Internet Appendix for: Sequential Learning, Predictability, and. Optimal Portfolio Returns

Similar documents
Technical Appendix: Policy Uncertainty and Aggregate Fluctuations.

Bayesian Dynamic Linear Models for Strategic Asset Allocation

Sequential learning, predictability, and optimal portfolio returns

Chapter 6 Forecasting Volatility using Stochastic Volatility Model

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Bayesian Estimation of the Markov-Switching GARCH(1,1) Model with Student-t Innovations

Stochastic Volatility (SV) Models

Combining State-Dependent Forecasts of Equity Risk Premium

1. You are given the following information about a stationary AR(2) model:

Linda Allen, Jacob Boudoukh and Anthony Saunders, Understanding Market, Credit and Operational Risk: The Value at Risk Approach

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2009, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Properties of the estimated five-factor model

Estimating a Dynamic Oligopolistic Game with Serially Correlated Unobserved Production Costs. SS223B-Empirical IO

Lecture 9: Markov and Regime

Lecture 8: Markov and Regime

Identifying Long-Run Risks: A Bayesian Mixed-Frequency Approach

The Time-Varying Effects of Monetary Aggregates on Inflation and Unemployment

Optimal Portfolio Choice under Decision-Based Model Combinations

Final Exam Suggested Solutions

Cross-Sectional Distribution of GARCH Coefficients across S&P 500 Constituents : Time-Variation over the Period

Statistical Inference and Methods

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Empirical Analysis of the US Swap Curve Gough, O., Juneja, J.A., Nowman, K.B. and Van Dellen, S.

Components of bull and bear markets: bull corrections and bear rallies

1 Volatility Definition and Estimation

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Modelling Returns: the CER and the CAPM

Model Construction & Forecast Based Portfolio Allocation:

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

1 01/82 01/84 01/86 01/88 01/90 01/92 01/94 01/96 01/98 01/ /98 04/98 07/98 10/98 01/99 04/99 07/99 10/99 01/00

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Web Appendix. Are the effects of monetary policy shocks big or small? Olivier Coibion

Conditional Heteroscedasticity

Omitted Variables Bias in Regime-Switching Models with Slope-Constrained Estimators: Evidence from Monte Carlo Simulations

Financial Econometrics

ARCH and GARCH models

Modelling the Sharpe ratio for investment strategies

Bloomberg. Portfolio Value-at-Risk. Sridhar Gollamudi & Bryan Weber. September 22, Version 1.0

Random Variables and Probability Distributions

Subject CS1 Actuarial Statistics 1 Core Principles. Syllabus. for the 2019 exams. 1 June 2018

Model Estimation. Liuren Wu. Fall, Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College. Liuren Wu Model Estimation Option Pricing, Fall, / 16

Market Risk Analysis Volume I

Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU

THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY ON EMERGING ECONOMIES. A TVP-VAR APPROACH

Lecture 1: The Econometrics of Financial Returns

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios

Thailand Statistician January 2016; 14(1): Contributed paper

Lecture 2: Forecasting stock returns

On modelling of electricity spot price

Market Risk Analysis Volume II. Practical Financial Econometrics

Return Decomposition over the Business Cycle

Beating the market, using linear regression to outperform the market average

Using MCMC and particle filters to forecast stochastic volatility and jumps in financial time series

Internet Appendix for Asymmetry in Stock Comovements: An Entropy Approach

Estimation Appendix to Dynamics of Fiscal Financing in the United States

Online Appendix to ESTIMATING MUTUAL FUND SKILL: A NEW APPROACH. August 2016

Oil Price Volatility and Asymmetric Leverage Effects

Are Stocks Really Less Volatile in the Long Run?

Calibration of Interest Rates

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2012, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

Volatility Risk Pass-Through

A potentially useful approach to model nonlinearities in time series is to assume different behavior (structural break) in different subsamples

Indian Institute of Management Calcutta. Working Paper Series. WPS No. 797 March Implied Volatility and Predictability of GARCH Models

Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk

Statistical Models and Methods for Financial Markets

1 Bayesian Bias Correction Model

GARCH Models. Instructor: G. William Schwert

Discussion Paper No. DP 07/05

Volume 30, Issue 1. Samih A Azar Haigazian University

[D7] PROBABILITY DISTRIBUTION OF OUTSTANDING LIABILITY FROM INDIVIDUAL PAYMENTS DATA Contributed by T S Wright

Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension

Derivation Of The Capital Asset Pricing Model Part I - A Single Source Of Uncertainty

KARACHI UNIVERSITY BUSINESS SCHOOL UNIVERSITY OF KARACHI BS (BBA) VI

**BEGINNING OF EXAMINATION** A random sample of five observations from a population is:

High-Frequency Data Analysis and Market Microstructure [Tsay (2005), chapter 5]

A Hidden Markov Model Approach to Information-Based Trading: Theory and Applications

EE266 Homework 5 Solutions

Keywords: China; Globalization; Rate of Return; Stock Markets; Time-varying parameter regression.

Empirical Distribution Testing of Economic Scenario Generators

Value at Risk Ch.12. PAK Study Manual

Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults

Reading the Tea Leaves: Model Uncertainty, Robust Foreca. Forecasts, and the Autocorrelation of Analysts Forecast Errors

The Two Sample T-test with One Variance Unknown

The change of correlation structure across industries: an analysis in the regime-switching framework

Actuarial Society of India EXAMINATIONS

Online Appendix of. This appendix complements the evidence shown in the text. 1. Simulations

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

Financial Econometrics Notes. Kevin Sheppard University of Oxford

Turbulence, Systemic Risk, and Dynamic Portfolio Construction

This homework assignment uses the material on pages ( A moving average ).

Downside Risk: Implications for Financial Management Robert Engle NYU Stern School of Business Carlos III, May 24,2004

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Fiscal Policy Uncertainty and the Business Cycle: Time Series Evidence from Italy

Master s in Financial Engineering Foundations of Buy-Side Finance: Quantitative Risk and Portfolio Management. > Teaching > Courses

Volatility Models and Their Applications

Transcription:

Internet Appendix for: Sequential Learning, Predictability, and Optimal Portfolio Returns MICHAEL JOHANNES, ARTHUR KORTEWEG, and NICHOLAS POLSON Section I of this Internet Appendix describes the full set of parameter estimates for the four Bayesian models (CV, CV-DC, SV, and SV-DC). Section II shows the simulation results used to determine statistical significance. Section III describes the portfolio weights for both cash dividends and net payout yields. Section IV shows the conditional and unconditional excess market return distributions. Section V describes the particle filter algorithms for the four Bayesian models in detail, and Section VI explains the calculation of Savage Density ratios for the hypothesis tests in Figure IA.. Citation format: Johannes, Michael, Arthur Korteweg, and Nicholas Polson, Internet Appendix for Sequential Learning, Predictability, and Optimal Portfolio Returns, Journal of Finance. Please note: Wiley-Blackwell is not responsible for the content or functionality of any supporting information supplied by the authors. Any queries (other than missing material) should be directed to the authors of the article.

I. Full Parameter Estimates A. CV Model The CV model jointly specifies the process for returns and payout ratios, as shown in equations (2) and (7) in the published article, where the volatilities are assumed to be constant. Figure IA. shows the sequential parameter estimates of the CV model, using the cash dividend yield as the predictor variable, x t. For each parameter, we summarize the posterior distribution at each point in time via its mean (the solid line) and a (, 99) % posterior probability interval (the shaded area). The figure reveals wide posterior bands at the beginning of the sample, consistent with the relatively uninformative priors from the generally short training sample. As new data arrive, the investor s view of the location and uncertainty of the parameters changes drastically. the returns equation declines substantially over time. Most notably, the volatility in This is merely an implication of the large fluctuations in market volatility, which are easiest to detect when the sample starts in a period of high volatility, such as the 927 to 93 period. Since nearly all studies begin in 926, discarding the data and starting after World War II merely generates additional sample selection issues with regard to volatility. The perceived equity premium is E [α + βx t y t ]. Interestingly, there is little significant variation in the location of α and β although the posterior confidence bands are naturally much tighter towards the end of the sample. The estimates of β follow the general pattern of the OLS estimates in Figure of the main paper. Regarding the dividend yield process, estimates of β x trend upwards, although the 2

.2 α.5 β...2.5 α x β x...95.2.9 σ.5.4.3.2 93938 948 958 968 978 988 998 28.92.94.96.98 ρ 93938 948 958 968 978 988 998 28 Figure IA.. Sequential parameter estimates: CV model with dividend yield. This figure plots sequential parameter estimates for the CV model, r t+ = α + βx t + σε r t+ x t+ = α x + β x x t + σ x ε x t+, where r t+ is the return on the market portfolio in excess of the risk-free rate from month t to month t +. The predictor variable, x t, is the traditional cash dividend yield. The shocks ε r t+ and ε x t+ are distributed standard normal with correlation coefficient ρ. Each panel displays the posterior means and (,99)% posterior probability intervals (the grey shaded area) for each time period. Excess market return volatility, σ, is annualized. 3

.2 α. β.5..5.5.5..5 α x β x.5.2.98.5.96..94 σ ρ.5.5.4.3.2.5 93 937 947 957 967 977 987 997 27 93 937 947 957 967 977 987 997 27 Figure IA.2. Sequential parameter estimates: CV model with net payout yield. This figure plots sequential parameter estimates for the CV model, r t+ = α + βx t + σε r t+ x t+ = α x + β x x t + σ x ε x t+, where r t+ is the return on the market portfolio in excess of the risk-free rate from month t to month t +. The predictor variable, x t, is the net payout yield of Boudoukh et al. (27). The shocks ε r t+ and ε x t+ are distributed standard normal with correlation coefficient ρ. Each panel displays the posterior means and (,99)% posterior probability intervals (the grey shaded area) for each time period. Excess market return volatility, σ, is annualized. 4

movement is not large. Brav et al. (25) present evidence that the speed of mean reversion for dividends has slowed in the second half of the 2th century, making dividend yields more persistent. If so, our results indicate the rate of structural change is rather slow, inconsistent with either a regime-switching or an abrupt structural break model. Figure IA.2 uses the net payout yield as the predictor variable. There are a number of important differences. Although the estimates of α, β, andσ are quite similar, the estimates for the payout ratio series are not. There is an abrupt change in the parameters of the net payout process in the early 98s, in particular, in α x, β x,andρ. This result is suggestive of a structural break in the dynamics of net payouts, something more substantial than just parameter uncertainty. Interestingly, Boudoukh et al. (27) formally test for a structural break and find no evidence; however, we use monthly data, whereas they focus on annual data. The source of the variation can be found in Figure of the main paper, where we can see that in the early 98s the net payout variable had a series of high frequency shocks. The net effect of making the process less persistent is that it reduces the autocorrelation (β x ). These high frequency fluctuations have an even greater impact on ρ, as the relatively stable link between payout ratio shocks and market returns is broken. The source of these shocks is a sudden increase in net repurchases, which no doubt corresponds to a structural economic change following the adoption in 982 of SEC rule b-8, providing safe harbor from liability for firms repurchasing shares in accordance with the rule s conditions. To formally assess the strength of predictability, Figure IA.3 summarizes the posterior probabilities in the benchmark model for tests of β =andβ dp = the unit root case. Using our particle filter, we calculate the Bayes factor for H : β =versush : β as 5

Posterior probability of no predictability (β=) Posterior probability of unit root in predictor (β =) x CV.5 Dividend yield Net payout.5 CV DC.5.5 SV.5.5 SV DC.5.5 93938 948 958 968 978 988 998 28 93938 948 958 968 978 988 998 28 Figure IA.3. Hypothesis tests. This figure plots posterior probabilities for hypothesis tests of no predictability (left-hand-side plots) and a unit root in the predictor process (right-hand-side plots). The predictor variable is either dividend yield (solid line) or net payout yield (striped line). CV and SV represent models with expected return predictability and constant volatility (CV) and stochastic volatility (SV), respectively. DC stands for drifting coefficients and represents models where the predictability coefficient is allowed to vary over time. The null hypothesis for no predictability is H : β = in the CV and SV models or H : β + β t = in the DC and SV-DC models. The null hypothesis for a unit root in the predictor process is H : β x =. 6

follows: BF t, = p (β = yt, H ) p (β = H ) N ( ) N p β = θ (i),s (i) t,y t, H. p (β = H ) Here p(β θ (i),s (i) t,y t ) is the normal distribution (see Section D) and θ (i) is the filtered parameter vector for particle i at time t. Since we use a Bayesian regression to train the prior, the denominator is easy to calculate from p (β H ), which is a Student t distribution. The calculation for H : β dp = is analogous. For more details on calculating Bayes factors, see Section E of this appendix. i= For the traditional dividend yield measure in the top-left panel of Figure IA.3, we find that there is little statistical evidence in favor of predictability. In the net payout data, the posterior probability of H : β = slowly decreases to around 2% as parameter uncertainty decreases, but the decline in the predictability coefficient starting in the early 99s reverses this trend, and ends up around 7%. This confirms the findings Boudoukh et al. (27), as the weight of evidence against the hypothesis that β = is much stronger using net payouts instead of the traditional cash dividend yield measure. The posterior probability of a unit root in dividend yields fluctuates significantly for the benchmark model, but the results generally favor a unit root and for net payout yield there is little evidence of any nonstationarity. B. CV-DC Model Figure IA.4 shows the parameter estimates for the drifting coefficients (CV-DC) model in equations (5) through (7) in the main article, using the cash dividend yield as predictor and assuming constant variances. In this model predictability consists of two components, 7

a long-run average, β, and a time-varying component, β t, with expected excess returns given by E [α +(β + β t )x t y t ]. The long-run average predictability, β, is statistically indistinguishable from zero for virtually the entire sample period, as shown by the (, 99) % posterior probability interval. The time-varying component, β t, reveals substantial variation around the long-run average. Figure IA.6 shows that this variation is related to real GDP growth, with β t higher in recessions and lower in expansions (Henkel, Martin, and Nardari (2); Dangl and Halling (22) also document this countercyclicality). However, the variation is not economically large and rarely statistically significant. The β t process is highly persistent, with an autoregressive coefficient β β of about.97, and the volatility of the shocks, σ β, is around.. The posterior probability for the hypothesis test β + β t = is analyzed in Figure IA.3. The probability is close to one for the entire sample, strongly supporting no predictability. This pattern in predictability from the CV-DC model is distinctly different from that of the cumulative OLS regressions in Figure of the main text and the benchmark model in Figure IA.. The results for the net payout measure in Figure IA.5 are closer to the CV model. Figure IA.3 shows that the posterior probability of the null tracks closely with the benchmark model. At one point in the late 96s, there was strong evidence for predictability, but that predictability quickly vanished in the 97s. The posterior probability of no predictability has remained between 5% and 9% since then. The long-run average predictability, β,is high compared to the dividend yield variable, and is close to the estimate of β x in the CV model. The time-varying component is stable, showing little variation around the long-run 8

..5 α.4.2 β..5 β t.5..2.5. α x β x β β..2.98.96.94.2.98.96.94 σ.5.4.3.2 933 948 963 978 993 28.92.94.96.98 933 948 963 978 993 28 ρ.8.6.4.2.8 x 3 σ β 933 948 963 978 993 28 Figure IA.4. Sequential parameter estimates: CV-DC model with dividend yield. This figure plots sequential parameter estimates for the drifting coefficients model using the traditional dividend yield as predictor. The time-varying predictability coefficient follows an AR() process, β t+ = β β β t + σ β ε β t+. The other coefficients are as defined in figure IA.. Each panel displays the posterior means and (,99)% posterior credible intervals for each time period. Return volatility is annualized. 9

α. β 5 x 3 β t.5..5.5.5 5 α x β x β β.2.5..98.96.94.8 σ.6.5.4.3.2 93394896397899327 ρ.5.5 93394896397899327 x 3.8.6.4.2.8 σ β.6 93394896397899327 Figure IA.5. Sequential parameter estimates: CV-DC model with net payout yield. This figure plots sequential parameter estimates for the drifting coefficients model using the net payout yield as predictor. The time-varying predictability coefficient follows an AR() process, β t+ = β β β t + σ β ε β t+. The other coefficients are as defined in figure IA.2. Each panel displays the posterior means and (,99)% posterior credible intervals for each time period. Return volatility is annualized.

.3.25.2.5..5.5 Dividend yield data β t (CV DC) β t (SV DC) real GDP growth. 93 938 948 958 968 978 988 998 28 3 x 3 Net payout yield data 2 2 3 93 938 948 958 968 978 988 998 27 Figure IA.6. Drifting predictability coefficient. This figure depicts time series plots of the posterior mean of β t, the drifting component of the predictability coefficient, plotted against real GDP growth (normalized to have the same standard deviation as β t ). The grey shaded areas are NBER peak-to-trough recessions. The top plot uses the traditional cash dividend yield as the predictor variable, whereas the bottom plot uses the net payout yield. The CV-DC model has constant volatility and the SV-DC model has stochastic volatility.

mean for most of the sample. The total predictability coefficient, β + β t, therefore hovers very closely around the CV estimate. Investors learn about the level of long-term predictability, β, as evidenced by the tightening (, 99) % bounds in Figures IA.4 and IA.5. The bounds for the time-varying component, β t, tighten only slightly over the sample period, and only to the extent that investors learn about β β and σ β, the parameters that govern the process of the time-varying coefficient. In other words, investors learn the long-run mean predictability and the process of the time-varying component, but never learn the exact predictability coefficient at a given point in time. The economic implication is that learning remains important in drifting coefficient models, even in very large data sets, whereas the effects of learning on portfolio formation wanes over time in constant coefficient models (such as our CV model). This is true in general for models with unobserved and time-varying state variables. C. SV Model Figure IA.7 displays the stochastic volatility (SV) model estimates using cash dividends. This model is expressed in equations (2) and (7) in the main article. It has constant regression coefficients, like the benchmark model, but allows for stochastic volatility in both the excess return and payout yield equations. The posterior mean estimates of the regression coefficients, α, β, α x,andβ x, are different from those obtained in the constant volatility (CV) model due to the GLS versus OLS distinction, where periods of high volatility are down-weighted in the SV model but not in the CV model. 2

.. α.2.2 β.8.6.4.2 exp(v r t / 2) α x β x exp(v x / 2) t..2.95.9.8.6.4.2 α r β r σ r.5.9.3.25.8.2 α v β v σ v.5 93394896397899328.9.8 93394896397899328.3.25.2 93394896397899328 Figure IA.7. Sequential parameter estimates: SV model with dividend yield. This figure plots sequential parameter estimates for the SV model using the traditional dividend yield as predictor. The log-volatilities follow AR() processes Vt+ r = α r + β r Vt r + σ r ηt+ r Vt+ x = α v + β v Vt x + σ v ηt+ v. All other parameters are as in figure IA.. Each panel displays the posterior means and (,99)% posterior credible intervals for each time period. Return and dividend yield volatilities are annualized. 3

α β exp(v r t / 2)...5.5.6.4.2 α x β x exp(v x / 2) t..2.95.9.85.6.4.2.5.5.5 α r.9.8 β r.35.3.25.2 σ r α v.5.5.5 93394896397899327 β v.9.8 93394896397899327 σ v.3.25.2 93394896397899327 Figure IA.8. Sequential parameter estimates: SV model with net payout yield. This figure plots sequential parameter estimates for the SV model using the net payout yield as predictor. The logvolatilities follow AR() processes Vt+ r = α r + β r Vt r + σ rηt+ r Vt+ x = α v + β v Vt x + σ v ηt+ v. All other parameters are as in figure IA.2. Each panel displays the posterior means and (,99)% posterior credible intervals for each time period. Return and net payout yield volatilities are annualized. 4

Excess return volatility, V r, is high in the 93s, during the oil crisis of the 97s, during the crash of 987, in the Internet period 997 to 2, and during the credit crisis of 28. Dividend yield volatility, V x, is high in the 93s and during the 97s and early 98s. The volatility processes of excess returns and dividend yields are very persistent, with autoregressive coefficients around.95. In comparison, Markov Chain Monte Carlo (MCMC) estimates of the autoregressive coefficient of excess return volatility are around.98 (Johannes, Polson, and Stroud (22)). For the net payout data, excess return volatility shows the same pattern as cash dividends, but the volatility for the predictor variable exhibits a different pattern. In contrast to dividend yield, net payout volatility is low in the 93s but high during the early 2s, when dividends remained stable but issuances and repurchases spiked (Boudoukh et al. (27)). There are two extreme volatility spikes, in the early 98s and in 2. The volatility shocks absorb the large shocks to net payouts during that period, and α x, β x, and ρ do not show the breaks that we find in the CV and CV-DC models. D. SV-DC Model Both features of the SV and DC models are present in the full-fledged SV-DC model in equations (5) through (7) in the published article. Figures IA.9 and IA. show sequential parameter estimates of the SV-DC model using the cash dividend yield and the net payout yield, respectively, as the predictor variable. For the dividend yield estimates in Figure IA.9, the most notable difference is that the process for β t is slightly less persistent (i.e., the autoregressive coefficient β β is lower), which causes shocks to β t to dissipate faster. The 5

.2.. α.4.2.2 β 5 5 x 3 β t α x β x β β..2.95.9.2.8.8.6.4.2 exp(v r t / 2).8.6.4.2 exp(v x / 2) t.8 x σ β 3.6.4.2.8 93394896397899328 α r β r σ r.5.5.9.8.3.25.2 α v β v σ v.5.5 93394896397899328.9.8 93394896397899328.3.25.2 93394896397899328 Figure IA.9. Sequential parameter estimates: SV-DC model with dividend yield. This figure plots sequential parameter estimates for the stochastic volatility and drifting coefficients model using the traditional dividend yield as predictor. The parameters are as defined in figures IA.4 and IA.7. Each panel displays the posterior means and (,99)% posterior credible intervals for each time period. Return and dividend yield volatilities are annualized. 6

.2.. α..5.5 β 5 5 x 3 β t α x β x β β..2.5.95.9.85.8 exp(v r t / 2) exp(v x / 2) t x 3 σ β.5.5 2.5 93394896397899327 α r β r σ r.5.5.5.9.8.35.3.25.2 α v.5.5.5 93394896397899327 β v.9.8 93394896397899327.3 σ v.2 93394896397899327 Figure IA.. Sequential parameter estimates: SV-DC model with net payout yield. This figure plots sequential parameter estimates for the stochastic volatility and drifting coefficients model using the net payout yield as predictor. The parameters are as defined in figures IA.5 and IA.8. Each panel displays the posterior means and (,99)% posterior credible intervals for each time period. Return and net payout yield volatilities are annualized. 7

evidence for or against predictability is quite volatile, as both volatility and the regression coefficients move over time. At the end of the sample, there is very strong evidence against predictability, using either data set. II. Simulation Results for Statistical Significance To judge statistical significance, we simulate 5 data sets of a model that has no predictability by construction: r t+ = α + σε r t+ x t+ = α x + β x x t + σ x ε x t+. (IA.) (IA.2) We calibrate the model to the observed data, generating returns and predictors with the same expected returns and variances as our empirical data set. The predictors are also calibrated to have the same autocorrelation as we observe in the data. We then estimate our various models on the simulated data sets and report the mean certainty equivalent return and Sharpe ratio, as well as the 9th and 95th percentiles across data sets. Tables IA.I and IA.II show the results for the simulated dividend yield and net payout yield, respectively. In Tables IA.III and IA.IV we perform a similar exercise for dividend yield and net payout yield, respectively, but we simulate data with stochastic volatility in both the returns and the predictor variables while maintaining no predictability by construction. We chose 8

Table IA.I Statistical Significance: Dividend Yield Data This table reports summary statistics of annualized certainty equivalent returns (Panel A) and monthly Sharpe ratios (Panel B) across 5 simulated data sets for a power utility investor with risk aversion γ. Simulated data sets are of the same size, and the same means and covariances, as the empirical data set, but with no predictability. The top line for each model shows the mean statistic across data sets, followed by the 9th and 95th percentiles. Panel A: Certainty equivalent returns (in % per annum) γ =4 γ =6 m y 2y m y 2y CV-CM mean 2.6 4. 4. 3.26 3.93 3.93 9th percentile 5.85 5.92 5.92 5.2 5.6 5.6 95th percentile 6.2 6.7 6.7 5.35 5.3 5.3 CV-OLS mean -4.84-4.73-4.85-3.45-4. -6.45 9th percentile 5.9 5.3 5.3 4.68 4.74 4.75 95th percentile 5.99 5.9 5.92 5.22 5.5 5.5 CV-rolling OLS mean -23.84-23.88-25.3-42.46-45.95-47.55 9th percentile -8.95-8.69-9.54-2.69-3.28-4.58 95th percentile -6.5-6.33-7.3-9.96 -.7 -.53 CV mean -3.89 3.66 3.5-2.32 3.63 3.48 9th percentile 5.47 5.84 5.84 4.87 5.8 5. 95th percentile 6.6 6.3 6.3 5.32 5.42 5.42 CV-DC mean -5.9 4.49 4.53 -.7 4.4 4.7 9th percentile 5.9 5.9 5.92 4.59 5.8 5.6 95th percentile 5.74 6.8 6.9 5.5 5.34 5.37 SV-CM mean 4.37 5.2 5.2 4. 4.64 4.65 9th percentile 5.89 6. 6. 5.4 5.26 5.26 95th percentile 6.3 6.25 6.25 5.3 5.36 5.37 SV mean 3.32 5. 5. 3.8 4.57 4.57 9th percentile 5.55 6.3 6.34 4.88 5.42 5.43 95th percentile 6. 6.5 6.53 5.7 5.55 5.56 SV-DC mean -.2 5. 5. -.84 4.53 4.52 9th percentile 5.8 6. 6.7 4.64 5.3 5.26 95th percentile 5.78 6.42 6.37 5.4 5.49 5.45 9

Panel B: Sharpe ratios (monthly) γ =4 γ =6 m y 2y m y 2y CV-CM mean.86.93.93.86.93.93 9th percentile.25.28.28.24.29.29 95th percentile.33.36.36.33.36.36 CV-OLS mean.59.72.72.59.7.7 9th percentile..7.6.8.6.6 95th percentile.26.29.3.25.29.3 CV-rolling OLS mean.63.7.72.59.67.68 9th percentile.8.4.4.4.9. 95th percentile.2.23.23.7.2.2 CV mean.72.85.86.7.85.85 9th percentile.8.24.26.8.25.26 95th percentile.3.36.35.3.35.35 CV-DC mean.68.89.9.67.88.89 9th percentile.3.24.26.2.25.27 95th percentile.23.34.35.23.34.35 SV-CM mean.88.3.4.86.2.2 9th percentile.29.32.32.29.32.32 95th percentile.37.4.4.37.39.4 SV mean.73.99..7.98.99 9th percentile.7.38.38.6.37.38 95th percentile.26.43.43.25.43.43 SV-DC mean.64.96.96.63.95.95 9th percentile.3.33.33.3.34.33 95th percentile.22.42.42.22.42.42 2

Table IA.II Statistical Significance: Net Payout Yield Data This table reports summary statistics of annualized certainty equivalent returns (Panel A) and monthly Sharpe ratios (Panel B) across 5 simulated data sets for a power utility investor with risk aversion γ. Simulated data sets are of the same size, and the same means and covariances, as the empirical data set, but with no predictability. The top line for each model shows the mean statistic across data sets, followed by the 9th and 95th percentiles. Panel A: Certainty equivalent returns (in % per annum) γ =4 γ =6 m y 2y m y 2y CV-OLS mean -5. -.24 -.2-7.5-6.44-6.39 9th percentile 5.68 6.32 6.3 5.2 5.42 5.43 95th percentile 6.33 6.74 6.75 5.47 5.7 5.73 CV-rolling OLS mean -2.88-7.6-6.56-4.85-4.6-4.4 9th percentile -5.4-4.2-3.94-8.75-6.88-6.7 95th percentile -3. -.7 -.64-5.68-4.8-4.64 CV mean -3.8 4.43 4.53-3.97 4.2 4.26 9th percentile 6. 6.42 6.43 5.27 5.49 5.5 95th percentile 6.56 6.79 6.78 5.59 5.74 5.76 CV-DC mean -4.8 4.94 5. -3.59 4.47 4.54 9th percentile 5.68 6.35 6.34 4.99 5.45 5.45 95th percentile 6.9 6.75 6.75 5.34 5.73 5.7 SV mean 4.32 5.72 5.72 3.92 5. 5.2 9th percentile 6.9 6.74 6.74 5.29 5.7 5.7 95th percentile 6.49 6.89 6.9 5.52 5.82 5.83 SV-DC mean.54 5.58 5.55.6 4.92 4.9 9th percentile 5.63 6.59 6.55 4.97 5.62 5.59 95th percentile 6.8 6.83 6.76 5.33 5.79 5.73 2

Panel B: Sharpe ratios (monthly) γ =4 γ =6 m y 2y m y 2y CV-OLS mean.69.88.89.68.87.87 9th percentile.2.35.35.9.34.35 95th percentile.35.45.45.35.45.45 CV-rolling OLS mean.79.88.88.76.84.84 9th percentile.23.27.27.9.2.2 95th percentile.32.37.37.28.32.32 CV mean.83.2.3.82.2.2 9th percentile.29.42.42.29.42.42 95th percentile.42.5.5.42.5.5 CV-DC mean.78.4.5.77.4.4 9th percentile.24.42.43.23.42.43 95th percentile.34.52.53.34.5.52 SV mean.9.2.2.88.2.2 9th percentile.28.5.5.28.5.5 95th percentile.4.57.56.4.58.57 SV-DC mean.77.7.6.75.6.6 9th percentile.2.49.49.2.5.5 95th percentile.29.55.54.29.55.56 22

Table IA.III Statistical Significance: Dividend Yield Data with Stochastic Volatility This table reports summary statistics of annualized certainty equivalent returns (Panel A) and monthly Sharpe ratios (Panel B) across 5 simulated data sets for a power utility investor with risk aversion coefficient γ. The simulated data sets are of the same size and with the same means as the empirical data set, but with no predictability. Stochastic volatility parameters are calibrated to match the observed data. The top line for each model shows the mean statistic across data sets, followed by the 9th and 95th percentiles. Panel A: Certainty equivalent returns (in % per annum) γ =4 γ =6 m y 2y m y 2y CV-CM mean.5 2.99 2.99.84 3.42 3.42 9th percentile 5.83 5.83 5.83 5.9 5. 5. 95th percentile 6.3 6.7 6.7 5.29 5.27 5.27 CV-OLS mean -6.57-6.62-7.78-6.48-4.88-5.98 9th percentile 5.2 5.3 5.34 4.67 4.74 4.76 95th percentile 5.7 5.7 5.67 5. 4.98 4.99 CV-rolling OLS mean -24.42-24.95-25.94-45. -57.23-59.25 9th percentile -7.7-6.99-7.47 -.8 -.48 -.85 95th percentile -4.5-3.87-4.2-8.5-6.93-7.5 CV mean -5.49 2.78 2.54-4.25 3.5 2.85 9th percentile 5.48 5.66 5.67 4.85 4.99 4.98 95th percentile 5.9 6. 6.2 5.4 5.23 5.23 CV-DC mean -7.2 4.37 4.42-5.65 4.6 4. 9th percentile 5.5 5.66 5.66 4.59 4.98 4.98 95th percentile 5.54 5.93 5.92 4.89 5.6 5.5 SV-CM mean 4.24 5.6 5.6 3.92 4.62 4.62 9th percentile 5.88 6.3 6.3 5.2 5.22 5.22 95th percentile 6.6 6.26 6.26 5.3 5.37 5.37 SV mean 2.66 5.8 5.9 2.3 4.57 4.57 9th percentile 5.5 6.4 6.6 4.8 5.23 5.25 95th percentile 5.87 6.38 6.38 5.9 5.46 5.49 SV-DC mean -.95 5.3 5. -4.33 4.5 4.5 9th percentile 5.32 6.5 6. 4.75 5.3 5.27 95th percentile 5.85 6.43 6.39 5.9 5.49 5.47 23

Panel B: Sharpe ratios (monthly) γ =4 γ =6 m y 2y m y 2y CV-CM mean.84.9.9.84.9.9 9th percentile.27.3.3.28.3.3 95th percentile.35.37.37.35.37.37 CV-OLS mean.52.67.67.5.66.66 9th percentile.8.3.4.8.3.4 95th percentile.2.25.25.2.24.24 CV-rolling OLS mean.6.69.7.57.65.66 9th percentile.7.2.3.5.8.9 95th percentile.2.2.22.6.8.8 CV mean.66.82.82.65.8.8 9th percentile.8.22.23.7.22.24 95th percentile.28.34.35.27.36.36 CV-DC mean.6.85.86.6.84.85 9th percentile..23.23..23.24 95th percentile.23.32.32.2.32.32 SV-CM mean.85..2.84.. 9th percentile.27.3.3.27.32.32 95th percentile.34.38.38.35.37.37 SV mean.69...67.99.99 9th percentile.4.35.36.3.35.35 95th percentile.26.42.43.25.4.42 SV-DC mean.65.99.98.63.98.97 9th percentile.6.38.37.6.37.38 95th percentile.27.45.46.26.45.46 24

Table IA.IV Statistical Significance: Net Payout Yield Data with Stochastic Volatility This table reports summary statistics of annualized certainty equivalent returns (Panel A) and monthly Sharpe ratios (Panel B) across 5 simulated data sets for a power utility investor with risk aversion coefficient γ. The simulated data sets are of the same size and with the same means as the empirical data set, but with no predictability. Stochastic volatility parameters are calibrated to match the observed data. The top line for each model shows the mean statistic across data sets, followed by the 9th and 95th percentiles. Panel A: Certainty equivalent returns (in % per annum) γ =4 γ =6 m y 2y m y 2y CV-OLS mean -6.54-3.47-2.89-8.54-6.78-4.42 9th percentile 5.69 6.6 6.7 5. 5.34 5.33 95th percentile 6. 6.6 6.64 5.28 5.6 5.63 CV-rolling OLS mean -2.64-8.38-7.74-4.95-39.35-36.99 9th percentile -4. -3.27-3.9-6.95-5.4-4.97 95th percentile -2.22 -.59 -.53-5. -3.83-3.78 CV mean -5.69 4.3 4.36-5.33 4.8 4. 9th percentile 5.96 6.35 6.36 5.9 5.46 5.47 95th percentile 6.4 6.72 6.74 5.49 5.7 5.72 CV-DC mean -6.6 4.9 4.96-6.64 4.43 4.49 9th percentile 5.77 6.3 6.3 5.8 5.45 5.43 95th percentile 6.26 6.65 6.65 5.42 5.65 5.66 SV mean 3.9 5.65 5.66 3.6 4.97 4.97 9th percentile 6.6 6.76 6.74 5.3 5.7 5.73 95th percentile 6.56 7.5 7.2 5.59 5.93 5.93 SV-DC mean -.36 5.56 5.53-3.47 4.9 4.89 9th percentile 5.97 6.6 6.54 5.9 5.62 5.59 95th percentile 6.5 6.88 6.79 5.53 5.79 5.75 25

Panel B: Sharpe ratios (monthly) γ =4 γ =6 m y 2y m y 2y CV-OLS mean.67.86.87.67.85.86 9th percentile.22.36.37.2.35.37 95th percentile.32.46.46.32.46.46 CV-rolling OLS mean.8.89.89.77.85.85 9th percentile.2.3.3.8.25.26 95th percentile.32.4.4.28.34.34 CV mean.82...8.. 9th percentile.3.4.4.3.4.4 95th percentile.4.5.5.4.5.5 CV-DC mean.78.4.4.77.3.4 9th percentile.25.39.4.25.39.4 95th percentile.34.5.49.34.5.5 SV mean.89.8.9.86.8.8 9th percentile.33.53.53.32.53.52 95th percentile.43.58.58.42.58.59 SV-DC mean.78.6.6.76.5.5 9th percentile.28.49.48.28.48.49 95th percentile.39.55.55.38.56.55 26

the parameters of the volatility processes to match the empirical data, with autoregressive coefficients equal to.98, and matching the long-run mean of the volatility process to the unconditional volatility in the data. III. Portfolio Weights Figures IA. and IA.2 provide a term structure perspective on the portfolio weights. The figures display the portfolio weights on different dates for different models and investment horizons. The various models can generate very different long-horizon moments and return distributions, due to the time-varying state variables, estimation risk, and predictability. The differences arise because parameter uncertainty and mean-reversion (in expected returns and volatilities) impacts predictive moments differently as a function of investment horizon. Table IA.V reports means and standard deviations of the portfolio weights, as well as correlations between the weights and the latent volatility states from the SV model, for γ = 4. The broad patterns are quite clear. First, the correlation between the portfolio weights in the SV models and actual volatility is negative and much higher (in an absolute sense) than in the constant volatility models. This clearly demonstrates the volatility timing result from using models with stochastic volatility. Second, the stochastic volatility To calculate the correlation between portfolio weights and the volatility state, we omitted the first years when there is still a lot of updating about the mean and variance in the constant model that can introduce a spurious correlation. 27

Portfolio weight 3 2.5 2.5 Jan 93, dp = 3.2 CV CV DC SV SV DC CV OLS 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Jan 94, dp = 3.6.5.4.3.2 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Jan 95, dp = 2.79.2.8.6.4 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Portfolio weight Jan 96, dp = 3.39.8.6.4.2 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Jan 97, dp = 3.35.2.8.6.4.2 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Jan 98, dp = 3.7.6.4.2.8.6 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Jan 99, dp = 3.3 Jan 2, dp = 4.3 Dec 27, dp = 3.98 Portfolio weight.5.6.4.2.2.8.6.4 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Horizon (years) 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Horizon (years) 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Horizon (years) Figure IA.. Optimal portfolio weights by investor horizon: dividend yield data. This figure plots optimal portfolio weights for an investor who allocates wealth between the market portfolio of stocks and a risk-free one-period bond, with an investment horizon spanning from one to years. The plots show the optimal weights on the stock portfolio at the beginning of each decade in our sample period, as well as at the final datapoint in our sample (December 28, bottom-right plot). The investor has power utility with risk aversion γ = 4, and rebalances annually while accounting for all parameter and state uncertainty. CV and SV represent models with expected return predictability and constant volatility (CV) and stochastic volatility (SV), respectively. DC stands for drifting coefficients and represents models where the predictability coefficient is allowed to vary over time. CV-OLS uses the OLS point estimates of equation () in the published paper, with data up to time t. 28

.2...2.5.5 Jan 93, dp = 2.5 bench DC SV SVDC Cum OLS 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Jan 96, dp = 2.6 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9.4.2.8.6.4.2 Jan 99, dp = 2.2 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9.35.3.25.2.8.6.4.2.2.2 Jan 94, dp =.94 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Jan 97, dp = 2.6 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Jan 2, dp = 2.76.4 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Jan 95, dp =.89.7.6.5 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Jan 98, dp = 2..6.4.2.8 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Dec 28, dp = 2.2.8.6.4 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Figure IA.2. Optimal portfolio weights by investor horizon: net payout yield data. This figure plots optimal portfolio weights for an investor who allocates wealth between the market portfolio of stocks and a risk-free one-period bond, with an investment horizon spanning from one to years. The plots show the optimal weights on the stock portfolio at the beginning of each decade in our sample period, as well as at the final datapoint in our sample (December 28, bottom-right plot). The investor has power utility with risk aversion γ = 4, and rebalances annually while accounting for all parameter and state uncertainty. CV and SV represent models with expected return predictability and constant volatility (CV) and stochastic volatility (SV), respectively. DC stands for drifting coefficients and represents models where the predictability coefficient is allowed to vary over time. CV-OLS uses the OLS point estimates of equation () in the published paper, with data up to time t. 29

Table IA.V Portfolio Weights Statistics, γ =4 This table reports basic statistics of portfolio weights across models and investment horizons, for a power utility investor with risk aversion coefficient γ. The columns mean and std show the mean and standard deviation of portfolio weights across all months in our sample. The column corr shows the correlation coefficient between portfolio weights and the conditional volatility state from the SV model, after a burn-in period of years. Panel A: Dividend yield data m y 2y mean std corr mean std corr mean std corr Constant volatility models CV-CM.4.8 -.3.4.6 -.9.4.6 -.9 CV-OLS.4.27 -..3.3.7.33.36.8 CV-rolling OLS.23.85 -..46.8 -.2.54.8 -. CV.26.26..28.9.6.3.2.6 CV-DC.9.46.8.22.27.3.9.26.3 Stochastic volatility models SV-CM.9.56 -.42.75.28 -.8.75.28 -.8 SV.88.5 -.59.57.24 -.25.59.25 -.26 SV-DC.75.7 -.43.4.26 -.2.3.22 -.2 Panel B: Net payout yield data m y 2y mean std corr mean std corr mean std corr Constant volatility models CV-OLS..33 -.22.25.29 -.2.27.3 -.3 CV-rolling OLS.39.72 -.6.55.62 -.9.57.62 -.9 CV.23.33 -.22.26.27 -.2.27.28 -.2 CV-DC.2.37 -.25.23.26 -.6.24.27 -.6 Stochastic volatility models SV.64.64 -.46.43.34 -.29.47.36 -.29 SV-DC.78.62 -.53.5.27 -.34.54.29 -.34 3

models generally have higher average weights than the constant volatility models (ignoring the CV-rolling OLS results). This result occurs for two reasons: () the stochastic volatility models can take significantly larger positions when volatility is low than the constant volatility models (portfolio weights increase convexly as volatility falls), and (2) volatility estimates in constant volatility models trend down for the first portion of the sample, as realized equity volatility fell in the 94s, 95s, and 96s. The constant volatility models just cannot handle persistent changes in volatility. In the dividend yield model, the SV model also has higher forecasts of expected returns for much of the sample. Third, constant mean models (for both stochastic and constant volatility specifications) have slightly higher average portfolio weights than the models with predictability. This is likely due to a combination of slightly less parameter uncertainty and drifting in predictability coefficients (see, for example, Figure of the published paper). IV. Conditional and Unconditional Return Distributions We analyze the conditional and unconditional moments of the excess market return distribution from the various models through the use of two sets of simulations. We simulate, one-month returns from the conditional distribution of the excess market returns using a two-step approach. First, we randomly draw a set of parameters from the joint posterior distribution of parameters at the midpoint of the sample time series (December 3

967). Second, we draw a return conditional on the set of parameters, where we set the state variables (payout yields and volatility states) equal to their sample means. 2 Thus, the simulated distribution is conditional in the sense that it conditions on specific values of the state variables, while fully reflecting the effects of parameter uncertainty. Given that the distribution absent uncertainty should be normal by assumption, this distribution is useful to gauge the impact of uncertainty about parameters and latent volatility states. The second set of simulations is set up to analyze the unconditional return distribution from the models. We simulate a time series of, returns, starting the payout yield and volatility states at their sample means, and simulating them forward (rather than resetting them to their sample means for each draw, as we did when sampling the conditional return distribution). Hence, this procedure involves an additional step compared to the simulation of the conditional return distribution above. The unconditional distribution not only fully reflects the effects of parameter uncertainty, but also, for the models with stochastic volatility, uncertainty about latent volatility states. Tables IA.VI and IA.VII show the results. The conditional and unconditional return distributions for the models with constant volatility (CV-CM, CV-OLS, CV-rolling, CV, and CV-DC) are similar, with kurtosis slightly above three, and skewness that tends to be slightly positive. Across all models, the rolling OLS model has the worst fit. In contrast, the unconditional distributions for the stochastic volatility models (SV-CM, SV, SV-DC, and SV-corr) have considerably larger variance and kurtosis than the conditional distributions. 2 Note that the specification of the model in equation (2) of the paper requires simulating the volatility state one month ahead. 32

Table IA.VI Conditional and Unconditional Return Distributions: Dividend Yield Data This table reports moments of the unconditional and conditional annualized excess market return distribution (where. = %), based on the posterior distribution of parameters at the midpoint of the sample time series (December 967). The top row shows the moments of the data. For each of the models, the moments of the unconditional excess return distribution are calculated from a time series of, simulated returns. The conditional excess return distribution is calculated from, draws of one-month returns, with state variables (dividend yield and volatilities) set equal to their long-run means. Both distributions fully reflect the effects of parameter uncertainty and the uncertainty about latent volatility states, where applicable. kurt is kurtosis (where the Normal distribution has kurtosis of three). Unconditional excess returns Conditional excess returns mean st.dev. skew kurt mean st.dev. skew kurt data.56.9 -.535 9.528 - - - - Constant Volatility models CV-CM.7.22. 3.35.7.22. 3.35 CV-OLS.72.25. 3.5.72.25. 3.5 CV-rolling OLS.32.2 -.54 2.925.324.64. 3.5 CV.64.25 -.6 3..64.25 -.2 3.2 CV-DC.48.287.3 3.25.49.286.6 3.4 Stochastic Volatility models SV-CM.73.25.396 2.422.73.79.36 6.435 SV.62.288 -.68 2.997.59.2 -.26 3.889 SV-DC.73.258 -.69 2.937.89.8 -. 4.5 SV-corr.73.235.9.267.72.2 -.3 3.73 This is due to the latent volatility state moving around over time, which is incorporated into the unconditional, but not the conditional, distribution. The unconditional distribution of these models gets much closer to the distribution of the data compared to the models with constant volatility. These results underscore once again that stochastic volatility is important for fitting the kurtosis observed in the data. The SV models also generate more negative skewness compared to the CV models, although the high negative skewness observed in the data is more difficult to match. 33

Table IA.VII Conditional and Unconditional Return Distributions: Net Payout Yield Data This table reports moments of the unconditional and conditional annualized excess market return distribution (where. = %), based on the posterior distribution of parameters at the midpoint of the sample time series (December 967). The top row shows the moments of the data. For each of the models, the moments of the unconditional excess return distribution are calculated from a time series of, simulated returns. The conditional excess return distribution is calculated from, draws of one-month returns, with state variables (net payout yield and volatilities) set equal to their long-run means. Both distributions fully reflect the effects of parameter uncertainty and the uncertainty about latent volatility states, where applicable. kurt is kurtosis (where the Normal distribution has kurtosis of three). Unconditional excess returns Conditional excess returns mean st.dev. skew kurt mean st.dev. skew kurt data.56.9 -.535 9.528 - - - - Constant Volatility models CV-OLS.68.26.9 3..65.23. 3.5 CV-rolling OLS.32.95 -.22 2.989.27.64. 3.5 CV.65.265 -.4 3..63.263 -.2 3.4 CV-DC.63.27 -.7 3.9.65.269.6 3.3 Stochastic Volatility models SV.62.278 -.64 2.278.64.99 -.28 3.77 SV-DC.84.26.22 5.68.86.95 -. 4.62 SV-corr.72.26 -.4.65.73.79 -. 3.69 34

V. Particle Filter Algorithms Our particle filtering and learning algorithm is as follows. First, express p (L t+ y t+ )relative to p (L t,s t,θ y t ). The s t are sufficient statistics for the distribution of the parameters, θ. The continuous distributions are approximated by a set of N particles, p N (L t,s t,θ y t ). The particles essentially form a histogram, where each particle represents a point in the support (L t,s t,θ) with a weight, w, that corresponds to the height of the histogram: p ( N L t+ y t+) = with weights given by = N i= p (y t+ L t,s t,θ) p (L t+ L t,s t,θ,y t+ ) dp N ( L t,s t,θ y t) ( w (L t,s t,θ) (i)) ) p (L t+ (L t,s t,θ) (i),y t+, ( w (L t,s t,θ) (i)) = p (y t+ (L t,s t,θ) (i)) N i= (y p t+ (L t,s t,θ) (i)). The distribution p N (L t+ y t+ ) is then a discrete mixture distribution. To sample from this distribution, first draw Step : ( k (i) Multi w (L t,s t,θ) (i)). Now propagate the states and sufficient statistics to (L t+ ) (i) Step 2: Step 3: ) L (i) t+ p (L t+ (L t,s t,θ) k(i),y t+ ( s (i) t+ = S s k(i) t,l (i) t+,y t+ ). Given sufficient statistics, the parameters are propagated with Step 4: ( ) θ (i) p θ s (i) t+. 35

Given these particles, it is easy to estimate parameters, state variables, and marginal likelihoods. The likelihood component p(y t M j )= t j= p(y j y j, M j ) is estimated recursively using p(y t y t, M j ) N N i= p(y t θ (i),s (i) t,l (i) t,y t, M j ). In the remainder of this section we provide the particle filter for each model in detail. A. CV Model The benchmark CV model has no latent state variables since both r t and x t are observed: r t+ = α + βx t + σε r t+ x t+ = α x + β x x t + σ x ε x t+. (IA.3) (IA.4) The shocks are standard normal random variables with correlation ρ, and the parameter vector θ =(α, β, α x,β x,σ,σ x,ρ). The initial resampling step uses weights proportional to the predictive likelihood of the new data, y t+ =[ r t+ x t+ ] : w(s t,θ) p (y t+ y t,s t,θ)=n α + βx t α x + β x x t, Σ, where Σ= σ 2 ρσσ x ρσσ x σ 2 x. The parameter posteriors follow from the theory of multivariate normal linear and conjugate 36

Normal-Inverse Wishart priors: p (Σ s t+ ) IW(c t+,c t+ ) p (α, β, α x,β x Σ,s t+ ) N ( vec(μ t+ ), Σ A t+), where μ t+ = A t+ a t+. The sufficient statistics, s t+, are updated using the recursions: A t+ = A t + Z t Z t a t+ = a t + Z t y t+ W t+ = W t + y t+ y t+ c t+ = c t + C t+ = C + W t+ + μ t+ A t+ μ t+ μ t+ a t+ a t+ μ t+ +(μ t+ μ ) A (μ t+ μ ), where W =andz t =[ x t ]. B. CV-DC Model The drifting coefficients model has one latent state variable, L t = β t : r t+ = α + βx t + β t+ x t + σε r t+ x t+ = α x + β x x t + σ x ε x t+, β t+ = β β β t + σ β ε β t+. (IA.5) (IA.6) (IA.7) The innovations in the predictability coefficient, ε β t+, are independent of the shocks ε t+ and ε x t+. First, resample the particles with weights proportional to the predictive likelihood: α + βx t + β β β t x t σβ 2 w(l t,s t,θ) p (y t+ y t,l t,s t,θ)=n, Σ+ x2 t, α x + β x x t 37

Next, update the latent state using the Kalman filter recursion β t+ L t,θ,y t+ N V β β β t /σβ 2 +[x t ]Σ r t+ α βx t x t+ α x β x x t,v, where V =/σβ 2 +[x t ]Σ [x t ]. The parameters of the observation equations are drawn as in the benchmark model, with Normal-Inverse Wishart conjugate priors. The parameters of the drifting coefficient evolution are drawn from a linear regression with Normal-Inverse Gamma conjugate prior: p (Σ s t+ ) IW(c t+,c t+ ) p (α, β, α x,β x Σ,s t+ ) N ( ) vec(μ t+ ), Σ A t+ p ( σβ 2 s t+) IG(gt+,G t+ ) p ( ) ( ) ) β β σβ,s 2 t+ N (μ β t+,σβ 2 S β t+, where μ t+ ) = A t+ a t+, andμ β t+ (S = β t+ m β t+. The sufficient statistics, s t+, are updated using the recursions A t+ = A t + Z t Z t a t+ = a t + Z t Y t+ W t+ = W t + y t+ y t+ c t+ = c t + C t+ = C + W t+ + μ t+ A t+ μ t+ μ t+ a t+ a t+ μ t+ +(μ t+ μ ) A (μ t+ μ ) S β t+ = Sβ t + β 2 t m β t+ = mβ t + β t β t+ 38

B t+ = B t + β 2 t+ g t+ = g t + G t+ = G + B t+ + ( ) 2 ) 2 ( ) 2 μ β t+ S β t+ (μ β t+ mβ t+ + μ β t+ μβ S β, where W =,B =,Z t =[ x t ],andy t =[ r t β t x t x t ]. C. SV Model Rewrite the SV model with log-stochastic volatility, with an innocuous change of variables for the volatility process for convenience: r t+ = α + βx t +exp ( V r t+ /2) ε r t+ (IA.8) x t+ = α x + β x x t +exp ( V x t+ /2) ε x t+, (IA.9) V r t+ = α r + β r V r t + σ r η r t+ (IA.) V x t+ = α v + β v V x t + σ v η v t+. (IA.) This model contains two latent state variables: the volatilities of returns and payout yields, L t =(Vt r,vx t ). The innovations in volatilities are independent of each other and to the shocks to returns and payout yields. First, we propagate the volatility states, Vt+ r N( ) α r + β r Vt r,σ2 r V x t+ N ( α v + β v V x t,σ 2 v). 39

Next, we resample particles using weights w(l t+,s t,θ) p (y t+ y t,l t+,s t,θ)=n α + βx t α x + β x x t, Σ t+, with Σ t+ = exp(v r t+) ρ exp(vt+ r /2+V t+ x x /2) exp(vt+ ) ρ exp(v r t+/2+v x t+/2). The parameters, θ =(α, β, α x,β x,α r,β r,σ r,α v,β v,σ v,ρ), are drawn from standard linear regression posteriors with the exception of the correlation coefficient, ρ, p (α, β, α x,β x s t+ ) N ( ) vec(μ t+ ),A t+ p ( σr 2 s t+) IG(ct+,C t+ ) p ( ) ( ) ) α r,β r σr,s 2 t+ N (μ r t+,σr 2 S r t+ p ( σ 2 v s t+) IG(dt+,D t+ ) p ( α v,β v σ 2 v,s t+ ) N (μ v t+,σ 2 v ( S v t+ ) ), where μ t+ = A t+a t+, μ r t+ = ( S r t+) m r t+,andμ v t+ = ( S v t+) m v t+. The vector of sufficient statistics, s t+, is updated using the recursions: A t+ = A t + Z tσ t+z t a t+ = a t + Z t Σ t+ y t+ S r t+ = S r t + R t R t m r t+ = mr t + R t V r t+ Wt+ r = W t r + ( ) Vt+ r 2 4

c t+ = c t + C t+ = C + Wt+ r + μ r t+ St+μ r r t+ 2 μ r t+ m r t+ + ( ) μ r t+ μ r ( S r μ r t+ μ) r S v t+ = Sv t + X tx t m v t+ = mv t + X t V x t+ Wt+ v = Wt v + ( ) Vt+ x 2 d t+ = d t + D t+ = D + Wt+ v + μv t+ St+ v μv t+ 2 μv t+ m v t+ + ( μ v t+ ) ( ) μv S v μ v t+ μ v, where W r =,W v =,andz t = J [ x t ], J is the two-dimensional identity matrix, R t =[ V r t ],andx t =[ V x t ]. The correlation between the residuals of the return and payout regressions, ρ, is estimated from a grid. The probability of drawing a particular ρ is proportional to t/2 ρ ( ) exp /2(S () t+ + S (22) t+ 2ρS (2) t+ )/( ρ 2 ), ρ where S t+ = S t + ε r t+ [ ε r t+ ε x t+ ]. ε x t+ 4

D. SV-DC Model The SV-DC model has both stochastic volatility and a drifting predictability coefficient, r t+ = α + βx t + β t+ x t +exp ( V r t+ /2) ε r t+ (IA.2) x t+ = α x + β x x t +exp ( V x t+/2 ) ε x t+, (IA.3) V r t+ = α r + β r V r t + σ r η r t+ (IA.4) V x t+ = α v + β v V x t + σ v η v t+ (IA.5) β t+ = β β β t + σ β ε β t+. (IA.6) The model contains three latent state variables: the volatilities of returns and payout yields and the drifting coefficient, L t =(V r t,vx t,β t). The particle filter for this model combines the filter for the SV and CV-DC models. We propagate the volatilities as in the SV model. The resampling weights and drifting coefficient are calculated as in the CV-DC model, replacing Σ by Σ t+ as defined above. The sufficient statistics and posterior parameter distributions are the same as in the SV model, using Y t =[r t β t x t x t ]. The sufficient statistics for the drifting coefficient are as shown in the CV-DC model. To summarize the particle filter algorithm, first we propagate the volatility states V r t+ V x t+ (i) p V r t+ V x t+ L (i) t,θ (i),y t+. Second, we resample the particles (L t+,s t,θ) (i) with weights w(l t+,s t,θ). Third, we update β (i) t+ p(β (y t+,l (i) t,θ (i) ). Fourth, we update sufficient statistics s (i) t+ = S s (i) t ( ( ) and in the last step we draw θ (i) p θ s (i) t+. 42,L (i) t+,y t+ ),

VI. Savage Density Ratios If we partition the parameter vector as θ =(θ M,θ M ), then we are interested in the models given by M : θ M =andm : θ M. Here nesting means that the priors over the unrestricted parameters are the same across the two models, p (θ M M )=p (θ M θ M =, M ), and that the likelihoods of the observed data are equal, p (y t θ M, M )=p (y t θ M,θ M =, M ). These are formal definitions of nesting. The main result is that the Bayes factor, BF,, equals BF t, = p (θ M = y t, M ) p (θ M = M ). To see this, note that by Bayes rule p (θ M = y t, M ) p (θ M = M ) = p (yt θ M =, M ) p (y t M ) = p (y t θ M,θ M =, M ) p (θ M θ M =, M ) dθ M p (y t M ) p (y t θ M, M ) p (θ M M ) dθ M = p (y t M ) = p (yt M ) p (y t M ) = BFt,. This takes the convenient form of a ratio of ordinates, both computed under the more general model. The denominator is just an ordinate of the prior distribution, p (θ M = M ). The numerator is p ( θ M = y t, M ) = p (θ M = θ M,s t ) p ( θ M,s M t y t) d ( θ M,s M t ), 43