Levy Economics Institute of Bard College. Policy Note WHEN A RISING TIDE SINKS MOST BOATS: TRENDS IN US INCOME INEQUALITY

Similar documents
Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates)

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2017 preliminary estimates)

Tools of Budget Analysis (Chapter 4 in Gruber s textbook) 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Notes on Hyman Minsky s Financial Instability Hypothesis

Fiscal Fact. Reversal of the Trend: Income Inequality Now Lower than It Was under Clinton. Introduction. By William McBride

From Communism to Capitalism: Private Versus Public Property and Inequality in China and Russia

ARE TAXES TOO CONCENTRATED AT THE TOP? Rapidly Rising Incomes at the Top Lie Behind Increase in Share of Taxes Paid By High-Income Taxpayers

The Economic Program. June 2014

From Communism to Capitalism: Private vs. Public Property and Rising. Inequality in China and Russia

The Elephant Curve of Global Inequality and Growth *

The U.S. Trade Deficit: A Sign of Good Times. Testimony before The Trade Deficit Review Commission

Normalizing Monetary Policy

Texas Christian University. Department of Economics. Working Paper Series. Keynes Chapter Twenty-Two: A System Dynamics Model

Women have made the difference for family economic security

EXECUTIVE OFFICE OF THE PRESIDENT COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS WASHINGTON, DC 20502

Would the Senate Democrats proposed excise tax on highcost employer-paid health insurance benefits be progressive?

The Material Well-Being of the Poor and the Middle Class since 1980

Chapter 4. What Macroeconomics Tries to Explain

A Transition to Sustainable and Shared Prosperity. Joseph E. Stiglitz Tokyo March 14, 2017

Deciphering the fall and rise in the net capital share by Matthew Rognlie, MIT BPEA Conference Draft (March, 2015)

Texas: Demographically Different

CEPR CENTER FOR ECONOMIC AND POLICY RESEARCH

Ric Battellino: Housing affordability in Australia

Income Progress across the American Income Distribution,

Real Median Family Income is Falling. Family incomes have stagnated since the mid-1980s. Income in 2012 ($51,017) is lower than in 1989 ($51,681).

Maurizio Franzini and Mario Planta

Issues 2012 MEASURED INEQUALITY: FALLACIES AND OVERSTATEMENTS. No. 10 April 2012

TOP INCOMES IN THE UNITED STATES AND CANADA OVER THE TWENTIETH CENTURY

A Just Social Wage and a Job Guarantee

Inequality and Redistribution

CRS Report for Congress

The economic situation in a wide range of economies in the wake of the crisis that began

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. Economics 134 Spring 2018 Professor David Romer LECTURE 19

RESEARCH REPORTS. AMERICAN INSTITUTE for ECONOMIC RESEARCH. Do Tax Cuts Mean Bigger Deficits? Published by. Great Barrington, Massachusetts 01230

Response by Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez to: The Top 1%... of What? By ALAN REYNOLDS

2 TRENDS IN THE DISTRIBUTION OF HOUSEHOLD INCOME BETWEEN 1979 AND 27 Summary Figure 1. Growth in Real After-Tax Income from 1979 to L

Defining the problem: the difference between current deficit and long-term deficits

15 th. edition Gwartney Stroup Sobel Macpherson. First page. edition Gwartney Stroup Sobel Macpherson

The U.S. Economy After the Great Recession: America s Deleveraging and Recovery Experience

The End of the Business Cycle?

IBO. Despite Recession,Welfare Reform and Labor Market Changes Limit Public Assistance Growth. An Analysis of the Hudson Yards Financing Plan

The Great Recession (UXL)

Source: Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez. Chart by Catherine Mulbrandon of VisualizingEconomics.com.

Macroeconomics Principles, Applications, and Tools O'Sullivan Sheffrin Perez Eighth Edition

ECONOMIC CURRENTS. Look for little growth in the first half of High energy costs and cooling housing market a drag on near term growth

At the end of Class 20, you will be able to answer the following:

Additional Slack in the Economy: The Poor Recovery in Labor Force Participation During This Business Cycle

The Gertler-Gilchrist Evidence on Small and Large Firm Sales

THE ESTATE TAX: MYTHS AND REALITIES

When Prosperity Passes By: Middle-Income Oregonians, Tax Cuts, and the Economic Prosperity of the Late 1990s. By Jeff Thompson and Charles Sheketoff

Objectives for Class 26: Fiscal Policy

Global economic inequality: New evidence from the World Inequality Report

1 of 24. Modern Macroeconomics: From the Short Run to the Long Run. 2 of 24. They could not have differed more sharply on economic theory and policy.

Inequality in Oregon

If the Economy s so Bad, Why Is the Unemployment Rate so Low?

EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM

Mitchell s Musings : Consistency May Be a Hobgoblin We Need to Mind. Daniel J.B. Mitchell

The 2017 Tax Cuts and Jobs Act

The Productivity to Paycheck Gap: What the Data Show

Q4 Household Net Worth: The "Real" Story

SPECIAL REPORT. TD Economics CONDITIONS ARE RIPE FOR AMERICAN CONSUMERS TO LEAD ECONOMIC GROWTH

Almost everyone is familiar with the

20 Years of School Funding Post-DeRolph Ohio Education Policy Institute August 2018

Neoliberalism, Investment and Growth in Latin America

April 19, 2004 Joint Select Committee on Public School Finance 78 th Legislature

Policy Brief March 2017

Goal-Based Monetary Policy Report 1

Levy Economics Institute of Bard College. Policy Note LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE AND THE ENTRY AND EXIT TO ZIRP AND QE

FIRST LOOK AT MACROECONOMICS*

Putting Capital Back to Work for America

THE NEW ECONOMY RECESSION: ECONOMIC SCORECARD 2001

Volume Title: The Formation and Stocks of Total Capital. Volume URL:

Levy Institute Measure of Economic Well-Being

Bush s Tax and Budget Policies Fail to. Promote Economic Growth

Gauging Current Conditions: The Economic Outlook and Its Impact on Workers Compensation

The Limping Middle Class

The Global Financial Crisis and the double recession in Spain

Consumption Inequality in Canada, Sam Norris and Krishna Pendakur

The NBER s Business-Cycle Dating Procedure

COMMENTARY NUMBER Household Income, August Housing Starts September 18, 2013

Analysis of latest Scottish Gross Domestic Product (2015 Q3) statistics

Employment Law Project. The Crisis of Long Term Unemployment and the Need for Bold Action to Sustain the Unemployed and Support the Recovery 1

Ric Battellino: Recent financial developments

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

EMBARGOED UNTIL TUESDAY, FEBRUARY 17, Issue Brief

The Manufacturing Sector. Remarks of Dr. N. Gregory Mankiw Chairman, Council of Economic Advisers At the Exchequer Club.

Productivity and Sustainable Consumption in OECD Countries:

Economic Forecast for 2009

Adults in Their Late 30s Most Concerned More Americans Worry about Financing Retirement

Budgets and Taxes Toolkit: Frequently Asked Questions

cepr Analysis of the Upcoming Release of 2003 Data on Income, Poverty, and Health Insurance Data Brief Paper Heather Boushey 1 August 2004

Progress. Economic Performance Under Presidents. Bill Clinton and George W. Bush

The Impact of the Student Debt Crisis on Housing: Five Takeaways for the U.S. Real Estate Industry

New England Economic Partnership May 2013: Massachusetts

Will Taxes Make Former Bush Adviser Greg Mankiw Work Less? Real People Don t Work Less When Their Taxes Go Up. What Does Mankiw Really Want?

Getting Public Value Out of Our Public Dollars Do Iowa s Spending Choices Represent Iowa s Values?

OBSERVATION. TD Economics U.S. DEFICITS & DEBT: PAST, PRESENT & FUTURE

Update on Homeownership Wealth Trajectories Through the Housing Boom and Bust

Public Sector Statistics

Income Inequality in Korea,

Transcription:

Levy Economics Institute of Bard College Levy Economics Institute of Bard College Policy Note 215 / 4 WHEN A RISING TIDE SINKS MOST BOATS: TRENDS IN US INCOME INEQUALITY PAVLINA R. TCHERNEVA Do the majority of Americans share in the benefits of economic recoveries? Does a rising tide, as we are often told, lift all boats? Growth for Whom? (Tcherneva 214a) shows changes in the share of income growth captured by different cohorts during economic expansions (see Tcherneva 214b for further analysis). It turns out that in the postwar period, with every subsequent expansion, a smaller and smaller share of the gains in income growth have gone to the bottom 9 percent of families. Worse, in the latest expansion, while the economy has grown and average real income has recovered from its 28 lows, all of the growth has gone to the wealthiest 1 percent of families, and the income of the bottom 9 percent has fallen. Most Americans have not felt that they have been part of the expansion. We have reached a situation where a rising tide sinks most boats. This policy note provides a broader overview of the increasingly unequal distribution of income growth during expansions, examines some of the changes that occurred from 212 to 213, and identifies a disturbing business cycle trend. It also suggests that policy must go beyond the tax system if we are serious about reversing the drastic worsening of income inequality. Research Associate PAVLINA R. TCHERNEVA is an assistant professor of economics at Bard College. The Levy Economics Institute is publishing this research with the conviction that it is a constructive and positive contribution to the discussion on relevant policy issues. Neither the Institute s Board of Governors nor its advisers necessarily endorse any proposal made by the author. Copyright 215 Levy Economics Institute of Bard College ISSN 2166-28X

Figure 1 9 vs. 1 : Distribution of Average 12 1 8 Figure 2 99 vs. 1 : Distribution of Average 12 1 8 6 4 6 4 2 2-2 -2 Bottom 9 Top 1 1958 6 197 73 1982 9 1991 2 21 7 29 12 Bottom 99 Top 1 1958 6 197 73 1982 9 1991 2 21 7 29 12 Growth and Inequality: 1949 212, including Capital Gains The figures in this policy note are based on Piketty and Saez data (23; updated in 215), which measure real average market income before taxes and transfers. Market income includes wages and salaries, entrepreneurial income, dividends, interest, rents, and capital gains (data excluding capital gains are presented below). For Figures 1 through 7, the x-axis shows expansion periods only (from trough to peak year), as defined by NBER business cycle data. Thomas Piketty (214) and many other scholars have illustrated the rapid worsening of US income inequality since the 197s. Coupling these findings with those in Figure 1 suggests that the way we grow the economy erodes the income distribution (business cycle data are also presented later). 1 As the economy grows, the wealthy are getting a bigger and bigger slice of the income pie, perpetuating a vicious cycle where inequality breeds more inequality. And not all wealthy families are created equal. Decomposing the top 1 percent further, we can see that during the latest expansion, from 29 to 212 (the data are updated to 213 below), the top 1 percent captured 95 percent of the growth pie (Figure 2), whereas the.1 percent captured 32 percent (Figure 3). A stunning one-third of all income growth has gone to a tiny sliver of the wealthiest families in the United States. Growth and Inequality: 1949 213, including Capital Gains Updating Figure 1 with the latest 213 data illustrates the exact same trend (see Figure 4). When we look at the wealthiest cohorts, however, the data seem to indicate a slight shift in trend. When comparing Figures 2 and 3 to Figures 5 and 6, it would seem that there has been an improvement in the way gains from growth are shared by the bottom 99 percent and 99.99 percent. This is in part due to a number of tax changes that occurred in 213. The data in these graphs are pretax, pretransfer, but changes in tax rates affect the way income is reported on a tax return. For example, in 213, a series of Bush-era tax cuts expired. For the wealthiest 2 percent of taxpayers, ordinary income is now taxed at 39.6 percent, instead of the earlier rate of 35 percent. Also, taxpayers in that bracket now pay 2 percent on long-term capital gains and qualified dividends, instead of the lower Bush-era tax rate of 15 percent. When comparing the two most recent estimates of real average income for the top 1 percent and top.1 percent, one notices that there was a spike in reported income for 212 in the latest estimate (compared to what was initially reported). This indicates that the ultrarich are pulling income forward and reporting it in the 212 tax return, when the preferential tax treatments were still in effect. In a sense, preliminary estimates Policy Note, 215/4 2

Figure 3 99.99 vs..1 : Distribution of Average Income Growth during Expansions (including capital gains) 12 1 8 6 4 2-2 1958 6 Bottom 99.99 Top.1 197 73 1982 9 1991 2 21 7 29 12 Figure 4 9 vs. 1 : Distribution of Average 12 1 8 6 4 2-2 Bottom 9 Top 1 1958 6 197 73 1982 9 1991 2 21 7 29 13 Figure 5 99 vs. 1 : Distribution of Average 12 1 8 6 4 2-2 Bottom 99 Top 1 1958 6 197 73 1982 9 1991 2 21 7 29 13 Figure 6 99.99 vs..1 : Distribution of Average Income Growth during Expansions (including capital gains) 12 1 8 6 4 2-2 1958 6 Bottom 99.99 Top.1 197 73 1982 9 1991 2 21 7 29 13 Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 3

of 213 income are too low (Saez 215). Thus, the 213 tax changes have likely triggered an improvement in the income distribution, due to the way the wealthy are reporting their income. This statistical improvement is misleading for another reason. Consider what has happened to the incomes of the bottom 99 percent of families in the meantime. Average real income for the bottom 99 percent, which fell after the crash from $5,4 (27) to $47, (28) continued falling during the expansion, to $44,3 (until 211). It finally showed a small uptick in 212, to $44,9, but in 213 it remained essentially flat. Thus, any improvement in the income distribution is not due to improvements in the well-being of the bottom 99 percent of households. Since the wealthy have greater discretion over the size of their income (a greater proportion of their income is composed of capital gains) and can elect to realize these gains at different times, one might want to examine what happens to the distribution of income growth once capital gains are excluded. To be sure, capital gains are a crucial component of income for the wealthy, and any analysis that excludes them will be limited in scope. Because capital gains can be taken as a lump sum in a given year, looking at tax return data is not an ideal way of examining them. A much better method would be to annuitize them (as in Wolff and Zacharias 29). Nevertheless, considering the income growth distribution once capital gains have been excluded can provide some insights. Growth and Inequality, 1949 213, excluding Capital Gains During 29 13, the wealthiest 1 percent of families captured more than 1 percent of the income growth (Figure 7). That means that market incomes of the bottom 99 percent, excluding capital gains, fell during the 29 13 expansion (from average real income of $44, in 29 to $43,8 in 213). The same is true for the bottom 9 percent, whose average real incomes fell from $31,6 in 29 to $3,98 in 213, while the incomes of the wealthy 1 percent rose. Comparing Figure 5 to Figure 7 (including and excluding capital gains, respectively, for the 99 percent and 1 percent), one notices that the distribution of income growth appears less unequal when capital gains are included. At first, this may seem like a counterintuitive result. What the data illustrate is that, even though capital gains are a very small share of income for Figure 7 99 vs. 1 : Distribution of Average Income Growth during Expansions (excluding capital gains) 14 12 1 8 6 4 2-2 -4 Bottom 99 Top 1 1958 6 197 73 the bottom 99 percent of families (only about 2 percent of their income comes from capital gains), they are the difference between a shrinking income and a marginally growing income for those families. Without capital gains, average real income for the bottom 99 percent fell by $127 from 29 to 213, but including them it rose by a meager $451. For the rich, however, average incomes grew with or without capital gains, even though the latter make up a proportionately larger share of income for the wealthy (between a quarter and a third of their income) and capital gains contributed $91,444 to their average income growth. In essence, the bottom 99 percent are counting on their very small capital gains to keep themselves afloat, because their shrinking wages are not doing the job. Economic Cycles and Inequality Piketty s work demonstrates that income inequality has been worsening rapidly over the last four decades. The figures above illustrate the same trend for all consecutive expansions since the 197s: the majority of the growth has gone to the wealthy. For that period, we can therefore conclude that even if the wealthy lose disproportionately more of their income as the economy 1982 9 1991 2 21 7 29 13 Policy Note, 215/4 4

enters a recession, they must more than make up their losses when the economy expands. The data below corroborate this conclusion. We can examine changes in real income over the economic cycle in two ways. The first is to consider what happens during the business cycle that is, from peak GDP to subsequent peak as reported by the NBER (Figure 8). Real incomes, however, rise, fall, and recover at a somewhat different pace from GDP. So we can also consider the income cycle by identifying actual peaks in the real income data from Piketty and Saez (23; updated 215). In other words, by looking at income cycles, we can also answer the question When real income falls and recovers from one peak to the next, who gains? (Figure 9). The GDP cycle and real income cycle data do not correspond perfectly to each other but they are very close. In either case, what is notable is that the trend toward greater inequality is even more apparent over the entire economic cycle (GDP or income). Worse, since the 7s, the incomes of the rich have recovered almost immediately after a downturn by capturing the overwhelming majority (and sometimes all) of the income growth that occurs in the period spanning only one year after the peak of the income cycle to the subsequent peak (Figure 1). The GDP and income cycle charts (Figures 8 and 9) confirm that, after the 7s, the wealthy capture most of the income growth in most economic cycles. Especially troubling is that during each of the last two periods, the incomes of the bottom 9 percent have shrunk (including or excluding capital gains). One must interpret the 27 13 period with caution. Average incomes have still not recovered their 27 highs, and the decline was about equally shared between the bottom 9 percent and top 1 percent of households. Nevertheless, this last period does not show the full picture, because the business cycle is not yet complete. Thus, we cannot draw too many conclusions yet about the distribution of income growth during this cycle. 2 Consider, however, what happens to the distribution of income growth from one year after the peak of the income cycle until the subsequent peak (Figure 1). It shows a surprising trend. Since the 7s, when we look at the period beginning only one year after a downturn, the cycle delivers between 78 percent and 17 percent of the income growth to the wealthiest 1 percent of families. Observe several periods. From 1973 to 1979, the incomes of the wealthy barely grew (Figure 9). But if one examines what happened beginning one year after the peak of that income cycle (Figure 1), one notices that during 1974 79 they captured 93 percent of the income growth. In other words, though their losses in that first year were large, they recovered all of those losses through the remaining years by capturing virtually all of the growth for that period. Furthermore, since 1973, the bottom 9 percent of households have experienced declining real incomes during four out of the five income cycles (Figures 8 and 9). Finally, during the last period, from 27 to 213, Figure 8 9 vs. 1 : Distribution of Income Gains during GDP Cycles (peak to peak) 15 1 Figure 9 9 vs. 1 : Distribution of Income Gains during Income Cycles (peak to peak) 15 1 5 5-5 -5-1 1953 57 1957 6 Bottom 9 Top 1 196 69 1969 73 1973 79 1979 9 199 2 2 7 27 13-1 1953 56 1956 68 Bottom 9 Top 1 1968 73 1973 79 1979 88 1988 2 2 7 27 13 Incomplete GDP cycle Incomplete income cycle Sources: Author s calculations based on Piketty/Saez data Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 5

Figure 1 9 vs. 1 : Distribution of Income Gains One Year after the Peak of an Income Cycle to Subsequent Peak 15 1 5-5 -1 1954 56 1957 68 Bottom 9 Top 1 Incomplete income cycle 1969 73 1974 79 average real income in the economy shrank, and those losses were shared about equally between the bottom 9 percent and top 1 percent (Figures 8 and 9). But during 28 13 (Figure 1), income for the bottom 9 percent fell proportionately more than that for the wealthiest 1 percent, meaning that incomes of the latter turned around more rapidly (even though they are still below their 27 highs). Indeed, during 29 13, real average income for the wealthiest 1 percent of households rose by 12 percent (not shown), while that for the bottom 9 percent was still falling. To recap, this quick turnaround in the incomes of the wealthy has been the norm for the majority of economic cycles since the mid- 7s. The economic cycle data again confirm that the way we grow recovers the incomes of the top 1 percent first. 198 88 Sources: Author s calculations based on Piketty/Saez data 1989 2 21 7 28 13 shared prosperity. Wages were rising in lockstep with productivity, public investment and public works were still a standard government response to downturns, the financial sector took only 7 15 percent of total corporate profits (compared to 3 percent today, after peaking at over 4 percent in the early 2s), and long-term unemployment was a small share of total unemployment. The focus on pro-employment and pro-wage policies slowly weakened, but after the 7s the shift was decisive away from labor markets and toward top marginal tax rates and financial markets. Trends in income distribution are largely underwritten by the policy regime in place. In no small measure, they are shaped by the method used to stimulate economic growth; by the direction of government spending and tax policy, for instance. When policy began prioritizing the reduction in top marginal tax rates (i.e., Reagan-style trickle-down economics) in place of an employment- and wage-led strategy, a growing economy began favoring the incomes of the ultrarich, by design. And when stabilization policies began focusing on recovering the banking and financial sectors first, households whose incomes were tied to stock market performance (i.e., wealthy families disproportionately benefiting from stock options, bonuses, capital gains, and dividends) experienced faster income growth than the rest. Most families still get their incomes from wages and salaries, which are derived from increasingly anemic and precarious labor markets. And indeed, since the 7s, in virtually every consecutive expansion, lost payrolls have taken longer and longer to recover. The abandonment of the goal of tight full employment has unsurprisingly meant that incomes of those who depend on employment, wages, and salaries would be the last to grow (if at all). When jobless recoveries became the norm and wages and salaries remained stagnant, the families who counted on them shared few, if any, of the benefits from expansions (Tcherneva 214b). An Important Culprit: The Shift in Government Policy The trends illustrated above are neither an accident nor inescapable. Indeed, during the Golden Age of American capitalism, the majority of economic growth was shared by the majority of families. As Hyman P. Minsky (1992) argued, there are many varieties of capitalism, some more stable than others and, we can add, some more equitable than others. In the immediate postwar era, when government prioritized pro-employment and pro-wage policies, growth brought Changing Directions: Refocusing Policy to Tackle Inequality John Maynard Keynes ([1936] 1973) famously said that the two outstanding faults of economic society were the failure to secure full employment and the arbitrary and inequitable distribution of income. I have argued (Tcherneva 214b) that the failure to solve the first problem (achieve tight full employment at decent wages for all) has contributed to the worsening of the Policy Note, 215/4 6

second (income inequality). A policy orientation that pursues chock-full employment and decent wages can go a long way toward lifting the floor and filling the middle, delivering shared prosperity. When we look exclusively to the tax system for policy solutions to inequality, we miss this more important piece of the puzzle. Returning to a more equitable variety of capitalism requires far more than just rolling back regressive tax cuts; it requires resuscitating and modernizing those labor-marketfocused policies left behind by the shift to a trickle-down, financial-sector-driven policy regime. Redesigning the tax structure alone will not do the job. Aggressive increases in top marginal tax rates will reduce incomes at the top and thereby improve the income distribution, but more extensive progress will not be made until steps are taken to ensure that incomes at the bottom and the middle rise faster than those at the top. This can be achieved by refocusing policy on labor markets including a mechanism that links wage increases to productivity gains, prioritizes decent work for decent pay, commits to pay equity, reexamines comparable worth policies, and, importantly, implements an effective employment safety net at living wages for all. These are policies that would ensure that (1) the incomes of the vast majority of people grow rather than shrink in expansions and (2) the majority of the gains from growth go to the majority of families. Notes 1. I examine why growth in the United States has increasingly brought income inequality in Tcherneva (214a and 214b). 2. To account for the 213 tax return reporting aberration in the data discussed above, I average the 212 and 213 income data in Figures 8-1. References Keynes, J. M. (1936) 1973. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. In D. E. Moggridge, ed. The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, Vol. 7. London: Macmillan. Minsky, H. P. 1992. The Capital Development of the Economy and the Structure of Financial Institutions. Prepared for the session Financial Fragility and the US Economy, Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, New Orleans, January 2 5. Piketty, T. 214. Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Piketty, T., and E. Saez. 23. Income Inequality in the United States, 1913 1998. Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, no. 1 (February): 1 39. (Tables and Figures updated to 213 in Excel format, January 215.) Saez, E. 215. Striking It Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States. (Updated with 213 preliminary estimates.) UC Berkeley, January 25. Tcherneva, P. R. 214a. Growth for Whom? One-Pager No. 47. Annandale-on-Hudson, N.Y.: Levy Economics Institute of Bard College. October.. 214b. Reorienting Fiscal Policy: A Bottom-up Approach. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 37, no. 1 (Fall): 43 66. Draft version first published as Working Paper No. 772, Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, August 213. Wolff, E., and A. Zacharias. 29. Household Wealth and the Measurement of Economic Well-Being in the United States. The Journal of Economic Inequality 7, no. 2 (June): 83 115. Originally published as Working Paper No. 447, Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, May 26. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 7