from financing more than 80% of the purchase price. In the absence of personal savings, buyers have to raise money through other channels. It seems that the family functions as such a source of support. Table 1 shows the results from six nationwide surveys in which Norstat on behalf of Finance Norway asked homeowners below the age of 40 if they had received any financial support from other family members. As we can see, the tendency is a strong increase in the receipt of family support for home purchase. Table 1: Percentage of young people who received financial assistance from the family in connection with house purchase - homeowners under 40 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 24 % 15 % 21 % 29 % 35 % 41 % Source: Norstat on behalf of Finance Norway. These surveys from Finance Norway also contain questions on the type of financial assistance young people have received. The most common type of assistance was that the family had provided surety for the mortgage. In 2013, a slight majority of those who had received assistance mentioned this type of support. This type of support has also been increasing since 2008. Almost one-third had received an advance on their inheritance. About one-fifth had given a younger family member a loan, while one in ten of the donors had taken out a loan in 78

their own name. One-fifth had received an amount of money, while one in ten had received help to cover the running costs of housing and living. Providing assistance to strengthen a young person s position in the credit market is rather more common than direct financial support. Instead of spending their housing wealth on themselves, it seems more frequently to be the case that the elderly use this capital as a kind of family insurance, both as a precaution against negative shocks and as an opportunity to carry out home improvements and home extensions, but also to support children and grandchildren embarking on homeownership. This form of family insurance can provide effective protection against general inequalities in the housing market, and it may be more effective than social insurance provided by the welfare state since families have more exact information about the needs to be met. Conclusion The background to this paper is the vast increase in house prices seen over the past couple of decades. For homeowners, the increase in house prices implies massive growth in housing wealth. An important question in the wake of this development is how current and future generations will deal with their wealth in retirement. In this paper, we have discussed how middle-aged and elderly homeowners dispose of their housing wealth. In contrast to popular descriptions of the elderly as selfish and greedy, we argue that intergenerational transfers in the family remain widespread and substantial. The combination of increasing house prices and substantial public pensions makes it possible for the elderly to use their housing wealth as a family insurance against negative shocks or to support descendants in embarking on homeownership. This may have implications not only for family solidarity as such, how the family distributes its resources among and assures the wellbeing of its members, but also for the broader issues of social policy, social inequality, and social integration (Attias-Donfut 1995 in Kohli 1999). Intergenerational transfers challenge the design of the traditional welfare state. Public transfers may increase the possibilities for private intergenerational transfers. However, private transfers often flow in the opposite direction to public transfers. Private transfers will potentially lead to social inequality, and received family support may become a stronger determinant of life chances. In recent years, economic development in the Nordic welfare state and Norway has been quite unlike the rest of Europe. The impact of the crisis has been less marked in the Nordic region than in the rest of Europe. However, we believe that family solidarity and support will be important independently of economic conditions. The role of family support has always been important in Southern Europe, not least in housing. The financial crisis has not changed this. On the contrary, the impact and importance of family support has probably increased during the crisis. The same appears to be the case in countries with more favourable economic conditions. A consequence of economic growth is increasing house prices and increased inequality between generations. Increasing housing wealth has provided greater opportunity to support descendants while increasing house prices have amplified the need for such assistance. On this basis, growth in the national economy also increases the importance of the family and family support. 79

References Arber, S., C. Attias-Donfut, 2000. The Myth of Generational Conflict. The Family and State in Ageing Societies. London and New York: Routledge. Albertini, M., C. Kohli, C. Vogel 2007. Intergenerational Transfers of Time and Money in European Families: Common Patterns Different Regimes? Journal of European Social Policy 17 (4): 319-333. DOI: 10.1177/0958928707081068. Attias-Donfut, C., J. Ogg, F. C. Wolff 2005. European Patterns of Intergenerational Financial and Time Transfers. European Journal of Ageing 2 (3): 161-173. DOI: 10.1007/s10433-005- 0008-7. Attias-Donfut, C., F. C. Wolff 2000. Complementarity between private and public transfers. Pp. 47-68 in S. Arber, C. Attias-Donfut (eds.) The Myth of Generational Conflict. The Family and State in Aging Societies. New York: Routledge. Cirman, A. 2008. Intergenerational Transfers as a Response to Changes in the Housing Market in Slovenia. European Journal of Housing Policy 8 (3): 303-315. DOI: 10.1080/14616710802256710. Fahey, T., M. Norris 2010. Housing Pp. 479-493 in F. G. Castles, S. Leibfried, J. Lewis, H. Orbinger, C. Pierson (eds.) The Oxford Handbook of The Welfare State. Oxford University Press. Gulbrandsen, L., H. C. Sandlie 2014. Intergenerational Solidarity and Transfers in a Country Being Rich and Representing the Scandinavian Model. Paper presented at the XVIII ISA World Congress of Sociology, RC43 Housing and Built Environment, Yokohama, Japan, 13-19 July 2014. Haffner, M. E. A. 2008. Savings for Old Age? Housing Wealth of the Dutch Elderly Housing, Theory and Society 25 (2): 110-131. DOI: 10.1080/14036090701547564. Kohli, M. 1999. Private and Public Transfers between Generations. Linking the Family and the State. European Societies 1 (1): 91-104. DOI: 10.1080/14036090701547564. Kohli, M., H. Künemund, A. Motel, M. Szydlik 2000. Families Apart? Intergenerational Transfers in East and West Germany. Pp. 88-99 in S. Arber, C. Attias-Donfut, (eds.) The Myth of Generational Conflict. The family and state in ageing societies. London and New York: Routledge. Kohli, M., H. Künemund 2003. Intergenerational Transfers in the Family: What Motivates Giving? Pp. 123-142 in V. L. Bengtson, A. Lowenstein (Eds.) Global Aging and Challenges to Families. New York. Aldine de Greuyter. Kohli, M., M. Albertini, H. Künemund 2010. Linkages Among Adult Family Generations: Evidence from Comparative Survey Research in P. Heady, M. Kohli, (eds.) Family, Kinship and State in Contemporary Europe. Vol. 3. Frankfurt: M Campus. 80

Künemund, H., M. Rein 1999. There is More to Receiving than Needing: Theoretical Arguments and Empirical Explorations of Crowding in and Crowding out. Ageing and Society, 19 (1): 93 121. Lauridsen, J., M. Skak 2009. Demographic Change and Housing Wealth. Workpackage 1. Deliverable No. 8. University of Southern Denmark. Piketty, T. 2014 Capital in the Twenty-First Century. The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. Smith, S. J., B. A. Searle 2008. Dematerialising Money? Observations on the Flow of Wealth from Housing to Other Things. Housing Studies 23 (1): 21-43. DOI: 10.1080/02673030701731225. Thane, P. 2012 Demographic futures: Addressing Inequality and Diversity among Older People. A Report prepared for The British Academy. Policy Centre. 81