Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes

Similar documents
Introduction Theory Equilibrium Data and Methodology Results conclusion. Toxic Arbitrage. Wing Wah Tham. Erasmus University Rotterdam

Indexing and Price Informativeness

Signal or noise? Uncertainty and learning whether other traders are informed

News Trading and Speed

Dynamic Trading and Asset Prices: Keynes vs. Hayek

Equilibrium Fast Trading

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

Ambiguous Information and Trading Volume in stock market

High Frequency Trading and Fragility

Liquidity Supply across Multiple Trading Venues

Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market

High Frequency Trading and Fragility

Why Do Agency Theorists Misinterpret Market Monitoring?

Limits to Arbitrage. George Pennacchi. Finance 591 Asset Pricing Theory

Dynamic Market Making and Asset Pricing

Liquidity and Risk Management

Market Size Matters: A Model of Excess Volatility in Large Markets

Imperfect Competition, Information Asymmetry, and Cost of Capital

Liquidity and Asset Prices in Rational Expectations Equilibrium with Ambiguous Information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 2013 D. Romer

News Trading and Speed

Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring The main idea The sequence of events: Technology and information

The Welfare Impact of High Frequency Trading

Market Transparency Jens Dick-Nielsen

The Flash Crash: The Impact of High Frequency Trading on an Electronic Market

Leverage and Liquidity Dry-ups: A Framework and Policy Implications

Financial Market Feedback:

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk. June 2012

Should Norway Change the 60% Equity portion of the GPFG fund?

Measurement of Market Risk

Insiders-Outsiders, Transparency, and the Value of the Ticker

What Can Rational Investors Do About Excessive Volatility and Sentiment Fluctuations?

Price Impact, Funding Shock and Stock Ownership Structure

Market Microstructure Invariants

Liquidity vs. Information Efficiency

The financialization of the term structure of risk premia in commodity markets. IdR FIME, February 3rd, 2017

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel

Financial Market Feedback and Disclosure

Speculation and Hedging in Segmented Markets

Learning whether other Traders are Informed

Risk and Wealth in Self-Fulfilling Currency Crises

A Network Model of Counterparty Risk

MPhil F510 Topics in International Finance Petra M. Geraats Lent Course Overview

Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Vayanos and Vila, A Preferred-Habitat Model of the Term Stru. the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Speculative Betas. Harrison Hong and David Sraer Princeton University. September 30, 2012

Information and Learning in Markets. Chapter 4

News Trading and Speed

Market Liquidity. Theory, Evidence, and Policy OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS THIERRY FOUCAULT MARCO PAGANO AILSA ROELL

Crises and Prices: Information Aggregation, Multiplicity and Volatility

Information Globalization, Risk Sharing and International Trade

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

The Life Cycle Model with Recursive Utility: Defined benefit vs defined contribution.

LEVERAGE AND LIQUIDITY DRY-UPS: A FRAMEWORK AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS. Denis Gromb LBS, LSE and CEPR. Dimitri Vayanos LSE, CEPR and NBER

On the Spillover of Exchange-Rate Risk into Default Risk! Miloš Božović! Branko Urošević! Boško Živković!

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Optimal Credit Limit Management

INVENTORY MODELS AND INVENTORY EFFECTS *

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Insiders-Outsiders, Transparency and the Value of the Ticker

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

Information Acquisition and Portfolio Under-Diversification

Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk

Circuit Breakers and Market Runs

Asset Pricing Implications of Social Networks. Han N. Ozsoylev University of Oxford

Public Information and Effi cient Capital Investments: Implications for the Cost of Capital and Firm Values

COMPARATIVE MARKET SYSTEM ANALYSIS: LIMIT ORDER MARKET AND DEALER MARKET. Hisashi Hashimoto. Received December 11, 2009; revised December 25, 2009

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Measuring and explaining liquidity on an electronic limit order book: evidence from Reuters D

Strategic Information Revelation and Capital Allocation

Investment Restrictions and Contagion in Emerging Markets

The Effects of Responsible Investment: Financial Returns, Risk, Reduction and Impact

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

The Macroeconomics of Shadow Banking. January, 2016

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk

Corrigendum to Prospect Theory and market quality Journal of Economic Theory 149 (2014),

News Trading and Speed

Online Appendix to Financing Asset Sales and Business Cycles

A Theory of Endogenous Liquidity Cycles

Background Risk and Trading in a Full-Information Rational Expectations Economy

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Asymmetric Information and Inventory Concerns in Over-the-Counter Markets

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles?

Liquidity and Asset Prices: A Unified Framework

Long-run Consumption Risk and Asset Allocation under Recursive Utility and Rational Inattention

Informed trading, indexing, and welfare

Fast and Slow Informed Trading

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

Long-run Consumption Risk and Asset Allocation under Recursive Utility and Rational Inattention

Investor Information Choice with Macro and Micro Information

SHORT-HORIZON TRADING AND MARKET MOVEMENT. 18 February Jeremy Large St Hugh s College, University of Oxford Tudor Investment Corp

Banking Regulation in Theory and Practice (2)

Bank Capital, Agency Costs, and Monetary Policy. Césaire Meh Kevin Moran Department of Monetary and Financial Analysis Bank of Canada

Dynamic Trading and Asset Prices: Keynes vs. Hayek

High-Frequency Trading and Market Stability

EFFICIENT MARKETS HYPOTHESIS

Transcription:

Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault SoFiE Conference Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 1 / 49

Introduction Plan 1 Introduction 2 Model 3 Benchmark: Segmented Markets 4 Partial Integration with fully price informed dealers 5 Partial Integration with imperfectly price informed dealers 6 Full Integration: the role of cross-market arbitrageurs Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 2 / 49

Introduction The Flash Crash The flash crash of May 6, 2010: Very large price declines in thousands of U.S stocks, ETFs and index futures without apparent changes in fundamentals. Very quick reversal. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 3 / 49

Introduction The Flash Crash Many of the almost 8,000 individual equity securities and exchange traded funds ( ETFs ) traded that day suffered similar price declines and reversals within a short period of time, falling 5%, 10% or even 15% before recovering most, if not all, of their losses. However, some equities experienced even more severe price moves, both up and down. Over 20,000 trades across more than 300 securities were executed at prices more than 60% away from their values just moments before. CFTC-SEC (2011) Proximate cause: a sell order for 75,000 contracts in the CME e-mini S&P500 futures ($4.1 billion of notional amount). Large? Many aspects of the Flash Crash remain mysterious. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 4 / 49

Introduction Contagious Illiquidity and Liquidity Crashes A market wide evaporation of liquidity. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 5 / 49

Introduction Consolidated depth (green: buy side, blue: selll side) for Procter and Gamble from 9:00 a.m to 4:00 p.m. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 6 / 49

Introduction Illiquidity crashes for close substitutes Many of the securities experiencing the most severe price dislocations on May 6 were equity-based ETFs [...]" (CFTC-SEC (2011), page 39) Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 7 / 49

Introduction Some puzzles Illiquidity Contagion: How can a large sell order in one security trigger an evaporation of liquidity in hundreds of securities? 1 Arbitrage? But then why an evaporation on both the sell and buy sides of limit order books? Why not an inflow of buy limit and buy market orders in the e.mini futures? Causality: Did the liquidity crash caused the price crash or vice versa? Market Integration: Why have Exchange Traded Funds (ETFs) been more affected? Market Stucture: Is the current market structure intrisincally more fragile? Why? HFTs or something else? Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 8 / 49

Introduction Our Hypothesis Important change in market structure in recent years: information on prices is more widely and quickly disseminated than ever. Example: Date Markets Technology Reduction in delay 1846 NYSE-Philadelphia Telegraph One day to a few hours 1975 NYSE-Regionals Consolidated Tape 5-10 mns to 1-2 mns 1980 NYSE Upgrades on floor 2mns to 20 sds Circa 2005 Electronic. Co-location sd to nano sds Source: Garbade and Silber (1978) and Easley, Hendershott and Ramadorai (2009) Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 9 / 49

Introduction Consequence Liquidity providers in one asset class increasingly rely on the information contained in the prices of other asset classes to set their quotes = the liquidity levels of various markets have become more interconnected Why? Prices are more informative when liquidity is higher and vice versa. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 10 / 49

Introduction Contagion and Illiquidity Multiplier Plausible? Theory. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 11 / 49

Introduction Modeling approach A rational expectations model of trading with two risky securities (two "asset classes"). Main assumptions: 1 CARA Gaussian framework 2 Payoffs have a factor structure: two risk factors 3 Two types of traders: Specialized dealers: provide liquidity in only one asset class; specialization brings information on one risk factor. Cross-market arbitrageurs: can trade in both markets; no private information; Dealers in one asset class use the price of the other asset as a source of information on the risk factor on which they have no expertise. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 12 / 49

Introduction Main properties of the model Contagion and fragility 1 Interconnected liquidity: the illiquidity levels of each asset are positively inter-connected= an increase in illiquidity for one asset affects all other assets. 2 Illiquidity multiplier: Small shocks to the liquidity of one asset can ultimately have large effects on the liquidity of all assets. 3 Fragility: Multiple rational expectations equilibria with high or low levels of illiquidity in all securities = Liquidity crash: A jump from a low to a high illiquidity equilibrium The channels for market integration (cross-asset learning and cross-market trading) break down in the high illiquidity equilibrium, especially if assets are close substitutes. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 13 / 49

Introduction Literature Models of contagion and crises: King and Wadhwani (1990), Gennotte and Leland (1990), Kyle and Xiong (2001), Gromb and Vayanos (2002), Kodres and Pritsker (2002), Barlevy and Veronesi (2003), Yuan (2005), Pasquariello (2007): 1 These models focus on the source of sharp price declines and the propagation of these declines. 2 We focus on discrete changes in illiquidity and magnification of illiquidity shocks, which then can be associated with large price declines. Empirical papers on the Flash Crash: Kirilenko et al.(2011), Madhavan (2011), Borkovec et al.(2011), Chakravarty, Wood, and Upson (2010). Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 14 / 49

Model Plan 1 Introduction 2 Model Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 15 / 49

Model The Model Two assets D and F Securities Payoffs at date t=2: v D = δ D + d δ F + η, v F = f δ D + δ F + ɛ with δ j N(0, 1) for j {D, F }, η N(0, σ 2 η), δ D, δ F and η are independent. For parsimony we assume d 0, ɛ = 0 and f = 1 Hence both payoffs are positively correlated and the correlation increases in d and decreases in σ 2 η. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 16 / 49

Model Market Participants Trades at date t=1. In each market: 1 A continuum of risk averse dealers with CARA utility functions; 2 A continuum of risk averse cross-market arbitrageurs with CARA utility functions; 3 "Liquidity demand shocks": u j N(0, σ 2 u) for j {D, F }. These demands are independent from each other and independent of other variables. Both arbitrageurs and dealers supply liquidity to liquidity traders Dealers and arbitrageurs have different "business models" 1 Dealers specialize in assets in which they are well informed (as suggested by Schultz (2003)). They have expertise in assessing one risk factor Dealers specialized in different assets have different information. 2 Arbitrageurs have no information on ris factors but engage in cross-market hedging to reduce the risk of their portfolios. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 17 / 49

Model Market Participants Dealers in security j: 1 Know δ j 2 A fraction µ j observes the price in the other market (p j ) 3 Choose their demand function x k j (p j ) to maximize: E [ ] U((v j p j )xj k ) δ j, Price Information for k {D, F } 4 Price Information= {p F, p D } if a dealer is a pricewatcher and Price Information= {p j }, otherwise. Cross-market arbitrageurs: 1 They have no private information 2 They choose their abitrage portfolio (xd H (p D, p F ), xf H (p D, p F )) to maximize [ ] E U((v D p D )xd H + (v F p F )xf H ) {p F, p D } Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 18 / 49

Model Market Clearing Equilibrium at date t=1: Supply=Demand in market j: µ j x W j (δ j, p j, p j ) + (1 µ j )x I j (δ j, p j ) + λx H j (p j, p j ) + u j = 0, (1) λ = Index of arbitrage capital. Dealers and arbitrageurs have rational expectations. Various Cases: 1 µ D = µ F = 0 and λ = 0: markets are segmented 2 µ D > 0 and µ F > 0 and λ = 0: markets are integrated through cross-asset learning. 3 µ D = µ F = 0 and λ > 0: markets are integrated through cross-asset trading. 4 µ D = µ F = 1 and λ > 0: full integration Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 19 / 49

Benchmark Plan 1 Introduction 2 Model 3 Benchmark: Segmented Markets Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 20 / 49

Benchmark Benchmark Segmented markets: dealers do not watch prices/no arbitrageurs (µ D = µ F = 0 and λ = 0) The equilibrium is unique. Prices: p j = δ j }{{} + B j0 }{{} u j }{{} Fundamentals Illiquidity Liquidity Demand Shocks for j {D, F } B D0 = Var(v D δ D ) γ D = σ2 η + d γ D and B F 0 = Var(v F δ F ) γ F = 1 γ F B j0 = Sensitivity of price to liquidity demand="illiquidity of security j." Parameters {σ 2 η, d, γ D } are the "liquidity fundamentals" of security D (similar interpretation for γ F ) Shocks to liquidity fundamentals in one market do not affect the other market No liquidity spillovers if no cross-asset learning Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 21 / 49

Benchmark Price informativeness and liquidity The price of security j is a noisy signal about factor δ j : p j = δ j + B j0 }{{} Illiquidity u j for j {D, F } }{{} Noise The informativeness of security D for dealers in security F depends on their belief regarding the liquidity of security D and vice versa. These beliefs are part of the equilibrium if markets are not fully segmented When µ j > 0, we focus on linear Rational Expectations Equilibria. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 22 / 49

Cross-Asset Learning and Interconnected liquidity Plan 1 Introduction 2 Model 3 Benchmark: Segmented Markets 4 Partial Integration with fully price informed dealers Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 23 / 49

Cross-Asset Learning and Interconnected liquidity No arbitrageurs, All Dealers are Pricewatchers When µ D = µ F = 1, there always exists at least one rational expectations equilibrium. In such an equilibrium: with p j = δ j + A j1 (δ j + B j1 u j ) }{{} + B j1 u j New: Information from the price of security j B j1 = B j0 (1 ρ 2 j1 }{{} ) Illiquidity with wide dissemination of price info Variable ρ 2 j1 measures the informativeness of the price of security j about the payoff of security j for dealers in security j. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 24 / 49

Cross-Asset Learning and Interconnected liquidity Self-reinforcing illiquidity 1/2 Illiquidity of security F Informativeness of the price of security F Illiquidity of security D and vice versa Formally: ρ 2 D1 = ρ 2 F 1 = d 2 (σ 2 η + d 2 )(1 + B 2 F 1 σ2 u F ), 1 (1 + B 2 D1 σ2 u D ). Solving for the equilibrium Find solutions to: B D1 = f 1 (B F 1 ; γ D, σ 2 η, d, σ 2 u F ) B F 1 = g 1 (B D1 ; γ F, σ 2 u D ) = Interconnected liquidity/positive Liquidity spillovers Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 25 / 49

Cross-Asset Learning and Interconnected liquidity Self-reinforcing illiquidity 2/2 Suppose that the risk tolerance of dealers in security D, γ D, decreases: 1 Security D becomes less liquid since dealers in this asset class have less risk appetite: B D1 2 Hence the price of security D is less informative for dealers in security F : ρ 2 F 1 3 Thus, inventory risk is higher for dealers in security F and security F becomes less liquid: B F 1. More generally, a shock to the liquidity fundamental of one security induces a change in the same direction for the liquidity of securities D and F = positive co-movements in liquidity. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 26 / 49

Cross-Asset Learning and Interconnected liquidity Equilibrium multiplicity 1/2 Only the extreme equilibria: L and H are stable Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 27 / 49

Cross-Asset Learning and Interconnected liquidity Equilibrium Multiplicity 2/2 Corollary: unique. If σ 2 η > 4d 2, the rational expectations equilibrium is Otherwise, multiple equilibria = Multiple equilibria are more likely if assets payoffs are more correlated. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 28 / 49

Cross-Asset Learning and Interconnected liquidity Vicious illiquidity loop Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 29 / 49 Illiquidity Crashes A switch from L to H generates a discrete market-wide increase in illiquidity: an illiquidity crash.

Cross-Asset Learning and Interconnected liquidity Illiquidity crashes Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 30 / 49

Cross-Asset Learning and Interconnected liquidity Illiquidity Crashes Illiquidity crash + large sell order = Price Crash Example: Suppose that γ j = d = 1, σ η = 0.2 and σ uj = 2. Now consider the arrival of a sell order in security F equal to u F = 5 (likelihood less than 1%). Equilibrium Type L H Ratio H/L Illiq F ( 10 2 ) 0.6 63 105 Illiq D ( 10 2 ) 4 65 16 p F 2.1% 223% 106 p D 2.1% 99% 47.14 Changes in prices are expressed as % of price volatility in the low illiquidity equilibrium Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 31 / 49

Cross-Asset Learning and Interconnected liquidity The illiquidity multiplier Even in a given equilibrium, liquidity is fragile: a small shock to the illiquidity of one market can trigger large changes in the liquidity of both markets. Consider again a change in γ D. 1 The total effect of a change in dealers risk appetite in security D is given by: db D1 dγ D = κ }{{} Amplification f 1 < 0 γ }{{ D } Direct effect db F 1 = dγ }{{} κ g 1 f 1 D B D1 γ D Amplification }{{} Direct effect < 0 2 κ = illiquidity multiplier 3 κ is greater than one in the extreme equilibria and can be large Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 32 / 49

Cross-Asset Learning and Interconnected liquidity Example γ F = 1/24; γ D = 1.8; d = 0.5; σ uf = 0.1; σ ud = 1.6 Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 33 / 49

The scope of access to price information Plan 1 Introduction 2 Model 3 Benchmark: Segmented Markets 4 Partial Integration with fully price informed dealers 5 Partial Integration with imperfectly price informed dealers Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 34 / 49

The scope of access to price information Market integration as a source of fragility Our hypothesis: an increase in the scope of access to price information has made liquidity more interconnected and liquidity crashes more likely. We explore this proposition by analyzing the effect of varying the fraction of dealers with price information. µ j =Fraction of pricewatchers in security j. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 35 / 49

The scope of access to price information Equilibrium with inattentive dealers Two types of dealers in each security: pricewatchers and inattentive dealers. Example: Security F Dealers Type Pricewatchers Inattentive Information δ F, p F, p D δ F, p F Inattentive dealers are less informed than pricewatchers 1 = Differential access to price information by a fraction of dealers is a source of adverse selection. 2 = Analysis is similar but more complex. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 36 / 49

The scope of access to price information Findings The equilibrium is unique if µ D or µ F is small = liquidity crashes arise only when the fraction of pricewatchers become large enough. In a given equilibrium, if dealers risk bearing capacity is not too high: 1 Liquidity spillovers are positive and there is an illiquidity multiplier as in the baseline model. 2 An increase in the fraction of pricewatchers makes all effects stronger. 3 Liquidity is maximal when the scope of dissemination for price information is maximal (µ D = µ F = 1) = Trade-off between liquidity and fragility. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 37 / 49

The scope of access to price information Illiquidity multiplier and price information Evolution of the illiquidity multiplier κ as a function of µ D (the fraction of pricewatchers in security D). Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 38 / 49

The scope of access to price information Co-movements in liquidity and price information Example: numerical values: d = 0.9; σ uj = 1/2; σ η = 2; γ F = 1/2; µ D = 0.1 or µ D = 0.9. We compute the covariance in the illiquidity of both markets for each value of µ F assuming that γ D is uniformly distributed over [0.5, 1]. Testable prediction: co-movements in liquidity become stronger when price information is more widely disseminated. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 39 / 49

Cross-market arbitrageurs Plan 1 Introduction 2 Model 3 Benchmark: Segmented Markets 4 Partial Integration with fully price informed dealers 5 Partial Integration with imperfectly price informed dealers 6 Full Integration Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 40 / 49

Cross-market arbitrageurs Cross-market arbitrageurs Cross-market traders seem to have played an important role during the Flash Crash. "cross-market arbitrageurs transferred this sell pressure to the equities markets by opportunistically buying E-Mini contracts and simultaneously selling products like SPY, or selling individual equities in the S&P 500 Index." "Cross-market strategies primarily focus on the contemporaneous trading of securities-related products [...] to capture temporary price differences between any two related products, but with limited or no exposure to subsequent price moves in those products [...] Some firms focus on one-way strategies by acting as a liquidity provider (i.e., trading passively by submitting non-marketable resting orders) primarily in one product, and then hedging by trading another product." (CFTC-SEC(2010)) Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 41 / 49

Cross-market arbitrageurs Cross-market arbitrageurs and market integration Cross-market arbitrageurs do exactly this in our model: if liquidity traders sell one asset, they will provide liquidity by buying the asset and hedge their positions by selling the other asset. BUT: Securities D and F are imperfect substitutes since σ η > 0 = arbitrage is risky in our model. Hedging reduces the risk of long/short portfolios but cannot fully eliminate it. The cost of hedging depends on dealers supply of liquidity: if arbitrageurs respond to a sell order in security F, they will hedge by selling security D to...dealers. As a result, cross-market arbitrageurs and dealers complement each other in integrating markets. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 42 / 49

Cross-market arbitrageurs Market integration: cross-asset learning and cross-asset trading Example: Suppose that λ = 1, γ j = d = 1, σ η = 0.2 and σ uj = 2. Market Integration = Var(p D p F ) Arbitrageurs Only Dealers Only Dealers + Arbitrageurs L equilibrium Illiq F ( 10 2 ) 204 0.6 0.6 Illiq D ( 10 2 ) 201 4 4 Var(p D p F ) 32.64 4.1.10 5 3.1.10 9 = Markets are integrated both through the actions of dealers and arbitrageurs. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 43 / 49

Cross-market arbitrageurs Fragility with cross-market arbitrageurs Results are qualitatively unchanged with arbitrageurs. In particular: 1 The informativeness of prices is not affected (arbitrageurs have no information and their flows are known once prices are known). 2 The parameters for which multiple equilibria are obtained are exactly the same with and without cross-market arbitrageurs. 3 The presence of arbitrageurs dampen the illiquidity multiplier and the size of illiquidity co-movements but do not suppress it. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 44 / 49

Cross-market arbitrageurs Giovanni Cespa L.H.S: and Thierry No Foucault pricewatchers () Illiquidity(µ Contagion = and µ Liquidity = 0); Crashes R.H.S: µ SoFiE = µ Conference = 1 45 / 49 Co-movement and Arbitrage Capital Example: numerical values: d = 0.9; σ uj = 1/2; σ η = 2; γ F = 1/2; µ D = 0.1 or µ D = 0.9. We compute the covariance inthe illiquidity in both markets for each value of λ assuming that σ η is uniformy distributed over [0.1, 2.5].

Cross-market arbitrageurs Implication: illiquidity crashes should be relatively stronger for close substitutes Close substitutes: d = 1 and σ η small = high correlation in the payoffs of the assets. When securities are close substitutes, prices are very informative in the low illiquidity equilibrium= 1 Dealers demand function is very elastic (a small drop in price is suffi cient to induce dealers to buy a large number of shares) 2 Arbitrageurs demand function is also very elastic because hedging costs are small. 3 Liquidity is very high and assets look very integrated A switch from L to H triggers a very sharp drop in price informativeness= 1 Sharp increase in illiquidity in relative terms 2 Sharp drop in integration in relative terms. Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 46 / 49

Cross-market arbitrageurs Example Suppose that λ = µ D = µ F = 1; γ j = d = 1, and σ uj = 2. Illiqu H D /IlliquL D Illiqu H F /IlliquL F Var H ( p)/var L ( p) σ η Corr 0.1 97% 37.93 943 8.7 10 8 0.2 95% 10.28 63 226, 705 0.25 94% 6.81 26 15280 Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 47 / 49

Cross-market arbitrageurs Illiquidity crashes for close substitutes Many of the securities experiencing the most severe price dislocations on May 6 were equity-based ETFs [...]" (CFTC-SEC (2011), page 39) Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 48 / 49

Cross-market arbitrageurs Conclusions Thanks! Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault () Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes SoFiE Conference 49 / 49