Microeconomics III. Oligopoly prefacetogametheory (Mar 11, 2012) School of Economics The Interdisciplinary Center (IDC), Herzliya

Similar documents
UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2012

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9

MKTG 555: Marketing Models

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

Noncooperative Oligopoly

1 Solutions to Homework 3

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer Review, oligopoly, auctions, and signaling. Block 3 Jul 1, 2018

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications Final Exam Ronaldo Carpio Jan. 13, 2015

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

A monopoly is an industry consisting a single. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two. An oligopoly is an industry consisting of a few

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati.

Econ 101A Final exam Th 15 December. Do not turn the page until instructed to.

Microeconomics I - Seminar #9, April 17, Suggested Solution

Oligopoly (contd.) Chapter 27

Math 152: Applicable Mathematics and Computing

Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Second Midterm Examination Answers

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals.

Analysis of a highly migratory fish stocks fishery: a game theoretic approach

is the best response of firm 1 to the quantity chosen by firm 2. Firm 2 s problem: Max Π 2 = q 2 (a b(q 1 + q 2 )) cq 2

Economics 51: Game Theory

Advanced Microeconomic Theory EC104

Strategy -1- Strategy

Lecture 6 Dynamic games with imperfect information

Challenge to Hotelling s Principle of Minimum

Credibility and Subgame Perfect Equilibrium

Solution Problem Set 2

HW Consider the following game:

Chapter 11: Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers

Université du Maine Théorie des Jeux Yves Zenou Correction de l examen du 16 décembre 2013 (1 heure 30)

13.1 Infinitely Repeated Cournot Oligopoly

Answers to Problem Set 4

M.Phil. Game theory: Problem set II. These problems are designed for discussions in the classes of Week 8 of Michaelmas term. 1

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally.

p =9 (x1 + x2). c1 =3(1 z),

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Graduate School of Management and Economics

Name: Midterm #1 EconS 425 (February 20 th, 2015)

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

In Class Exercises. Problem 1

Advanced Microeconomics

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

Volume 29, Issue 1. Second-mover advantage under strategic subsidy policy in a third market model

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly

Strategic Production Game 1

Table 10.1: Elimination and equilibrium. 1. Is there a dominant strategy for either of the two agents?

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 5

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Econ 601 Prof. James Peck Extra Practice Problems Answers (for final)

Chapter 8. Repeated Games. Strategies and payoffs for games played twice

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND TRADE POLICY

EconS Oligopoly - Part 3

Problem Set 2 Answers

ECON402: Practice Final Exam Solutions

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 26, Lecture 28. Oligopoly

Economics 171: Final Exam

Microeconomics I. Undergraduate Programs in Business Administration and Economics

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 4

Game Theory Notes: Examples of Games with Dominant Strategy Equilibrium or Nash Equilibrium

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY MIDTERM EXAM #2 ANSWER KEY

Eco AS , J. Sandford, spring 2019 March 9, Midterm answers

Maximin and minimax strategies in asymmetric duopoly: Cournot and Bertrand

ECON 803: MICROECONOMIC THEORY II Arthur J. Robson Fall 2016 Assignment 9 (due in class on November 22)

Business Strategy in Oligopoly Markets

MICROECONOMICS II. Author: Gergely K hegyi. Supervised by Gergely K hegyi. February 2011

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

The Timing of Endogenous Wage Setting under Bertrand Competition in a Unionized Mixed Duopoly

Some Notes on Timing in Games

Antoine Augustine Cournot was a French mathematician who, in 1838, wrote a book entitled Researches

Cournot with N rms (revisited)

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik ( December 29, 2008

Oligopoly Games and Voting Games. Cournot s Model of Quantity Competition:

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

1 R. 2 l r 1 1 l2 r 2

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

Economics 212 Microeconomic Theory Final Exam. April 24, Faculty of Arts and Sciences Queen s University

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

I. Introduction and definitions

Notes for Section: Week 4

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Economics 101A (Lecture 21) Stefano DellaVigna

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Dynamic Games. Econ 400. University of Notre Dame. Econ 400 (ND) Dynamic Games 1 / 18

Capacity precommitment and price competition yield the Cournot outcome

Problem 3,a. ds 1 (s 2 ) ds 2 < 0. = (1+t)

Transcription:

Microeconomics III Oligopoly prefacetogametheory (Mar 11, 01) School of Economics The Interdisciplinary Center (IDC), Herzliya

Oligopoly is a market in which only a few firms compete with one another, and entry of new firmsisimpeded. The situation is known as the Cournot model after Antoine Augustin Cournot, a French economist, philosopher and mathematician (1801-1877). In the basic example, a single good is produced by two firms (the industry is a duopoly ).

Cournot s oligopoly model (1838) A single good is produced by two firms (the industry is a duopoly ). The cost for firm =1 for producing units of the good is given by ( unit cost is constant equal to 0). If the firms total output is = 1 + then the market price is = if and zero otherwise (linear inverse demand function). We also assume that.

The inverse demand function P A P=A-Q A Q

To find the Nash equilibria of the Cournot s game, we can use the procedures based on the firms best response functions. But first we need the firms payoffs (profits): and similarly, 1 = 1 1 1 = ( ) 1 1 1 = ( 1 ) 1 1 1 = ( 1 1 ) 1 =( 1 )

Firm 1 s profit as a function of its output (given firm s output) Profit 1 q' q q A c 1 q A c 1 q' Output 1

To find firm 1 s best response to any given output of firm, we need to study firm 1 s profit as a function of its output 1 for given values of. If you know calculus, you can set the derivative of firm 1 s profit with respect to 1 equaltozeroandsolvefor 1 : 1 = 1 ( 1 ) We conclude that the best response of firm 1 to the output of firm depends on the values of and 1.

Because firm s cost function is 6= 1, its best response function is given by = 1 ( 1 ) A Nash equilibrium of the Cournot s game is a pair ( 1 ) of outputs such that 1 is a best response to and is a best response to 1. From the figure below, we see that there is exactly one such pair of outputs 1 = + 1 3 and = + 1 3 which is the solution to the two equations above.

The best response functions in the Cournot's duopoly game Output A c 1 BR 1 ( q ) A c Nash equilibrium BR ( q 1 ) A c 1 A c Output 1

Nash equilibrium comparative statics (a decrease in the cost of firm ) Output A c 1 BR 1 ( q ) Nash equilibrium II Nash equilibrium I A c BR ( q 1 ) A c 1 A c Output 1 A question: what happens when consumers are willing to pay more (A increases)?

In summary, this simple Cournot s duopoly game has a unique Nash equilibrium. Two economically important properties of the Nash equilibrium are (to economic regulatory agencies): [1] The relation between the firms equilibrium profits and the profit they could make if they act collusively. [] The relation between the equilibrium profits and the number of firms.

[1] Collusive outcomes: in the Cournot s duopoly game, there is a pair of outputs at which both firms profits exceed their levels in a Nash equilibrium. [] Competition: The price at the Nash equilibrium if the two firms have the same unit cost 1 = = is given by = 1 = 1 3 ( + ) which is above the unit cost. But as the number of firm increases, the equilibrium price deceases, approaching (zero profits!).

Stackelberg s duopoly model (1934) How do the conclusions of the Cournot s duopoly game change when the firms move sequentially? Is a firm better off moving before or after the other firm? Suppose that 1 = = and that firm 1 moves at the start of the game. We may use backward induction to find the subgame perfect equilibrium. First, for any output 1 of firm 1, wefind the output of firm that maximizes its profit. Next, we find the output 1 of firm 1 that maximizes its profit, given the strategy of firm.

Firm Since firm moves after firm 1, a strategy of firm is a function that associate an output for firm for each possible output 1 of firm 1. We found that under the assumptions of the Cournot s duopoly game Firm has a unique best response to each output 1 of firm 1, given by (Recall that 1 = = ). = 1 ( 1 )

Firm 1 Firm 1 s strategy is the output 1 the maximizes 1 =( 1 ) 1 subject to = 1 ( 1 ) Thus, firm 1 maximizes 1 =( 1 ( 1 ( 1 )) ) 1 = 1 1( 1 ) This function is quadratic in 1 that is zero when 1 = 0 and when 1 =. Thus its maximizer is 1 = 1 ( )

Firm 1 s (first mover) profit in Stackelberg's duopoly game Profit 1 1 1 q1( A q1 c) A c 1 A c Output 1

We conclude that Stackelberg s duopoly game has a unique subgame perfect equilibrium, in which firm 1 s strategy is the output and firm s output is 1 = 1 ( ) = 1 ( 1 ) = 1 ( 1 ( ) ) = 1 ( ) 4 By contrast, in the unique Nash equilibrium of the Cournot s duopoly game under the same assumptions ( 1 = = ), each firm produces 1 ( ). 3

Output The subgame perfect equilibrium of Stackelberg's duopoly game A c BR ( q 1 ) Nash equilibrium (Cournot) Subgame perfect equilibrium (Stackelberg) A c 3 A c A c Output 1

Bertrand s oligopoly model (1883) In Cournot s game, each firm chooses an output, and the price is determined by the market demand in relation to the total output produced. An alternative model, suggested by Bertrand, assumes that each firm chooses a price, and produces enough output to meet the demand it faces, given the prices chosen by all the firms. = As we shell see, some of the answers it gives are different from the answers of Cournot.

Suppose again that there are two firms (the industry is a duopoly ) and that the cost for firm =1 for producing units of the good is given by (equal constant unit cost ). Assume that the demand function (rather than the inverse demand function as we did for the Cournot s game) is ( ) = for and zero otherwise, and that (the demand function in PR 1.3 is different).

Because the cost of producing each unit is the same, equal to, firm makes the profit of on every unit it sells. Thus its profit is = where is the other firm. ( )( ) if 1 ( )( ) if = 0 if In Bertrand s game we can easily argue as follows: ( 1 )=( ) is the unique Nash equilibrium.

Using intuition, If one firm charges the price, then the other firmcandonobetter than charge the price. If 1 and,theneachfirm can increase its profit by lowering its price slightly below. = In Cournot s game, the market price decreases toward as the number of firms increases, whereas in Bertrand s game it is (so profits are zero) even if there are only two firms (but the price remains when the number of firm increases).