Shadow Interest Rates and the Stance of U.S. Monetary Policy

Similar documents
Perspectives on the Current Stance of Monetary Policy

How Far Is the FOMC from Its Goals?

Does Low Inflation Justify a Zero Policy Rate?

Four Questions for Current Monetary Policy

Making Sense of Thresholds, Triggers, Twists, and Timelines

More on Modern Monetary Policy Rules

Still Very Accommodative

The U.S. Economic Situation and Recent Monetary Policy Developments

Commodity Prices, Inflation Targeting, and U.S. Monetary Policy

James Bullard. 13 January St. Louis, Missouri

R-Star Wars: The Phantom Menace

Two Views of International Monetary Policy Coordination

The FOMC: Ahead on Results, Behind on Rates

U.S. Monetary Policy: Still Appropriate

SNEAK PREVIEW: Death of a Theory

QE2 in Five Easy Pieces

James Bullard. 30 June St. Louis, MO

Some Considerations for U.S. Monetary Policy Normalization

Monetary Policy Options in a Low Policy Rate Environment

An Illustrative Calculation of r

A Singular Achievement of Recent Monetary Policy

An Update on the Tapering Debate

International Monetary Stability: A Multiple Equilibria Problem?

Faster solutions for Black zero lower bound term structure models

Time Consistency and Fed Policy

The U.S. Economy in the Aftermath of the Financial Crisis

Assessing the Risk of Yield Curve Inversion: An Update

A New Characterization of the U.S. Macroeconomic and Monetary Policy Outlook 1

The U.S. Monetary Policy Outlook

A Primer on Price Level Targeting in the U.S.

Ghosts of Forecasts Past and Future

Remarks on the 2018 U.S. Macroeconomic Outlook

The Recent Reduction in Global Macroeconomic Uncertainty

When Will U.S. Inflation Return to Target?

Assessing the Risk of Yield Curve Inversion

The Fed at a Crossroads

FOMC FAQS. December 17, 2015 by John Canally of LPL Financial

U.S. Monetary Policy: Recent Developments

Commentary: Challenges for Monetary Policy: New and Old

U.S. Monetary Policy and the Path to Normalization

What Is the Best Strategy for Extending the U.S. Economy s Expansion?

FOMC FAQS COMMENTARY KEY TAKEAWAYS LPL RESEARCH WEEKLY ECONOMIC. December John Canally, Jr., CFA Chief Economic Strategist, LPL Financial

Three Lessons for Monetary Policy from the Panic of 2008

During the global financial crisis, many central

Will Regulatory Reform Prevent Future Crises?

FOMC FAQs: ALL ABOUT THE DOTS

U.S. Monetary Policy: A Case for Caution

Understanding and Influencing the Yield Curve at the Zero Lower Bound

Remarks on Monetary Policy Challenges. Bank of England Conference on Challenges to Central Banks in the 21st Century

FOMC Preview: When, How Often, and How Much

Comments on Monetary Policy at the Effective Lower Bound

Chapter 11 The Determination of Aggregate Output, the Price Level, and the Interest Rate

Economic Outlook and Monetary Policy

A Perspective on Unconventional Monetary Policy

The First Phase of the U.S. Recovery and Beyond

Expectations for U.S. Monetary Policy

Monetary Policy Tools in an Environment of Low Interest Rates James Bullard

Monetary Policy Normalization Should Be More Systematic and Less Wobbly

Economic Inequality and Possible Policy Responses

Remarks on Monetary Policy Challenges

How to Extend the U.S. Expansion: A Suggestion

Survey of Primary Dealers

Non-Uniform Currencies and Exchange Rate Chaos

Re-Normalize, Don t New-Normalize Monetary Policy. John B. Taylor. Economics Working Paper 14109

The Taylor Rule: A benchmark for monetary policy?

Average Household Debt: $132,000 - Not Counting Mortgage

Macroeconomic and Interest Rate Outlook

Strengthening Our Monetary Policy Framework Through Commitment, Credibility, and Communication

Living Standards across U.S. Metropolitan Statistical Areas

Monetary Policy Frameworks

US Federal Reserve: Feels like the first time

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

What Can We Expect for 2017 from the FOMC?

US Federal Reserve: Feels like the first time

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

FRBSF Economic Letter

Empirically Evaluating Economic Policy in Real Time. The Martin Feldstein Lecture 1 National Bureau of Economic Research July 10, John B.

Macroeconomics. 1. Course Information Version Description

Goldman: The Fed Needs To Print $4 Trillion

Economic Outlook and Monetary Policy

Perspectives on 2019 Monetary Policy

Responses to Survey of Market Participants

2012 Economic Outlook: Overview of U.S. Economy. Presented by: Mark Evans, CFA Director of Investment Strategies

The U.S. Macroeconomic Outlook

The FRB St Louis New Economic Narrative and Negative Rates

The Fed and The U.S. Economic Outlook

Monetary and Fiscal Policy During the Great Recession: Old Challenges and New Insights

Discussion of The Decline of Activist Stabilization Policy

Federal Reserve Communications and Transparency

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Monetary Policy Strategy: Crisis. Frederic Mishkin April 7, 2011

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA Economics 134 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Spring 2018 Professor David Romer LECTURE 9

Charles I Plosser: Strengthening our monetary policy framework through commitment, credibility, and communication

MonetaryTrends. What is the slope of the yield curve telling us?

The Federal Reserve: Everything You Wanted to Know But Were Afraid to Ask. CFA Societies 2014 Texas Investor Summit

RESPONSES TO SURVEY OF

FRBSF Economic Letter

Monetary Policy Revised: January 9, 2008

Alan Bush. January 10, 2019 STOCK INDEX FUTURES. Stock index futures are lower due to the lack of details of the U.S.-China trade talks.

Opening Remarks at the 2017 BOJ-IMES Conference Hosted by the Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies, Bank of Japan

Transcription:

Shadow Interest Rates and the Stance of U.S. Monetary Policy James Bullard President and CEO, FRB-St. Louis 8 November 2012 Center for Finance and Accounting Research Annual Corporate Finance Conference Olin Business School Washington University in St. Louis Any opinions expressed here are my own and do not necessarily reflect those of others on the Federal Open Market Committee.

Is Current U.S. Monetary Policy Too Easy?

Main idea Some recent research suggests that current U.S. monetary policy may be considerably easier than commonly understood. In particular, the current U.S. policy stance may be substantially easier than the policy stance recommended by commonly-used monetary policy feedback rules. This research is based on ideas in mathematical finance.

A shadow rate The level of nominal short-term interest rates is conventionally taken to indicate the stance of policy. Lower values are described as easier policy. The FOMC s policy rate has been effectively pegged near zero since December of 2008. How should the monetary policy stance be described given this development? A math finance answer: Construct a shadow rate.

Sources Main papers: Leo Krippner. 2012a. Measuring the stance of monetary policy in zero lower bound environments. Reserve Bank of New Zealand, Discussion Paper 2012/04, August. Leo Krippner. 2012b. Modifying Gaussian term structure models when interest rates are near the zero lower bound. Reserve Bank of New Zealand, Discussion Paper 2012/02, March. Less technical discussion: Leo Krippner. 2012c. A model for interest rates near the zero lower bound: An overview and discussion. Reserve Bank of New Zealand, Analytical Note 2012/05, September.

The value of the shadow rate Krippner (2012a,b,c) calculates a shadow short-term rate. This rate can be understood as a metric for the stance of monetary policy in a zero lower bound environment. The current value is about -5.0 percent. This value is considerably more negative than values recommended by common monetary policy rules. Bottom line: The current policy stance looks very easy according to this analysis.

Background and Methodology

Fischer Black The late Fischer Black (1938-1995) was a leader in mathematical finance. Co-creator of Black-Scholes option pricing. One paper he worked on shortly before his death: Interest Rates as Options Published in late 1995 in the Journal of Finance. * * See: F. Black, 1995, Interest Rates as Options, Journal of Finance, 50(5), pp. 1371-6.

Interest rates as options Nominal interest rates cannot fall materially below zero. This is because cash provides a risk-free investment at a zero nominal rate. Holding cash will therefore be more attractive than accepting a negative nominal rate on a security. Black (1995) provided a way to calculate the value of the call option to hold cash at the zero lower bound. The value of this option can then be subtracted from observed nominal yields. This leaves a shadow nominal yield curve that would exist in the absence of the cash option.

Monetary policy applications Leo Krippner is a financial market economist working at the Reserve Bank of New Zealand. Krippner (2012a,b) suggested modifications to the Black (1995) approach to allow for closed-form solutions to the option pricing problem. This allows for considerable simplification. Krippner (2012a,b,c) also emphasized a monetary policy application: Using the implied shadow overnight rate as a metric for the actual stance of monetary policy. One earlier U.S. monetary policy application is Bomfim (2003). * * See: A. Bomfim, 2003, Interest Rates as Options: Assessing the Markets View of the Liquidity Trap, Federal Reserve Board Finance and Economics Discussion Series paper 2003-45.

Example Source: Krippner (2012c).

Implications for U.S. Monetary Policy

Recommended U.S. monetary policy It has become popular in recent years to describe the desired level of the policy rate by using versions of Taylor-type policy rules. These rules relate the current value of the policy rate to macroeconomic variables such as inflation and output or unemployment gaps. Most policy rules in this class currently recommend a negative policy rate.

One recommended policy One possible policy rule is often called the Taylor (1999) rule: * R t = 2 + π t + 0.5 (π t 2) + 1.0 Y t π t : headline PCE inflation (year-over-year) Y t = 2.3 (5.6 U t ): output gap U t : unemployment rate Vice Chair Janet Yellen used this specification of the Taylor (1999) rule in her June 6, 2012, speech Perspectives on Monetary Policy given at the Boston Economic Club Dinner. * See J.B. Taylor, 1999, A Historical Analysis of Monetary Policy Rules, in J.B. Taylor, ed., Monetary Policy Rules, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

One recommended policy We can plot the recommended policy rate according to the Taylor (1999) rule. In some ways this plot does not make sense, since the recommended short-term rate is negative, which cannot occur. One interpretation is that other, unconventional policies have been needed to try to achieve the recommended policy rate. But, how do we know if those unconventional policies are working?

Plot of the Taylor (1999) policy recommendation Source: Federal Reserve Board, Bureau of Economic Analysis, Bureau of Labor Statistics and author s calculations. Last observation: October, 2012.

Application of Krippner The Krippner calculation of a shadow short-term nominal interest rate allows us to compare a measure of actual policy against the recommended policy from a standard policy rule. The Krippner approach is dubbed ZLB-GATSM. Zero lower bound Gaussian affine term structure model. Krippner uses an estimated two-factor GATSM from his earlier work. More extensive empirical work is desirable, and further research on this topic is something I encourage.

Recommended policy versus actual policy Source: Federal Reserve Board, Bureau of Economic Analysis, Bureau of Labor Statistics and author s calculations; the estimated shadow rate was kindly provided by Leo Krippner. Last observation: October, 2012.

Current policy may be easier than often perceived According to these estimates, the shadow policy rate is currently more than 300 basis points lower than the rate recommended by the Taylor (1999) rule. This suggests that actual U.S. monetary policy may currently be easier than the recommendations from that particular rule.

More implications In 2009, policy may have been too tight relative to the recommended Taylor (1999) rate. The FOMC at that point had not taken many of the unconventional policy actions and did not expect to do so. The actual policy stance as measured by the shadow rate has recently been more volatile than during the pre-2008 era. This may be because monetary policy has been harder to interpret during the period of the zero lower bound.

A closer look: Forward guidance Source: the estimated shadow rate was kindly provided by Leo Krippner. Last observation: October, 2012.

A closer look: QE Source: the estimated shadow rate was kindly provided by Leo Krippner. Last observation: October, 2012.

The value of unconventional policy The Krippner study gives us one way to evaluate recent unconventional policy actions by the FOMC. Significant unconventional policy actions at times seem to conform well with movements in the shadow policy rate. Times of less conformity may indicate an ineffective policy action.

The value of unconventional policy The accumulation of policy actions since 2008 has generally been associated with a continuing decline in the level of the shadow rate that is, an easier and easier policy stance. Krippner argues that these estimates are consistent with Williams (2011), * which are based on wholly different methods. * See J. Williams, 2011, Unconventional monetary policy: Lessons from the past three years, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Letter 2011-31.

Conclusions

Summary Recent research by Leo Krippner builds on earlier work following Fischer Black and others in thinking about the call option value of cash in a zero nominal interest rate environment. Krippner s findings suggest current U.S. monetary policy is easier than the policy recommended by commonly-used Taylor-type policy rules. These findings are interesting and I encourage further and more detailed analysis in this area.

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED) research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/ James Bullard research.stlouisfed.org/econ/bullard/