A note on health insurance under ex post moral hazard

Similar documents
A Note on Health Insurance under Ex Post Moral Hazard

Photovoltaic deployment: from subsidies to a market-driven growth: A panel econometrics approach

Money in the Production Function : A New Keynesian DSGE Perspective

The National Minimum Wage in France

Strategic complementarity of information acquisition in a financial market with discrete demand shocks

Equivalence in the internal and external public debt burden

Networks Performance and Contractual Design: Empirical Evidence from Franchising

Parameter sensitivity of CIR process

Inequalities in Life Expectancy and the Global Welfare Convergence

Equilibrium payoffs in finite games

Ricardian equivalence and the intertemporal Keynesian multiplier

Motivations and Performance of Public to Private operations : an international study

About the reinterpretation of the Ghosh model as a price model

Rôle de la protéine Gas6 et des cellules précurseurs dans la stéatohépatite et la fibrose hépatique

The German unemployment since the Hartz reforms: Permanent or transitory fall?

Characterization of the Optimum

The Hierarchical Agglomerative Clustering with Gower index: a methodology for automatic design of OLAP cube in ecological data processing context

MORAL HAZARD AND BACKGROUND RISK IN COMPETITIVE INSURANCE MARKETS: THE DISCRETE EFFORT CASE. James A. Ligon * University of Alabama.

On the Design of Optimal Health Insurance Contracts under Ex Post Moral Hazard

Yield to maturity modelling and a Monte Carlo Technique for pricing Derivatives on Constant Maturity Treasury (CMT) and Derivatives on forward Bonds

On the design of optimal health insurance contracts under ex post moral hazard

Modèles DSGE Nouveaux Keynésiens, Monnaie et Aversion au Risque.

On the Design of Optimal Health Insurance Contracts under Ex Post Moral Hazard

IS-LM and the multiplier: A dynamic general equilibrium model

Carbon Prices during the EU ETS Phase II: Dynamics and Volume Analysis

Solving the Yitzhaki Paradox: Income Tax Evasion and Reference Dependence under Prospect Theory

The impact of commitment on nonrenewable resources management with asymmetric information on costs

BDHI: a French national database on historical floods

Standard Risk Aversion and Efficient Risk Sharing

Optimal Tax Base with Administrative fixed Costs

Mossin s Theorem for Upper-Limit Insurance Policies

Advanced Financial Economics Homework 2 Due on April 14th before class

The Quantity Theory of Money Revisited: The Improved Short-Term Predictive Power of of Household Money Holdings with Regard to prices

The Sustainability and Outreach of Microfinance Institutions

BACKGROUND RISK IN THE PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL. James A. Ligon * University of Alabama. and. Paul D. Thistle University of Nevada Las Vegas

STX FACULTY WORKING PAPER NO Risk Aversion and the Purchase of Risky Insurance. Harris Schlesinger

The Riskiness of Risk Models

French German flood risk geohistory in the Rhine Graben

Dynamics of the exchange rate in Tunisia

Moral Hazard and Health Insurance when Treatment is Preventive

On some key research issues in Enterprise Risk Management related to economic capital and diversification effect at group level

Comment Does the economics of moral hazard need to be revisited? A comment on the paper by John Nyman

Choice under Uncertainty

Why ruin theory should be of interest for insurance practitioners and risk managers nowadays

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

Information Transmission in Nested Sender-Receiver Games

Inefficient Lock-in with Sophisticated and Myopic Players

On the Design of Optimal Health Insurance Contracts under Ex Post Moral Hazard

Section 9, Chapter 2 Moral Hazard and Insurance

A note on choosing the alternative with the best median evaluation

3. Prove Lemma 1 of the handout Risk Aversion.

Drug launch timing and international reference pricing

Theoretical considerations on the retirement consumption puzzle and the optimal age of retirement

Two dimensional Hotelling model : analytical results and numerical simulations

European Debt Crisis: How a Public debt Restructuring Can Solve a Private Debt issue

Andreas Wagener University of Vienna. Abstract

Splitting Risks in Insurance Markets With Adverse Selection

Administering Systemic Risk vs. Administering Justice: What Can We Do Now that We Have Agreed to Pay Differences?

OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY. WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics

Wage bargaining with non-stationary preferences under strike decision

Risk Aversion, Stochastic Dominance, and Rules of Thumb: Concept and Application

Micro Theory I Assignment #5 - Answer key

A revisit of the Borch rule for the Principal-Agent Risk-Sharing problem

STOCHASTIC CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL: CANONICAL APPLICATIONS FEBRUARY 19, 2013

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

Do Professional Economists Forecasts Reflect Okun s Law? Some Evidence for the G7 Countries

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Control-theoretic framework for a quasi-newton local volatility surface inversion

Chapter 8 Liquidity and Financial Intermediation

Transactions with Hidden Action: Part 1. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Endogenous interest rate with accommodative money supply and liquidity preference

What first assessment can be made of the monetary strategy since 1999?

Risk aversion and choice under uncertainty

The relevance and the limits of the Arrow-Lind Theorem. Luc Baumstark University of Lyon. Christian Gollier Toulouse School of Economics.

Insurance and Monopoly Power in a Mixed Private/Public Hospital System. Donald J. Wright

MICROECONOMIC THEROY CONSUMER THEORY

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems III

Rôle de la régulation génique dans l adaptation : approche par analyse comparative du transcriptome de drosophile

The Optimal Regulation of a Risky Monopoly

Liability, Insurance and the Incentive to Obtain Information About Risk. Vickie Bajtelsmit * Colorado State University

On the properties of non-monetary measures for risks

TIME AND RISK PREFERENCES IN THE COVERAGE. W. DAVID BRADFORD, PH.D. Department of Public Administration and Policy, University of Georgia.

The demand for health insurance in a multirisk context

Combining Monte Carlo Simulations and Options to Manage the Risk of Real Estate Portfolios

IS TAX SHARING OPTIMAL? AN ANALYSIS IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT FRAMEWORK

Problem Set 2. Theory of Banking - Academic Year Maria Bachelet March 2, 2017

University of California, Davis Department of Economics Giacomo Bonanno. Economics 103: Economics of uncertainty and information PRACTICE PROBLEMS

Homework 1: Basic Moral Hazard

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

Creating a winner s curse via jump bids

The Welfare Cost of Asymmetric Information: Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

Adverse Selection and Switching Costs in Health Insurance Markets. by Benjamin Handel

Representing Risk Preferences in Expected Utility Based Decision Models

Microeconomic Theory May 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program.

The distortionary effect of monetary policy: credit expansion vs. lump-sum transfers in the lab

EU i (x i ) = p(s)u i (x i (s)),

Health Insurance Part 2. Health Policy Eric Jacobson

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014

Transcription:

A note on health insurance under ex post moral hazard Pierre Picard To cite this version: Pierre Picard. A note on health insurance under ex post moral hazard. 2016. <hal- 01353597v2> HAL Id: hal-01353597 https://hal-polytechnique.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-01353597v2 Submitted on 23 Aug 2016 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access archive for the deposit and dissemination of scientific research documents, whether they are published or not. The documents may come from teaching and research institutions in France or abroad, or from public or private research centers. L archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, émanant des établissements d enseignement et de recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires publics ou privés.

ECOLE POLYTECHNIQUE CENTRE NATIONAL DE LA RECHERCHE SCIENTIFIQUE A note on health insurance under ex post moral hazard Pierre PICARD August 1, 2016 Cahier n 2016-10 DEPARTEMENT D'ECONOMIE Route de Saclay 91128 PALAISEAU CEDEX (33) 1 69333033 http://www.portail.polytechnique.edu/economie/fr mariame.seydi@polytechnique.edu

A note on health insurance under ex post moral hazard Pierre Picard August 1st, 2016 Abstract In the linear coinsurance problem, examined first by Mossin (1968), a higher risk aversion with respect to wealth in the sense of Arrow- Pratt implies a higher optimal coinsurance rate. We show that this property does not hold for health insurance under ex post moral hazard, i.e., when illness severity cannot be observed by insurers and policyholders decide on their health expenditures. The optimal coinsurance rate trades off a risk sharing effect and an incentive effect, both related to risk aversion. JEL Codes: D1, D8, I1. Keywords: Health insurance; ex post moral hazard; coinsurance. Ecole Polytechnique, Department of Economics, 91128, Palaiseau Cedex, France. Email: pierre.picard@polytechnique.edu 1

1 Introduction The linear coinsurance problem, originally examined by Mossin (1968), plays an important role in the analysis of economic and financial decisions under risk, and this is for at least two reasons. Firstly, this model is suitable for tractable comparative statics analysis, in order to study wealth and income effects on insurance demand in various settings (e.g., with or without background risk, in a static or dynamic setting, etc...). Secondly, its conclusions can be straighforwardly adapted to the analysis of static portfolio choices when agents can invest in one risk-free asset and in one risky asset. An important property of this model states that the individual s degree of risk aversion with respect to wealth in the sense of Arrow-Pratt goes hand in hand with a higher optimal coinsurance rate: more risk averse individuals choose a higher coinsurance rate. In this note, we will show that this property does not hold for health insurance under ex post moral hazard. There is ex post moral hazard in medical insurance when insurers do not observe the severity of illness and policyholders may exaggerate their health care expenses - Arrow (1963), Pauly (1968) and Zeckhauser (1970). Linear coinsurance under ex post moral hazard (i.e., when insurers pay the same fraction of the health care cost whatever the individuals expenses) has been considered by many authors, including Zeckhauser (1970), Feldstein (1973), Arrow (1976), and Feldman and Dowd (1991) to analyze the trade-off between two conflicting objectives: providing risk coverage on one side, and incentivizing policyholders to moderate their health expenses on the other side. In order to show that ex post moral hazard breaks the link between the degree of risk aversion and the optimal coinsurance rate, we will proceed through a simple example. We will consider a model where utility depends on wealth and health in an additive way, with constant absolute risk aversion with respect to wealth, and where the utility derived from health is linear. Furthermore, the only private information of individuals is about the severity of their illness. All other preference parameters, including health risk exposure and risk aversion are either observed by insurers, or rather recovered from observable variables such as age, education, occupation, marital status or from past loss experience. These very crude assumptions are obviously not chosen for the sake of realism, but because they allow us to focus on the ex post moral hazard problem in a fully computable model, without inter- 2

fering with adverse or advantageous selection issues. It will turn out that, in this model, the optimal coinsurance rate does not depend on the index of absolute risk aversion. The intuition for this result goes through two effects of an increase in the coinsurance rate. On one hand, for a given pattern of health care expenses, a larger coinsurance rate offers a better risk protection to risk averse individuals: thus, the larger the degree of risk aversion, the larger the benefit drawn for this more complete risk coverage. This is the standard channel that links together the intensity of risk aversion and the optimal insurance coverage. On the other hand, an increase in coverage exacerbates health care overexpenses, and it turns out that, in an expected utility setting such as ours, this (dis)incentive effect is the larger as the absolute risk aversion is small. Thus, more risk aversion entails less financial risk, because it corresponds to less health care overexpenses, and thus it reduces the need for insurance coverage. When the index of absolute risk aversion increases, the risk protection effect and the incentive effect push the optimal coinsurance rate upwards and downwards, respectively. In the model that we will consider, these two effects exactly balance each other out, so that the optimal coinsurance rate remains unchanged. 2 A computable example Let us consider an individual whose welfare depends both on monetary wealth R and health level H, with a separable bi-variate von Neumann-Morgenstern utility function U(R, H) = u(r) + v(h). The individual displays CARA preferences with respect to wealth, i.e., u(r) = exp{ αr}, where α is the index of absolute risk aversion, and v(h) = βh, β > 0. We thus have U(R, H) = exp{ αr} + βh. Health may be negatively affected by illness, but it increases with the health care expenses. This is written as H = h 0 γx(1 m), γ > 0, where h 0 is the initial health endowment, x is the severity of illness and m is the health care expense level. Illness severity is distributed as a random variable X over an intervall [a, b],with a > 0, and the parameters of the 3

problem are such that m [0, 1]. Thus, the health level H increases linearly from h 0 γx to h 0 when m increases from 0 to 1. The individual s insurance contract specifies that a fraction θ of the monetary expenses are reimbursed and that the insurance premium P is actuarial. It is assumed that insurers observe all the characteristics of insurance seekers, including their risk exposure and degree of risk aversion (i.e., the probability distribution of X and parameter α). In more concrete terms, insurers are supposed to be able to recover these information through observable characteristics, such as age, gender or level of education. 1 In state x, the individual s wealth is R(x) = w (1 θ)m(x) P, where m(x) denotes the health care expenses in state x. chooses m(x) such that The individual m(x) arg max [ exp{ α(w (1 θ) m P )} + βγx m]. m [0,1] Let us assume that m(x) (0, 1) for all x. Later, we will find conditions under which this is actually the case. Then, the first-order condition for m(x) to be an optimal choice of the individual is written as which implies and α(1 θ) exp{ αr(x)} + βγx = 0, R(x) = 1 [ ] α(1 θ) α ln, (1) βγx m(x) = Using P = θe[m(x)] yields [ α(w P ) + ln α(1 θ) βγx α(1 θ) ]. E[R(X)] = w (1 θ)e[m(x)] P = w P θ = 1 ( )] α(1 θ) [ln α E. βγx 1 Outreville (2014) surveys the empirical analysis of socio-demographic variables associated with risk aversion. 4

which gives and using (1) and (2) yields P = θw + θ ( )] βγx [ln α E, (2) α(1 θ) m(x) = w P R(x) 1 θ = w 1 α ln[α(1 θ)] + ln(βγx) θe[ln(βγx)] α(1 θ) (3) By disregarding the constant term h 0 βγe[x], (1) and (3) allow us to write the individual s expected utility as E [exp{ αr(x)}] + βγe[xm(x)] = βγe[x] α(1 θ) +βγ [ E[X]w E[X] α ln[α(1 θ)] + E[X ln(βγx)] θe[x]e[ln(βγx)] ], α(1 θ) which is maximized with respect to θ [0, 1]. Let z = 1/(1 θ). Equivalently, z maximizes in [1, + ), where V (z) E[X] ln(z) + z[ E[X]], = E[X ln(x)] E[X]E[ln(X)] = cov[x, ln(x)] > 0. We have and V (z) = E[X] + E[X], z V (z) = E[X] < 0. z 2 V (1) = > 0 5

If then V (z) is maximized over [1, + ) when that is θ = z = E[X] < E[X], (4) E[X] E[X] > 1, = cov[x, ln(x) E[X] (0, 1). (5) If E[X], then θ = 1 would be an optimal corner solution, with m(x) = 1 for all x. Thus (4) is a necessary condition for an optimal interior solution to exist. (3) shows that m(x) is increasing for such an interior solution. Thus we have m(x) (0, 1) for all x [a, b] if w (w, w), (6) where w and w are given by (3), m(a) = 0, m(b) = 1 and θ = /E[X], with w > w if ln(b/a) < α(1 θ). (7) In short, under (4),(6) and (7), we have an interior optimal solution θ = /E[X] (0, 1) with m(x) (0, 1) for all x. At this optimal solution, the coinsurance rate θ is given by (5) and it is independent from the index of absolute risk aversion α. It only depends on the probability distribution of the illness severity X. 2 3 Comments Let R (x) be the individual s wealth that would be chosen in state x in the absence of insurance, that is R (x) = 1 [ ] α α ln, βγx 2 Everything else given, (7) does not hold when α is small enough. In that case, m(x) is equal to 0 or 1 in a sub-interval of [a, b]. Thus, strictly speaking, the independence of θ from α has been established among values of α that are large enough for such corner solutions no to be optimal. 6

with R(x) < R (x) when θ > 0. R (x) is ex post effi cient, since the marginal utility of wealth is the same, be it used for health care or for other uses. A decrease in R(x)/R (x) corresponds to an increase in health care overexpenses (i.e., an increase above the ex post effi cient level). 3 Assume R (x) > 0, and thus ln(α/βγx) > 0. We have [R(x)/R (x)] θ 2 [R(x)/R (x)] θ α 1 = (1 θ) ln(α/βγx) < 0, = 1 α(1 θ) ln(α/βγx) 2 > 0. Thus, as expected, an increase in θ increases the health care overexpense (i.e., R(x)/R (x) decreases), but the larger the index of risk aversion, the smaller this induced expense effect. In other words, more risk aversion corresponds to less financial risk, because it corresponds to less health care overexpenses. Coming back to our initial notation, the index of risk aversion is equal to d[ln(u (R)]/dR, and thus it measures the rate of increase in the marginal utility of wealth when wealth decreases, and thus it is not astonishing that the larger the absolute risk aversion, the smaller the insurance-induced increase in health care spending. This induced risk exposure is anticipated by insurance seekers, and thus it is a reason why more risk averse individuals may purchase less insurance. Conversely, for a given risk exposure, more risk averse individuals tend to purchase more insurance. In the absence of loading, they would purchase full coverage if there were no ex post moral hazard. In the present model, the two mechanisms compensate exactly, and ultimately risk aversion does not affect the optimal coinsurance rate. 4 Conclusion Risk aversion may depend on several parameters, including wealth, age, marital status and occupation, among others. Consider the case of a background risk, such as business interruption, assumed to be uninsurable and in force for self-employed people, but not for employees. Under risk vulnerability, such a background risk makes the individual more averse to other independent risks, including health care expenditures. If insurance expenses were 3 Note that R(x)/R (x) is decreasing with respect to x. Thus, the larger the severity of illness, the larger the distortion in health expenses due to ex post moral hazard. 7

perfectly monitored by the insurer, then this background risk would increase the coinsurance rate for health care. In other words, everything else given, self-employed people should choose a more complete health insurance than employees. The previous example shows that this is no more the case under ex post moral hazard. 5 References Arrow, K.J., 1963, "Uncertainty and the welfare economics of medical care", American Economic Review, 53, 941-973. Arrow, K.J., 1976, "Welfare analysis of changes in health co-insurance rates", in The Role of Health Insurance in the Health Services Sector, R. Rosett (ed.), NBER, New York, 3-23. Feldman, R. and B. Dowd, 1991, "A new estimate of the welfare loss of excess health insurance", American Economic Review, 81, 297-301. Feldstein, M., 1973, "The welfare loss of excess health insurance", Journal of Political Economy, 81, 251-280. Mossin, J., 1968, "Aspects of rational insurance purchasing", Journal of Political Economy, 76, 533-568. Outreville, J.F., 2014, "Risk aversion, risk behavior, and demand for insurance: a survey", Journal of Insurance Issues, 37, 2, 158-186. Pauly, M., 1968, "The economics of moral hazard: comment", American Economic Review, 58, 531-537. Zeckhauser, R., 1970, "Medical insurance: a case study of the tradeoff between risk spreading and appropriate incentives", Journal of Economic Theory, 2, 10-26 8