A Double Counting Problem in the Theory of Rational Bubbles

Similar documents
Assets with possibly negative dividends

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Collateralized capital and News-driven cycles

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

FISCAL POLICY AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS. C 1t + S t + B t P t = 1 (1) C 2,t+1 = R tb t P t+1 S t 0, B t 0. (3)

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Consumption and Saving

Real Business Cycles (Solution)

Inflation. David Andolfatto

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2007

Part A: Questions on ECN 200D (Rendahl)

Growth and Distributional Effects of Inflation with Progressive Taxation

Consumption and Asset Pricing

Optimal Monetary Policy Rule under the Non-Negativity Constraint on Nominal Interest Rates

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

In our model this theory is supported since: p t = 1 v t

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016

Bubbles and the Intertemporal Government Budget Constraint

Detailed Working Through Garegnani Reswitching Example Robert L. Vienneau 27 March 2005, Updated: 11 October 2005

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory. Steve Williamson Dept. of Economics Washington University in St. Louis St. Louis, MO 63130

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2009

Funded Pension Scheme, Endogenous Time Preference and Capital Accumulation

1 Dynamic programming

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Lecture 1: Lucas Model and Asset Pricing

1 The Solow Growth Model

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015

Speculative Trade under Ambiguity

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function:

1. Introduction of another instrument of savings, namely, capital

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background

Homework 3: Asset Pricing

Bubbles and Credit Constraints

Income Disparity, Uneven Economic Opportunities, and Verifiability. Masayuki Otaki (Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo)

Public Investment, Life Expectancy and Income Growth

Credit, externalities, and non-optimality of the Friedman rule

Regressive Welfare Effects of Housing Bubbles

Collateralized capital and news-driven cycles. Abstract

Speculative Trade under Ambiguity

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Macroeconomics and finance

The International Transmission of Credit Bubbles: Theory and Policy

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

Endogenous Money, Inflation and Welfare

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Golden rule. The golden rule allocation is the stationary, feasible allocation that maximizes the utility of the future generations.

TAKE-HOME EXAM POINTS)

1 The Goodwin (1967) Model

Pinning down the price level with the government balance sheet

Asset Price Bubbles in the Kiyotaki-Moore Model

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS

Bubbles. Macroeconomics IV. Ricardo J. Caballero. Spring 2011 MIT. R.J. Caballero (MIT) Bubbles Spring / 29

Markets Do Not Select For a Liquidity Preference as Behavior Towards Risk

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

A numerical analysis of the monetary aspects of the Japanese economy: the cash-in-advance approach

Practice Questions for Mid-Term Examination - I. In answering questions just consider symmetric and stationary allocations!

Savings, Investment and the Real Interest Rate in an Endogenous Growth Model

1 Mar Review. Consumer s problem is. V (z, K, a; G, q z ) = max. subject to. c+ X q z. w(z, K) = zf 2 (K, H(K)) (4) K 0 = G(z, K) (5)

Money Inventories in Search Equilibrium

Speculative Bubble Burst

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

A REINTERPRETATION OF THE KEYNESIAN CONSUMPTION FUNCTION AND MULTIPLIER EFFECT

Unemployment, Income Growth and Social Security

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Aggregate Implications of Credit Market Imperfections (II) By Kiminori Matsuyama. Updated on January 25, 2010

Exact microeconomic foundation for the Phillips curve under complete markets: A Keynesian view

Multiperiod Market Equilibrium

On the evolution from barter to fiat money

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Limited Market Participation, Financial Intermediaries, And Endogenous Growth

Monetary union enlargement and international trade

Will Bequests Attenuate the Predicted Meltdown in Stock Prices When Baby Boomers Retire?

FALLACY OF THE MULTIPLIER EFFECT: CORRECTING THE INCOME ANALYSIS

Chapter 6 Money, Inflation and Economic Growth

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model

Long run equilibria in an asymmetric oligopoly

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Transcription:

JSPS Grants-in-Aid for Scientific Research (S) Understanding Persistent Deflation in Japan Working Paper Series No. 084 May 2016 A Double Counting Problem in the Theory of Rational Bubbles Hajime Tomura UTokyo Price Project 702 Faculty of Economics, The University of Tokyo, 7-3-1 Hongo, Bunkyo-ku, Tokyo 113-0033, Japan Tel: +81-3-5841-5595 E-mail: watlab@e.u-tokyo.ac.jp http://www.price.e.u-tokyo.ac.jp/english/ Working Papers are a series of manuscripts in their draft form that are shared for discussion and comment purposes only. They are not intended for circulation or distribution, except as indicated by the author. For that reason, Working Papers may not be reproduced or distributed without the expressed consent of the author.

A Double Counting Problem in the Theory of Rational Bubbles Hajime Tomura Faculty of Political Science and Economics, Waseda University, 1-6-1 Nishiwaseda, Shinjyuku-ku, Tokyo, Japan. Email: tomura.hajime@gmail.com May 2, 2016 Abstract In a standard overlapping generations model, the unique equilibrium price of a Lucas tree can be decomposed into the present discounted value of dividends and the stationary monetary equilibrium price of fiat money, the latter of which is a rational bubble. Thus, the standard interpretation of a rational bubble as the speculative component in an asset price double-counts the value of pure liquidity that is already part of the fundamental price of an interest-bearing asset. Keywords: rational bubbles; liquidity. JEL classification: E3. I thank Akihisa Shibata for helpful discussion of the paper. I am also grateful for financial support from JSPS Grant-in-Aid for Scientific Research (24223003). 1

1 Introduction A rational bubble is usually modeled as an intrinsically useless asset. As shown by Tirole (1985), it attains a positive market value if it is expected to be exchangeable for goods in the future. It becomes worthless if it is expected to be worthless in the future, given that it has no intrinsic use. This property of self-fulfilling multiple equilibria has been used to explain a large boom-bust cycle in an asset price, as a stochastic transition between the two equilibria can generate a boom-bust cycle without any associated change in asset fundamentals. In this result, a rational bubble is interpreted as the speculative component in an asset price, as typical assets that show a boom-bust cycle, such as land and stock, have some intrinsic use, or yield returns. Thus, it is implicitly assumed that an asset price is the sum of a fundamental component and a rational bubble. This paper shows that this interpretation of a rational bubble is invalid, as it double-counts the value of pure liquidity that is already part of the fundamental price of an interest-bearing asset. This result is due to a basic property of a competitive market such that an asset always attains a positive price, and hence liquidity, as long as it yields a positive dividend. Thus, the value of pure liquidity, if any, is always part of the price of an interest-bearing asset. This paper demonstrates this result by decomposing the price of a Lucas tree in a standard overlapping generations model. A recent strand of literature, such as Kocherlakota (2008) and Miao and Wang (2014), introduces an independent autoregressive component into the equilibrium price of an interestbearing asset by considering borrowing constraints loosened by the component. This paper s result is complementary to their works, as the result implies that it is necessary to incorporate an interest-bearing asset explicitly into a model to identify an environment in which speculation can cause a boom-bust cycle in an asset price. 2

2 The model Time is discrete and indexed by t = 0, 1, 2,... A unit continuum of agents are born in each period and live for two periods. Call agents in their first period young, and those in their second period old. Each agent maximizes the following utility function: U = ln c 1,t + β ln c 2,t+1, (1) where β (0, 1), and c 1,t and c 2,t denote the consumption of goods by a young and an old agent, respectively, in period t. Each agent is endowed with amounts e Y and e O of perishable goods when young and old, respectively. Assume that βe Y > e O > 0. (2) There also exist a unit continuum of the initial old in period 0 who maximize their consumption in the period and exit from the economy after that. The initial old do not have any good, but are endowed with a share of a Lucas tree for each. A Lucas tree is divisible, never depreciates, and yields an amount d ( 0) of goods as a dividend at the beginning of each period. There exists a competitive market for the shares of a Lucas tree in each period. Under these assumptions, the maximization problem for a young agent born in period t is specified as: max ln c 1,t + β ln c 2,t+1, (3) c 1,t,c 2,t+1,a t s.t. c 1,t = e Y q t a t, (4) c 2,t+1 = e O + (q t+1 + d)a t, (5) c 1,t, c 2,t+1, a t 0, (6) where q t denotes the price of a Lucas tree in terms of goods in period t, and a t denotes the share of a Lucas tree held by a young agent at the end of period t. The initial old s 3

consumption of goods in period 0 is q 0 + d. Given the values of parameters, (β, e Y, e O, d), an equilibrium is characterized by the solution for the utility maximization problem for each agent and the value of q t satisfying the market clearing condition, a t = 1 (7) for t = 0, 1, 2..., where the right-hand side is the fixed-supply of a Lucas tree. 2.1 Equilibrium value of fiat money A Lucas tree becomes fiat money if the dividend, d, is set to zero. As well known in the literature, there exist two stationary equilibria under the assumption of dynamic inefficiency, (2), in this case. One is a non-monetary equilibrium in which q t = 0 for all t. The other is a monetary equilibrium in which q t > 0 for all t. In the latter equilibrium, the first-order condition for a t implies Given d = 0, substituting (4), (5), and (7) into (8) yields q t = βc 1,tq t+1 c 2,t+1. (8) q t = p βe Y e O 1 + β (9) for all t in the stationary monetary equilibrium, where p denotes the stationary monetary equilibrium price of fiat money. The assumption (2) ensures that the right-hand side of (9) is positive. The positive value of fiat money in a monetary equilibrium is a rational bubble, because it stems from self-fulfilling expectations of the resellability of fiat money for goods in the future. Thus, a rational bubble represents the value of pure liquidity. 2.2 Equilibrium price of a Lucas tree with a positive dividend Next, suppose that d > 0. In this case, q t > 0 (10) 4

for all t in any equilibrium, as otherwise agents would demand an infinite share of a Lucas tree in the competitive market. The first-order condition for a t is Then, substituting (4), (5), and (7) into (11) yields for t = 0, 1, 2... q t+1 = q t = βc 1,t(q t+1 + d) c 2,t+1. (11) e O q t βe Y (1 + β)q t d (12) Figure 1 draws the phase diagram implied by (12). The point E is the unique equilibrium, because q t becomes negative in some period t to satisfy (12) unless q 0 takes the stationary equilibrium value at the point E. Even though the figure is a numerical example, this result of unique equilibrium holds for any parameter values. 1 This result is essentially the same as the results shown by Homburg (1991) and Rhee (1991) on the dynamic efficiency of an economy with land. The novel contribution of this paper is in the next part, which shows that the value of pure liquidity represented by a rational bubble is in fact part of the unique equilibrium price of a Lucas tree. 2.3 Decomposition of the equilibrium price of a Lucas tree The uniqueness of equilibrium with a Lucas tree contrasts with the existence of multiple equilibria with fiat money. This result is due to a bifurcation. The solid curve in Figure 1 moves upward as the dividend on a Lucas tree, d, declines towards zero. The limit case is the economy with fiat money. In the limit, the point A converges to the origin at the point O, which corresponds to the non-monetary equilibrium with fiat money. Also, the point E converges to some point on the 45-degree line at which q t and q t+1 are positive. This point corresponds to the stationary monetary equilibrium with fiat money. Thus, for q t 0, the 1 Equation (12) is a hyperbolic function of q t. For q t [0, βe Y /(1 + β)), (12) is monotonically increasing and strictly convex and has a range over [ d, ). For q t R\[0, βe Y /(1 + β)), q t+1 takes a negative value below d. 5

Figure 1: Phase diagram for the model with a Lucas tree 0.4 0.2 E 45 o line q t+1 0.0 d 0.2 O A 0.4 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 q t Note: (β, e Y, e O, d) = (0.5, 1, 0.05, 0.1). The solid curve and the dotted line are (12) and a 45-degree line, respectively. 6

solid curve and the 45-degree line in Figure 1 intersect only once if d > 0, but twice if d = 0. This bifurcation property of the economy holds because an asset always attains a positive equilibrium price in a competitive market as long as it yields a positive dividend. Hence, unlike fiat money, there is no equilibrium in which a Lucas tree with a positive dividend loses liquidity. The convergence of the point E to the stationary monetary equilibrium with fiat money implies lim q = d 0 p, (13) where q denotes the value of q t and q t+1 at the point E. This result indicates that the unique equilibrium price of a Lucas tree, q, consists of a contribution from positive future dividends, d, and the value of pure liquidity represented by a rational bubble, p. To confirm this result formally, decompose q using (8) and (11): q p = Λ(q + d) Λ p, = Λ(q + d p ) (Λ Λ)p, = Λd (Λ Λ)p, (14) 1 Λ where Λ and Λ denote the discount factors, βc 1,t /c 2,t+1, in the equilibrium with a Lucas tree and the stationary monetary equilibrium with fiat money, respectively: Rearranging both sides of (14) yields Λ β(e Y q) e O + q + d, (15) Λ β(e Y p ) e O + p. (16) ρq = d + (1 + ρ) ρ p 1 + ρ, (17) 7

where ρ and ρ denote the time preference rates implied by Λ and Λ, respectively: ρ 1 Λ Λ, (18) ρ 1 Λ Λ. (19) The left-hand side of (17), ρq, is the yield on a Lucas tree with the time preference rate, ρ, as the discount factor. Thus, (17) is a standard asset-pricing formula. On the right-hand side of (17), the first term, d, is the physical dividend on a Lucas tree. In the second term, ρ p /(1 + ρ ) is the present discounted value of the internal yield on fiat money, ρ p, in the stationary monetary equilibrium. Hence, the yield on a Lucas tree consists of the physical dividend and the value of pure liquidity represented by a rational bubble. The second term on the right-hand side of (17) is multiplied by the gross time preference rate in the economy with a Lucas tree, 1 + ρ, to convert it into the current value. 2 The decomposition formula, (17), is valid even for a dynamically efficient economy, as p is simply zero in that case. Thus, the proper definition of the fundamental price of an interestbearing asset must include the value of pure liquidity given the underlying environment in the economy. This result is a reflection of an earlier result that an asset with a positive dividend always attains a positive price, and hence liquidity, in a competitive market. It in turn implies that it is a double-counting of the value of pure liquidity if an asset price is assumed to be the sum of the fundamental price and a rational bubble on an intrinsically useless asset, so that the latter component can be switched on and off exogenously. References [1] Homburg, Stefan, 1991. Interest and Growth in an Economy with Land, Canadian Journal of Economics, 24(2): 450-59. 2 Rhee (1991) shows that there exists an equilibrium in which an overlapping generations economy with land is dynamically inefficient, if the yield on land per capita is converging to zero over time. In this equilibrium, the land price converges to zero; thus it does not contain the value of liquidity incorporated by a rational bubble. This paper reports a result on a normal asset class whose aggregate yield per capita does not vanish in the steady state. 8

[2] Kocherlakota, Narayana, 2008. Injecting Rational Bubbles, Journal of Economic Theory, 142(1): 218-232. [3] Miao, Jianjun, and Pengfei Wang, 2014. Sectoral Bubbles, Misallocation, and Endogenous Growth, Journal of Mathematical Economics, 53(C): 153-163. [4] Rhee, Changyong, 1991. Dynamic Inefficiency in an Economy with Land, Review of Economic Studies, 58(4): 791-797. [5] Tirole, Jean, 1985. Asset Bubbles and Overlapping Generations, Econometrica, 53(6): 1499-1528. 9