The demand for health insurance in a multirisk context

Similar documents
MORAL HAZARD AND BACKGROUND RISK IN COMPETITIVE INSURANCE MARKETS: THE DISCRETE EFFORT CASE. James A. Ligon * University of Alabama.

Liability, Insurance and the Incentive to Obtain Information About Risk. Vickie Bajtelsmit * Colorado State University

A note on health insurance under ex post moral hazard

BACKGROUND RISK IN THE PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL. James A. Ligon * University of Alabama. and. Paul D. Thistle University of Nevada Las Vegas

STX FACULTY WORKING PAPER NO Risk Aversion and the Purchase of Risky Insurance. Harris Schlesinger

Optimal Tax Base with Administrative fixed Costs

Standard Risk Aversion and Efficient Risk Sharing

A Theory of Regret and Information

The relevance and the limits of the Arrow-Lind Theorem. Luc Baumstark University of Lyon. Christian Gollier Toulouse School of Economics.

Academic Editor: Emiliano A. Valdez, Albert Cohen and Nick Costanzino

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Mossin s Theorem for Upper-Limit Insurance Policies

The Probationary Period as a Screening Device: The Monopolistic Insurer

Correlation Aversion and Insurance Demand

Problem Set 2. Theory of Banking - Academic Year Maria Bachelet March 2, 2017

Precautionary Insurance Demand with State-Dependent. Background Risk

Answer: Let y 2 denote rm 2 s output of food and L 2 denote rm 2 s labor input (so

Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem

Elasticity of risk aversion and international trade

Inflation Risk, Hedging, and Exports

Citation Economic Modelling, 2014, v. 36, p

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Background Risk, Demand for Insurance, and Choquet Expected Utility Preferences

ECON 581. Decision making under risk. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Slides III - Complete Markets

Forward Dynamic Utility

Export and Hedging Decisions under Correlated. Revenue and Exchange Rate Risk

Reinsurance Contracting with Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard: Theory and Evidence

The Theory of Insurance Demand

Section 9, Chapter 2 Moral Hazard and Insurance

Drug launch timing and international reference pricing

Prevention in Insurance Markets 1

Auctions That Implement Efficient Investments

Risk-Taking Behavior with Limited Liability and Risk Aversion

The Spillover Effect of Compulsory Insurance

Financial Economics: Risk Aversion and Investment Decisions

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Why do French firms hold cash? Pourquoi les entreprises françaises détiennent-elles de la trésorerie?

EU i (x i ) = p(s)u i (x i (s)),

USING PARTICIPATING AND FINANCIAL CONTRACTS TO INSURE CATASTROPHE

EconS Micro Theory I Recitation #8b - Uncertainty II

IS TAX SHARING OPTIMAL? AN ANALYSIS IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT FRAMEWORK

A Note on Health Insurance under Ex Post Moral Hazard

Citation for published version (APA): Oosterhof, C. M. (2006). Essays on corporate risk management and optimal hedging s.n.

WAGES, EMPLOYMENT AND FUTURES MARKETS. Ariane Breitfelder. Udo Broll. Kit Pong Wong

Advanced Financial Economics Homework 2 Due on April 14th before class

A Note on the Relation between Risk Aversion, Intertemporal Substitution and Timing of the Resolution of Uncertainty

market opportunity line fair odds line Example 6.6, p. 120.

A note on strategic piracy in the economics of software: an explanation by learning costs

The impact of commitment on nonrenewable resources management with asymmetric information on costs

Insurance and Monopoly Power in a Mixed Private/Public Hospital System. Donald J. Wright

The Production of Goods in Excess of Demand: A Generalization of Self-Protection

Hedonic Equilibrium. December 1, 2011

Mistakes, Negligence and Liabilty. Vickie Bajtelsmit * Colorado State University. Paul Thistle University of Nevada Las Vegas.

PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION AND SHARPE RATIO BASED ON COPULA APPROACH

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

General Equilibrium under Uncertainty

Risk Management Determinants Affecting Firms' Values in the Gold Mining Industry: New Empirical Results

Loss-leader pricing and upgrades

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

Uberrimae Fidei and Adverse Selection: the equitable legal judgment of Insurance Contracts

CEREC, Facultés universitaires Saint Louis. Abstract

First-Order (Conditional) Risk Aversion, Backround Risk and Risk Diversification

Some Simple Analytics of the Taxation of Banks as Corporations

Arrow s theorem of the deductible: moral hazard and stop-loss in health insurance

Andreas Wagener University of Vienna. Abstract

Consumer Theory. The consumer s problem: budget set, interior and corner solutions.

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

Wage bargaining with non-stationary preferences under strike decision

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Mechanisms for House Allocation with Existing Tenants under Dichotomous Preferences

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Adverse Selection When Agents Envy Their Principal. KANGSIK CHOI June 7, 2004

Legal Errors and Liability Insurance. Vickie Bajtelsmit Colorado State University. and. Paul D. Thistle * University of Nevada Las Vegas

Portfolio Selection with Quadratic Utility Revisited

Prudence, risk measures and the Optimized Certainty Equivalent: a note

A Preference Foundation for Fehr and Schmidt s Model. of Inequity Aversion 1

Application of large deviation methods to the pricing of index options in finance. Méthodes de grandes déviations et pricing d options sur indice

Introduction to game theory LECTURE 2

A new model of mergers and innovation

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5. Property Rights Theory. The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights?

JEFF MACKIE-MASON. x is a random variable with prior distrib known to both principal and agent, and the distribution depends on agent effort e

Micro Theory I Assignment #5 - Answer key

Midterm 1, Financial Economics February 15, 2010

On Monopoly Insurance Pricing when Agents Differ in Risk Aversion

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

Overall Excess Burden Minimization from a Mathematical Perspective Kong JUN 1,a,*

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 9. Demand for Insurance

WORKING PAPER SERIES 2011-ECO-05

A Newsvendor Model with Initial Inventory and Two Salvage Opportunities

OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY. WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics

A Newsvendor Model with Initial Inventory and Two Salvage Opportunities

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

Explaining Insurance Policy Provisions via Adverse Selection

Risk Management Determinants Affecting Firms' Values in the Gold Mining Industry: New Empirical Results

Transcription:

GATE Groupe d Analyse et de Théorie Économique MR 584 du CNR DOCMENT DE TRAVAI - WORKING PAPER W.P. 05-04 The demand for health insurance in a multirisk context Mohamed Anouar Razgallah Mai 005 GATE Groupe d Analyse et de Théorie Économique MR 584 du CNR 9 chemin des Mouilles 690 Écully France B.P. 67 69 Écully Cedex Tél. + (0)4 7 86 60 60 Fax + (0)4 7 86 60 90 Messagerie électronique gate@gate.cnrs.fr erveur Web : www.gate.cnrs.fr

The demand for health insurance in a multirisk context a demande d assurance santé dans un contexte multirisque Mohamed Anouar Razgallah GATE niversity of yon Mai 005 Abstract sing a model of bivariate decision under risk, we analyse the health insurance demand when there are two sources of risk: a health risk and an uninsurable one. We examine how the uninsurable risk affects the coverage of the health risk. We show that the determinants of the demand for health insurance are not only the correlation between the health and uninsurable risks as shown by Doherty and chlesinger (98a) and the variation of the marginal utility of wealth with respect to the health status (Rey, 00) but also the way in which the occurrence of the uninsurable risk affects the marginal utility of wealth. Résumé En utilisant un modèle bivarié de décision dans le risque, nous analysons la demande d assurance santé dans un contexte où un individu fait face à deux risques de nature différente : un risque de santé et un risque non assurable. Nous examinons l impact d un risque non assurable sur la couverture du risque de santé. Nous montrons que les principaux déterminants de la demande d assurance santé sont non seulement la corrélation entre le risque de santé et le risque non assurable comme l ont montré Doherty et chlesinger (98a) et l utilité marginale de la richesse en fonction de l état de santé (Rey, 00) mais aussi la manière dont la réalisation du risque non assurable affecte l utilité marginale de la richesse. Mots clés : risques corrélés, assurance santé, utilité contingente Keywords: Correlated risks, Health insurance, tate-dependent utility JE CAIFICATION: D8, I, I8 razgallah@gate.cnrs.fr Groupe d Analyse et de Théorie Economique,MR 584 D cnrs 9, chemin des mouilles, 690 Ecully - France I am grateful for the helpful comments and suggestions given by aurent Flochel. I am also grateful to Florence Goffette-Nagot for very useful comments.

Introduction The analysis of the optimal health insurance was strongly influenced by three propositions. The first proposition is the Bernoulli principle. It states that risk-averse agents will choose full coverage when the premium is actuarially fair. The second proposition derives from by Mossin-mith (968). In their pioneering paper, Mossin-mith (968) showed that if the premium for insurance is loaded, the individual chooses less than full insurance. The third proposition is proposed by Arrow (96). It states that a risk-averse agent will prefer a franchise contract to a coinsurance contract. Doherty and chlesinger (98a) show, in the presence of an uninsurable financial risk, that sufficient conditions for the validity of these propositions depend on the correlation between insurable and uninsurable risks. However, Doherty and chlesinger (98a) use a oneargument utility function. Rey (00) takes into account this limit by using a bivariate utility function. he shows that the determinants of the demand for health insurance are not only the correlation between the health and uninsurable risks but also the variation of the marginal utility of wealth with respect to the health status. However, Rey (00) imposes restrictive assumptions on the health risk. he assumes that illness is characterized only by a decrease in health status. However, since there exist curative cares, which are costly for individuals, the health risk induces both a loss in the health status and a financial loss. This paper extents the result obtained by Rey (00) to this framework. We also consider an uninsurable risk (For example an accident risk). The aim of this paper is to examine how the uninsurable risk affects the coverage of the health risk. We show that the optimal health insurance depends crucially on the way in which the occurrence of the uninsurable risk affects the marginal utility of wealth. The organization of this article is as follows. The next section introduces the model. The section that follows examines the optimal coinsurance contracts. ection 4 analyses the optimal insurance policy. The last section concludes. The model We consider an individual who derives utility from wealth W and from its health stock H. We use a Von Neumann Morgenstern two-arguments utility function (W,H). We assume for

standard concavity assumptions: > 0, > 0, < 0, < 0 and ( ) > 0. We don t impose any restriction on the sign of, the cross second derivative of. The agent has an initial health stock H 0, an initial wealth stock W 0 and he becomes ill with a probability. The disease implies a health loss D. In case of disease, there exist exogenous p curative cares at cost c for the individual. With a probability p, the agent faces an uninsurable loss. We denote V(W,H) the utility function when the uninsurable loss occurs, with V(W,H) < (W,H). Indeed, the realisation of the uninsurable loss always decreases the utility of wealth and health for risk-averse preferences (Cook and Graham (977)). We assume for V standard assumptions: V > 0, V > 0, V < 0, V < 0 and V V (V ) > 0. We don t impose any restriction on the sign of the variation of the marginal utility of wealth with respect to the uninsurable loss. Three cases are possible. - The occurrence of the uninsurable loss may leave the individual s marginal utility of wealth unchanged: (W,H) = V (W,H). In this case, the uninsurable loss does not effect the wealth uncertainty. - The occurrence of the uninsurable loss may increase the individual s marginal utility of wealth: (W,H) < V (W,H). In this case, the uninsurable loss plays as a hedge against wealth uncertainty. - The occurrence of the uninsurable loss may decrease the individual s marginal utility of wealth: (W,H) > V (W,H). In this case, the uninsurable loss plays as an amplifier of wealth uncertainty.

Optimal Coinsurance Contracts To examine the optimal coinsurance contracts 4, we consider a coinsurance health contract in which the insurance reimburses c of the expense in health care. The premium for insurance level is ) p P = ( + m c, where m is the loading factor, m 0. Four states of nature can appear. tility levels and probabilities of occurrence are characterized as follows. tate : (W 0 - P ( ) tate : (W 0 - P( )- ( ) tate : V (W 0 - P ( ) tate 4: V(W 0 - P( )- ( ), H 0 ) no loss occurs c, H0 - D + ) only the insurable loss occurs, H 0 ) only the uninsurable loss occurs c, H0 - D + ) the two loss occurs. We note Π the probability of occurrence of state i (i =.4). i They are defined as follows: Π = - - + p p p p / p p / Π = ( - ) Π = - p p p / Π 4 = p p / Where (resp. ) denotes the probability of occurrence of the insurable (resp. uninsurable) p p loss and p / the conditional probability of the uninsurable loss given the insurable loss. We don t impose restriction on the correlation between the losses. The tree cases are possible: the insurable loss and the uninsurable loss are independent ( = ), the insurable loss and the uninsurable loss are positively correlated ( < ) and the insurable loss and the uninsurable loss are negatively correlated ( > ). p p p / p / The optimal level of insurance is solution of the following program: max ( ) Π 0 - ( ) E = (W + V(W Π 0 - ( ) P, H 0 ) + P, H 0 ) + V(W 4 p p / Π (W 0 - P( )- ( ) Π 0 - P( )- ( ) c, H 0 - D + ) c, H 0 - D + ) () 4 The optimal coinsurance contracts is the individual s optimal insurance demand for given health expenditures. 4

First order condition writes 5 : ( ) E ' = c [ Z (W, H 0 - + ) ( - Where: D ( + m) p ) - ( - ) + m Z (W, H 0 ) ] + p ( p / - ) c { ( + m) p [F(W, H 0 - D + )- F(W, H 0 )] W = W 0 - P ( ) et W = W 0 - P( )- ( ) c - F (W, H 0 - D + )} (6) Z(W, H) = ( - ) (W, H) + p V(W, H) p F(W,H) = (W, H) - V(W, H). To examine the optimal coinsurance contracts, we consider in turn two situations: the situation where the premium is actuarially fair ( m = 0) and the situation where the premium is loaded ( m > 0).. The premium is actuarially fair In this section, we examine optimal coinsurance contracts where the premium is actuarially fair ( m = 0). The actuarially fair insurance premium is such premium when the expected loss of the insurance company equals exactly the revenue from insurance premium. Two situations are possible: the situation where the individual treats himself perfectly ( = D ) and the situation where he does not ( < D ). Firstly, let us consider the case where the individual treats himself perfectly ( = D ). If the premium for insurance is actuarially fair then equation (6) may be written as: ( ) E ' = c ( - p ) [ Z(W, H 0 - D + ) - Z(W, H 0 ) ] + ( - ) { p [F(W, H 0 - D + )- F(W, H 0 )] p p / c - F (W, H 0 - D + )} (8) From equation (8), we obtain in the case where the individual treats himself perfectly ( = D ): 5 see proof developped in Appendix. 5

Proposition (Complete curing) If the premium for insurance is actuarially fair ( m = 0), the individual chooses full insurance ( = ) if one of the following conditions is true: p / - The insurable loss and the uninsurable loss are positively correlated ( > p ) and the occurrence of the uninsurable loss increases the individual s marginal utility of wealth ( < V ). p / - The insurable loss and the uninsurable loss are negatively correlated ( < p ) and the occurrence of the uninsurable loss decreases the individual s marginal utility of wealth ( > V ). Proof. ee appendix.. et us now turn to the case where the individual doesn t treat himself perfectly ( < D ). We obtain: Proposition (Partial curing) If the premium for insurance is actuarially fair ( m = 0), the individual chooses full insurance ( = ) if one of the following conditions is true: - The insurable loss and the uninsurable loss are independent ( > p ) and the cross derivative of is negative or null ( 0). p / p / - The insurable loss and the uninsurable loss are positively correlated ( > p ), the cross derivative of is negative or null ( 0) and the occurrence of the uninsurable loss increases the individual s marginal utility of wealth ( < V ). p / - The insurable loss and the uninsurable loss are negatively correlated ( < p ), the cross derivative of is negative or null ( 0) and the occurrence of the uninsurable loss decreases the individual s marginal utility of wealth ( > V ). Proof. ee appendix.. The positive sign of the cross derivative of ( > 0) means that the marginal utility of the composite material good (W) increases with health status (H) and reciprocally. Rey (00) obtains that when the insurable and the uninsurable risks are negatively correlated and < 0, full coverage is optimal if the premium is actuarially fair. We show that this result is true if the occurrence of the uninsurable loss increases the individual s marginal utility of 6

wealth. The sign of the variation of the marginal utility of wealth with respect to the uninsurable loss is crucial when studying individual s optimal insurance demand.. The premium is loaded In this section we examine the individual s optimal insurance demand when the premium for insurance is loaded ( m > 0). Firstly, let us consider the case where the individual treats himself perfectly ( = D ). We obtain: Proposition (Complete curing) If the premium for insurance is loaded ( m > 0), the individual chooses less than full insurance ( < ) if one of the following conditions is true: - p / = p p / - The insurable loss and the uninsurable loss are positively correlated ( > p ) and the occurrence of the uninsurable loss decreases the individual s marginal utility of wealth ( > V ). p / - The insurable loss and the uninsurable loss are negatively correlated ( < p ) and the occurrence of the uninsurable loss increases the individual s marginal utility of wealth ( < V ). Proof. ee appendix.. et us now turn to the case where the individual doesn t treats himself perfectly ( < D ). We obtain: Proposition 4 (Partial curing) If the premium for insurance is loaded ( m > 0), the individual chooses less than full insurance ( < ) if one of the following conditions is true: p / - = p and 0 p / - > p, 0, > V and > V p / - < p, < 0, < V and < V. Proof. ee appendix.4. Contrary to Rey (00), the determinants of the demand for health insurance depend not only on the correlation between the insurable and the uninsurable losses risks and the variation of 7

the marginal utility of wealth with respect to the health status, but also on the way in which the occurrence of the uninsurable risk affects the marginal utility of wealth. 4 Optimal Insurance Policy The Arrow theorem states that a risk-averse agent will prefer a franchise contract to a coinsurance contract. To examine the validity of this theorem to our framework, we extent our previous model to the case where the individual faces three losses: - a small health loss - a large health loss - an uninsurable loss We define six states of nature. tility levels and probabilities of occurrence are characterized as follows: tate : (W 0, H 0 ). No loss occurs. tate : (W 0 - c ), H0 - D + ). Only the insurable small health loss occurs. ( ( ) tate : (W 0 - c, H0 - D + ). Only the insurable large health loss occurs tate 4: V(W 0, H 0 ). Only the uninsurable loss occurs. tate 5: V(W 0 - c( ), H0 -D + ). The uninsurable and the insurable small health losses occurs. tate 6: V(W 0 - c( ), H0 -D + ). The uninsurable and the insurable large health losses occurs. We note Π the probability of occurrence of state i (i =.6). i They are defined as follows: Π = - p - - p + p + Π = p - p p p / p / p p / Π = p - p p / Π = p - p - 4 p / p p / Π 5 = p p / Π 6 = p p / Where p and p denotes the probabilities of and, respectively. 8

We consider two insurance policies defined as follows: Franchise contract c F = 0 ( )-c in states and 6 otherwise F is a deductible policy with deductible level c ( ). Coinsurance contract c C = c 0 ( ) ( ) + ( - f )[ c( ) c( )] C is a proportional basis policy. in states and 5 in states and 6 in statesand 4 However, coinsurance and franchise contracts are available at the same premium. We obtain: P = with f c ( p + ) + (- ( ) = c p f ( )) [ c - c( ) + p c p 6. c ] = [ c - c ] p. The optimal level of coinsurance is solution of the following program: = arg max ( ) E = Π (W 0 - P, H 0 ) + p + Π (W0 - P - p + Π V(W 4 0- P, H 0 ) + Π V(W First order condition writes: ( ) c Π E ' = (W p - p Π (W 0 - P - ( ) 5 0 - P - ( ) ( ) c, H 0 - D + ) c, H 0 - D + ) c, H 0 - D + ) p + Π 6 V(W0 - P - c( )-, H 0 - D + ) (5) p 0 - P - ( ) c( ) Π (W Π c 0 - P - ( ) + V (W 5 c, H 0 - D + ) 0 - P - p c ( ) p, H 0 - D + ) c, H 0 - D + ) + Π 6 p p c ( ) V (W 0 - P - p c( ) p -, H 0 - D + ) (6) 6 see proof developped in Appendix. 9

Proposition 5 The Arrow theorem only holds when one of the following conditions is true: - = V - = V = 0 - < 0 and V > 0 Proof. ee appendix 4. Proposition 5 shows the importance of the knowledge of the way in which the occurrence of the uninsurable risk affects the marginal utility of wealth to determine the optimal insurance policy. 5 CONCION In this article, we view health insurance as a combined hedge against the two consequences of falling ill: treatment expenditures and loss in health status. We use a bivariate utility function depending both on the wealth and health. We don t impose any restriction on the sign of the variation of the marginal utility of wealth with respect to the uninsurable loss. We have shown that it is difficult to obtain classical results of insurance theory in the health case. We have concluded that the determinants of the demand for health insurance are not only the correlation between the health and uninsurable risks and the variation of the marginal utility of wealth with respect to the health status but also the way in which the occurrence of the uninsurable risk affects the marginal utility of wealth. Appendix Appendix The optimal level of insurance is solution of the following program: max ( ) Π 0 - ( ) E = (W + V(W Π 0 - ( ) P, H 0 ) + P, H 0 ) + V(W Where: P ( ) = ( + m ) p 4 Π (W 0 - P( )- ( ) Π 0 - P( )- ( ) c denote the premium for insurance. c, H 0 - D + ) c, H 0 - D + ) () 0

Replacing the probabilities by their expressions, equation () writes as follows: E = { [( - ) (W p + V(W p p / p 0 - P( )- ( ) p 0 - P( )- ( ) + ( - )[( - ) (W p + { ( - ) [(W p 0 - ( ) c, H 0 - D + ) c, H 0 - D + )] p 0 - ( ) P, H 0 ) + V(W P, H 0 )]} p 0 - P ( ), H 0 )- V(W 0 - P ( ), H 0 ) - (W 0 - P( )- ( ) + V(W 0 - P( )- ( ) c, H 0 - D + ) c, H 0 - D + )]} () Or in a more compact form: ( ) E = { Z(W Where: p 0 - P( )- ( ) p p / +{ ( - )[F(W c, H0 - D + ) + ( - ) Z(W p 0 - ( ) p 0 - P ( ), H 0 )- F(W 0 - P( )- ( ) P, H 0 )} c, H 0 - D + )]} () Z(W, H) = ( - ) (W, H) + p V(W, H) p p / p p / A(,W,H) = ( - ) [(W p 0 - P ( ), H 0 )- V(W 0 - ( ) - (W 0 - P( )- ( ) + V(W 0 - P( )- ( ) P, H 0 ) c, H 0 - D + ) c, H 0 - D + )] F(W,H) = (W, H) - V(W, H). Consequently, the optimal level of insurance is solution of the following program: = arg max ( ) E = { Z(W p 0 - P( )- ( ) + ( - ) Z(W p 0 - ( ) p p / + { ( - )[F(W P,H 0 )} c, H 0 - D + ) p 0 - P ( ), H 0 )- F(W 0 - P( )- ( ) c, H0 - D + )]} (4) First order condition writes: ( ) E ' = c [ (W p p / Z 0 - P( )- ( ) - ( - p ) ( + m) (W + ( - ) { + m [F c D ( + m) c, H 0 - + ) ( - Z 0 - ( ) P, H 0 )] p (W 0 - P( )- ( ) - c F(W 0 - P( )- ( ) ) p D (W 0 - ( ) c, H 0 - + )- F c, H 0 - D + )} (5) P, H 0 )]

Equation (5) can be written as follows: ( ) E ' = c [ Z (W, H 0 - + ) ( - p p / D ( + m) + ( - ) { + m p [F(W, H 0 - + )- F p ( ) c Where: W = W 0 - P ( ) et W = W 0 - P( )- ( ) c p ) - ( - ) + m Z (W, H 0 ) ] D (W, H 0 )]- c F (W, H 0 - D + )} (6) econd order condition writes: ( ) E '' = { Π ( + m) p ( c ) (W 0 - ( ) P, H 0 ) + Π ( ) c [ ( + m) p ] (W 0 - P( )- ( ) Π ( + ) ( p ) ( c ) (W 0 - ( ) + m V + + m p V 4 P, H 0 ) Π ( c ) [ ] (W 0 - P( )- ( ) c, H 0 - D + ) c, H 0 - D + )} < 0 (7) The second order condition is satisfied because ''( ) E is always negative. Appendix Appendix. The strict concavity of the first-order condition for maximizing () = E' 0. () E ' writes: () E ensures that full coverage is optimal ( = ) if and only if E ( ) evaluated at full coverage is nonnegative: E ' = - p ( p / - ) c [(W 0 - c, H 0 )- V (W 0 - c, H 0 )] (9) If = p then < p / If > p then p / =if <if < V > V If < p then p / =if <if > V < V

Appendix. The strict concavity of the first-order condition for maximizing () = E' 0. () E ' writes: () E ensures that full coverage is optimal ( = ) if and only if E ( ) evaluated at full coverage is nonnegative: E ' = ( - p ) c [ Z (W0 - c, H 0 - D + ) - Z( W0 - c, H 0 ) ] - p ( p / - ) c [(- p ) F(W 0 - c, H 0 - D + ) + p F(W 0 - c, H0)] (0) However, the sign of is equal to the sign of Z. From the equation (0), we obtain: If = p then p / =if < if 0 > 0 If > p then p / =if <if 0 and > 0 and < V > V If < p then p / =if <if 0 and > 0 and > V < V Appendix. The strict concavity of the first-order condition for maximizing () = E' 0. () E ' writes: () E ensures that full coverage is optimal ( = ) if and only if E ( ) evaluated at full coverage is nonnegative: E ' = - [ m Z (W0 - c, H0 ) + p ( p / - ) c F (W 0 - c, H 0 )] () From the equation (0), we obtain:

If = p then < p / If > p then p / =is possible if <if > V < V If < p then p / =is possible if <if < V > V Appendix.4 The strict concavity of the first-order condition for maximizing () = E' 0. () E ' writes: () E ensures that full coverage is optimal ( = ) if and only if E ( ) evaluated at full coverage is nonnegative: E ' = ( - p ) ( + m) [ Z (W, H 0 - D + ) - Z(W, H 0 ) ] - m Z (W, H 0 - D + ) + ( - ) { + m p [F(W, H 0 - D + )- F(W, H 0 )] p p / p c - F (W, H 0 - D + )} () However, the sign of is equal to the sign of Z. From the equation (8), we obtain: If = p then p / =is possible if < if 0 < 0 If > p then p / =is possible if < 0, < V and <if 0, > V and > V < V If < p then p / =is possible if 0, > V and <if < 0, < V and < V > V Appendix We consider two insurance policies defined as follows: Franchise contract c F = 0 ( )-c in states and 6 otherwise F is a deductible policy with deductible level c ( ). 4

Coinsurance contract c C = c 0 ( ) ( ) + ( - f )[ c( ) c( )] C is a proportional basis policy. in states and 5 in states and 6 in statesand 4 In the case of a coinsurance contract, the profit of the insurance company is defined as follows: tate P with Π tate P - c ( ) with Π tate P - [ ( c ) + (- f ( )) [ c - c ]] with Π tate 4 P with Π 4 tate 5 P - c ( ) with Π 5 tate 6 P - [ ( E ( π ) = P - [ c ) + (- f ( )) [ c - c ( p + ) + (- However, E ( π ) = 0 Thus P = c ( p + ) + (- c ]] with Π 6 p f ( )) [ c - p f ( )) [ c - c ] ] p c ] () p In the case of a franchise contract, the profit of the insurance company is defined as follows: tate P with Π tate P with Π tate P - [ c - c )] with Π ( tate 4 P with Π 4 tate 5 P with Π 5 c tate 6 P - [ - c ] with Π 6 E c π = P - [ - c ] However, E p c π = 0 thus P = [ - c ] (4) p 5

However, coinsurance and franchise contracts are available at the same premium. We obtain: P = with f c ( p + ) + (- ( ) = c p f ( )) [ c - c( ) + p c p c ] = [ c - c ] p. Appendix 4 The Arrow theorem holds only if '( 0) ( 0) V 0. V ' = c p [ (W0 - P - c ), H0 - D + ) - (W [V (W 0 - P - ( c, H 0 - D + ) - V (W 0 - P - 0 - P - - c, H 0 - D + )] c, H 0 - D + )]ν (7) REFERENCE - Arrow K. J. (96), ncertainty and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care, American Economic Review 5, 94-97. - Bien F. (00), Assurance maladie et risque moral : une note sur l incidence du type de risqué, Mimeo THEMA niversité Paris X-Nanterre. - Cook P.J. and Graham D.A. (977), The demand for insurance and protection : the case of irreplaceable commodities, Quarterly journal of economics 4-56. - Doherty N. et chlesinger H. (98), A note on risk premium with random initial wealth, Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 5, 8-85. - Doherty N. and chlesinger H. (98a), Optimal Insurance in incomplete markets, journal of political economy 9: 045-054. - Doherty N. and chlesinger H. (98b), The optimal deductible for an insurance policy when initial wealth is random, Journal of Business 56, 555-565. - Doherty N. and chlesinger H. (990), Rational insurance purchasing: consideration of contract nonperformance, Quarterly journal of economics, 05, 4-5. 6

- Eeckhoudt. and Hammit J. K. (00), Background risks and the value of a statistical ive, Journal of risk and uncertainty Vol. n: : 6-79. - Eeckhoudt. and Kimball M. (99), Background risk, prudence and the demand for insurance, In:G. Dionne (ed.), (99), Contributions to Insurance Economics, Kluwer Academic Publishers, 9-54. - Evans W.N. and W.K. Viscusi (99), "Estimation of state dependent utility function using survey data ", Review of economics and statistics, 7, 94-04. - Flochel. and B. Rey (00), " Health care demand and health insurance", Mimeo GATE - Mossin J. (968), "Aspects of rational insurance purchasing", journal of political economy 76: 55-568 - Razgallah M.A. (004), "Demande de soins curatifs, auto-protection et auto-asssurance", Mimeo GATE. - Rey B. (00), A Note on Optimal Insurance in the presence of a Nonpecuniary Background Risk, Theory and Decision Vol. 54 n:. - mith V. (968), "Optimal Coverage", Journal of Political Economy 76: 68-77. 7