Research Article Welfare Comparison of Leader-Follower Models in a Mixed Duopoly

Similar documents
Welfare and Profit Comparison between Quantity and Price Competition in Stackelberg Mixed Duopolies

Advertisement Competition in a Differentiated Mixed Duopoly: Bertrand vs. Cournot

Research Article Extended Games Played by Managerial Firms with Asymmetric Costs

Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Mixed Motives of Simultaneous-move Games in a Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit

Organizational Structure and the Choice of Price vs. Quantity in a Mixed Duopoly

Price versus Quantity in a Mixed Duopoly under Uncertainty

Volume 29, Issue 1. Second-mover advantage under strategic subsidy policy in a third market model

Market Structure and Privatization Policy under International Competition

Coopetition in a Mixed Duopoly Mark. De Ngo, Duc; Okura, Mahito. Economics Bulletin, 12(20), pp.1-9; Issue Date

X. Henry Wang Bill Yang. Abstract

On supply function competition in a mixed oligopoly

Research Article A Mathematical Model of Communication with Reputational Concerns

Privatization and government preference. Abstract

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

Volume 29, Issue 2. Equilibrium Location and Economic Welfare in Delivered Pricing Oligopoly

Coopetition in a Mixed Duopoly Market

Export Taxes under Bertrand Duopoly. Abstract

Efficiency, Privatization, and Political Participation

The Timing of Endogenous Wage Setting under Bertrand Competition in a Unionized Mixed Duopoly

Mixed Oligopoly, Partial Privatization and Subsidization. Abstract

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly

Alternative Strategies of a Public Enterprise in Oligopoly Revisited: An Extension of Stackelberg Competition

Cournot-Bertrand competition in a unionized mixed duopoly

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Mixed Duopoly with Price Competition

Cournot-Bertrand Comparison in a Mixed Oligopoly

ENDOGENOUS TIMING IN A MIXED DUOPOLY: WEIGHTED WELFARE AND PRICE COMPETITION

What Industry Should We Privatize?: Mixed Oligopoly and Externality

Relative Performance and Stability of Collusive Behavior

Research Article The Optimal Licensing Contract in a Differentiated Stackelberg Model

Profit Share and Partner Choice in International Joint Ventures

Strategic Choice of Channel Structure in an Oligopoly

Urban unemployment, privatization policy, and a differentiated mixed oligopoly

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

Maximin and minimax strategies in asymmetric duopoly: Cournot and Bertrand

Noncooperative Oligopoly

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik ( December 29, 2008

Ex-ante versus ex-post privatization policies with foreign penetration in free-entry mixed markets

Patent Licensing in a Leadership Structure

Optimal Trade Policies for Exporting Countries under the Stackelberg Type of Competition between Firms

Oligopoly (contd.) Chapter 27

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Price discrimination in asymmetric Cournot oligopoly

Export subsidies, countervailing duties, and welfare

Analysis of a highly migratory fish stocks fishery: a game theoretic approach

Wage-Rise Contract and Entry Deterrence: Bertrand and Cournot

Does Timing of Decisions in a Mixed Duopoly Matter?

Regional restriction, strategic commitment, and welfare

The Nightmare of the Leader: The Impact of Deregulation on an Oligopoly Insurance Market

A monopoly is an industry consisting a single. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two. An oligopoly is an industry consisting of a few

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Econ 101A Final exam Th 15 December. Do not turn the page until instructed to.

Endogenous Price Leadership and Technological Differences

Price Competition in International Mixed Oligopolies

Microeconomics III. Oligopoly prefacetogametheory (Mar 11, 2012) School of Economics The Interdisciplinary Center (IDC), Herzliya

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies?

Strategic export policy, monopoly carrier, and product differentiation

Foreign direct investment and export under imperfectly competitive host-country input market

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND TRADE POLICY

research paper series

Differentiated duopoly with asymmetric costs: new results from a seminal model

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Haiyang Feng College of Management and Economics, Tianjin University, Tianjin , CHINA

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2012

Horizontal Mergers. Chapter 11: Horizontal Mergers 1

Quota bonuses in a principle-agent setting

CORVINUS ECONOMICS WORKING PAPERS. Quota bonuses as localized sales bonuses. by Barna Bakó, András Kálecz-Simon CEWP 1/2016

Quantity Competition vs. Price Competition under Optimal Subsidy in a Mixed Duopoly. Marcella Scrimitore. EERI Research Paper Series No 15/2012

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

Demand-Enhancing Investment in Mixed Duopoly

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals.

Strategic Production Game 1

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

Name: Midterm #1 EconS 425 (February 20 th, 2015)

Chapter 11: Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers

Capacity precommitment and price competition yield the Cournot outcome

The endogenous choice of delegation in a duopoly with input outsourcing to the rival

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

International Economics B 6. Applications of international oligopoly models

MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001

Math 152: Applicable Mathematics and Computing

p =9 (x1 + x2). c1 =3(1 z),

SOLVING COURNOT, STACKELBERG AND COLLUSION GAMES USING R

MKTG 555: Marketing Models

Cournot duopolies with investment in R&D: regions of Nash investment equilibria

Free-Trade Areas and Welfare: An Equilibrium Analysis. Sang-Seung Yi* This version: April 21, Abstract

CEREC, Facultés universitaires Saint Louis. Abstract

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9

Regulation of Foreign Direct Investment in. Mixed Oligopolies

Endogenous choice of decision variables

Economics 101A (Lecture 21) Stefano DellaVigna

Transcription:

Applied Mathematics Volume 03 Article ID 307 7 pages http://dx.doi.org/0.55/03/307 Research Article Welfare Comparison of Leader-Follower Models in a Mixed Duopoly Aiyuan Tao Yingjun Zhu and Xiangqing Zou 3 School of Mathematics and Information Science Shanghai Lixin University of Commerce Shanghai 060 China Accounting Research Institute Shanghai Lixin University of Commerce China 3 School of Accounting and Finance Shanghai Lixin University of Commerce China Correspondence should be addressed to Aiyuan Tao; taoaiyuan@6.com Received 9 September 03; Accepted October 03 Academic Editor: X. Henry Wang Copyright 03 Aiyuan Tao et al. This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License which permits unrestricted use distribution and reproduction in any medium provided the original work is properly cited. In the standard leader-follower duopoly models with otherwise symmetric firms the market outcome and total welfare are the same whichever firm is the leader. This paper studies and compares total welfare in a sequential-move mixed duopoly when either the public firm or the private firm acts as the leader. It is found that the fact that which firm is the leader affects total welfare and that whether firms compete in quantity or price also affects the optimal choice of market leader.. Introduction A mixed oligopoly is one in which private and public (or semipublic) firms coexist. Casual empiricism suggests that there are many mixed oligopolies in the real economies oftheworldespeciallyinlessthanfullydevelopedand recently developed economies. Theoretically many papers have been written on this topic. The sizable literature on mixed oligopolies dates back to Merril and Schneider []. More recent contributions are Matsumura [] and Matsumura and Ogawa [6] See De Fraja and Delbono[3] for a surveyoftheearlyliterature.thesepapershaveinvestigated a variety of issues related to mixed oligopolies. While both simultaneous- and sequential-move modelsarecommonlyadoptedinthestudyofpurelyprivate oligopolies with the most well-studied simultaneous-move models as the Cournot quantity competition model and the Bertrand price competition model and the most popular sequential-move models as the Stackelberg model in which firms quantities are sequentially chosen and the price leader-follower model sequential-move models for mixed oligopolies have not been studied much. Pal [4] Bàrcena- Ruiz [5] and Matsumura and Ogawa [6] havestudiedthe choice of price or quantity competition endogenously in a two-period mixed oligopoly model. This paper studies an issue that seems to be very relevant to mixed oligopolies and yet remains unexplored as of now. While in symmetric private duopolies in which firms face symmetric demands and have equal production costs which firm plays leader and the other the follower does not affect the market outcome and total welfare it is unclear whether this conclusion continues to hold true for a mixed duopoly. The present paper studies and compares total welfare in sequential-move mixed duopoly models. There is a public firmwhoseobjectiveistomaximizetotalwelfareanda private firm that maximizes its own profit. The firms produce differentiated goods. Both quantity leader-follower models and price leader-follower models are examined. Three main results are found in this study. First which firmplaystheleaderandtheotherfirmthefollowermatters to total welfare in a mixed duopoly. Second if firms compete in quantity then total welfare is higher if the private firm plays theleaderbutiftheycompeteinpricethentotalwelfare is higher if the public firm plays the leader. Finally total welfare is highest if firms compete in price with the public firm playing as the leader than if they compete in quantity with the private firm playing as the leader. The above results are derived in the main text of the paper by assuming that the firms have the same unit cost

Applied Mathematics of production. In Appendix it is shown that these results continue to hold even if the firms have different levels of unit production cost. Hence the findings here are independent of which firm is more efficient. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The next section introduces the basic model setup. Section 3 studies and compares total welfare under alternative quantity competition leader-follower models. Section 4 studies and compares total welfare under alternative price competition leader-follower models. A comparison of the two competition modes is also presented. Section 5 concludes the paper.. Model Setup We consider a differentiated goods market with two firms (labeled as firm and firm ). Firm is a public firm while firm is a private firm. The two firms face symmetric linear (inverse) demands: p =a q γq p =a q γq where p i and q i (i = )arethepriceandquantityof firm i s product a represents the maximum (nonnegative) price consumers are willing to pay for either good and γ (0 ) measures the level of substitutability between the two products. The more independent two goods are the smaller γ is and the closer the substitutes are the closer γ is to. In the main text of the paper we assume that firms produce at equal constant unit production cost c (0 c<a). In Appendix we show that the main results of the paper continue to hold even if the two firms have different unit costs of production. It is well known from Dixit [7]andHäckner [8](seeHsu and Wang [9] for an extension) that the demand system () above corresponds to a representative consumer model with a quasi-linear utility function given by U(q q )=a(q +q ) [(q ) +(q ) +γq q ]. () () 3. Alternative Quantity Leader-Follower Models Under quantity competition the leader chooses its output first followed by output choice by the follower. Our alternative models correspond to the public firm as the leader (Section 3.) and the private firm as the leader (Section 3.). 3.. Equilibrium with Public Firm as the Quantity Leader. Here the private firm is the quantity follower. We first find its best-response equation in quantity. Substituting the demand equation () for good into (4)and maximizing with respect to q yieldfirm sbest-responseasgivenby q = a c γq. (5) Thisresponseisthesameasinthestandardquantityleaderfollower game played by purely private firms. The quantity q is a decreasing function of q because quantities are strategic substitutes. Fromtheresponserelationship(5) we can find the leader firm s optimal choice of output in the first stage of the game. More specifically substituting () and(5) intototal welfare (3) and maximizing give firm s optimal output. All relevant results for this model are summarized in the following lemma. Since derivations for the results in this lemma and all subsequent lemmas are straightforward they are not provided in the paper but are available from the authors upon request. Lemma. When the firms compete in quantity with the public firm as the leader the equilibrium is given by the following (superscript here indicates that the public firm is the leader). p = γ( γ)a+(4 γ γ )c 4 3γ p = ( γ)a+(+γ 3γ )c 4 3γ. (6) The public firm s objective function is total welfare which is equal to total consumer surplus plus total firm profits and is given by W=U(q q ) c(q +q ). (3) The private firm s objective function is its profit given by Π = (p c) q. (4) In the next two sections we study alternative leaderfollower models under quantity competition (Section 3) and under price competition (Section 4) andcomparethe resulting total welfare levels. Π q = (4 3γ) (a c) 4 3γ q = ( γ)(a c) 4 3γ. = γ ( γ) (4 3γ) (a c) (4 3γ ) Π = 4( γ) (a c) (4 3γ ). (7) (8)

Applied Mathematics 3 W = (7 6γ) (a c). (9) (4 3γ ) 3.. Equilibrium with Private Firm as the Quantity Leader. Here the public firm is the quantity follower. We first find its best-response equation in quantity. Substituting () into(3) and maximizing with respect to q yield firm s best-response in quantity as given by Proof. From Lemmas and W W = (7 6γ) (a c) (4 3γ ) = 3γ ( γ) (a c) 8(+γ)(4 3γ ) <0. The proposition follows immediately. (7 + γ) (a c) 8(+γ) (5) q =a c γq. (0) Comparingthisresponsewiththatoftheprivatefirm sgiven in (5) the public firm is more responsive in that it wants to producemoreoutputinresponsetoanyquantitychoiceby the private leader than a private firm would. Fromtheresponserelationship(0) we can find the leader firm s optimal choice of output in the first stage of the game. More specifically substituting (0) into firm s profit (4) and maximizing give firm s optimal output. All relevant results for this model are summarized in the following lemma. Lemma. When the firms compete in quantity with the private firm as the leader the equilibrium is given by the following (superscript here indicates that firm is the leader). p =c q p ( γ) a + ( + γ) c =. () ( + γ) (a c) = q (+γ) = a c (+γ). () Π =0 W = Π ( γ) (a c) =. (3) 4(+γ) (7 + γ) (a c). (4) 8(+γ) 3.3. Comparison of Alternative Quantity Leader-Follower Models. Although we can make several comparisons based on the results in Lemmas and we will simply report themainresultweseektofindoutinthispaperinthe comparison of total welfare under alternative models. The following proposition reports the comparison result when the firms compete in quantity. Proposition 3. Under quantity competition total welfare is higher when the private firm plays the leader and the public firm plays the follower. From this proposition when firms compete in quantity if the government wants to promote social welfare it should try to make the public firm a follower in the quantity leaderfollower game. 4. Alternative Price Leader-Follower Models Under price competition the leader chooses its price first followed by price choice by the follower. Our alternative models correspond to the public firm as the leader (Section 4.) and the private firm as the leader (Section 4.). For the derivations of this section we need to provide the direct demand equations. Inverting the demand system () gives the equivalent demands as q = q = a +γ γ p γ + γ p a +γ γ p γ + γ p. (6) 4.. Equilibrium with Public Firm as the Price Leader. Here the private firm is the price follower. We first find its bestresponse equation in price. Substituting the demand equation (6) forgoodinto(4) andmaximizingwithrespecttop yield firm s best-response in price as given by p = ( γ)a+c+γp. (7) Thisresponseisthesameasinthestandardpriceleaderfollower model played by purely private firms. The price p is an increasing function of p because prices are strategic supplements. From the response relationship (7) we can find the leader firm s optimal choice of price in the first stage of the game. More specifically substituting () and(7) into total welfare (3) and maximizing give firm s optimal price. All relevant results for this model are summarized in the following lemma. Lemma 4. When the firms compete in price with the public firm as the leader the equilibrium is given by the following (the additional superscript here indicates that it is for the price competition model).

4 Applied Mathematics p = γ( γ)a+(4 γ γ )c 4 3γ p = ( γ) ( γ )a+(+γ γ γ 3 )c 4 3γ. (8) Π = γ(a c) ( + γ) (a Π c) = 4( + γ). (5) W = (7 + 8γ) (a c) 8( + γ). (6) q = (4 + γ 3γ γ 3 ) (a c) ( + γ) (4 3γ ) q = ( γ ) (a c) ( + γ) (4 3γ ). Π = γ( γ)(4+γ 3γ γ 3 ) (a c) ( + γ) (4 3γ ) Π = ( γ) ( γ ) (a c) ( + γ) (4 3γ ). (9) (0) W = (7 + γ 5γ γ 3 ) (a c). () (+γ)(4 3γ ) 4.. Equilibrium with Private Firm as the Price Leader. Here thepublicfirmisthepricefollower.wefirstfinditsbestresponse equation in price. Substituting the demand equation (6) for good into total welfare (3) andmaximizingwith respect to p yield firm s best-response in price as given by p = ( γ) c+γp. () Note that since ( γ)c < [( γ)a + c]/ thepublic firm sresponseinpriceisnotmoreaggressivethanthatof the private firm s given in (7).Thisreflectsthepublicfirm s interest in keeping the prices low. Fromtheresponserelationship() we can find the leader firm s optimal choice of price in the first stage of the game. More specifically using () maximizing firm s profit (4) gives firm s optimal price. All relevant results for this model are summarized in the following lemma. Lemma 5. When the firms compete in price with the private firm as the leader the equilibrium is given by the following. p = γa + ( + γ) c p = a+(+γ)c. (3) (+γ) (+γ) q = a c +γ q = a c (+γ). (4) 4.3. Comparison of Alternative Price Leader-Follower Models. The following proposition reports the comparison result in total welfare when the firms compete in price. Proposition 6. Under price competition total welfare is higher when the public firm plays the leader and the private firm plays the follower. Proof. From Lemmas 4 and 5 W W = (7+γ 5γ γ 3 )(a c) (+γ)(4 3γ ) (7+8γ)(a c) 8( + γ) = γ (5 4γ )(a c) 8( + γ) (4 3γ ) >0. The proposition follows immediately. (7) From this proposition when firms compete in price if the government wants to promote social welfare it should try to make the public firm the leader in the price leader-follower game. Finally a comparison of the results under both quantity and price competition can reveal which competition mode leads to higher total welfare when firms make their choices sequentially. This result is summarized in the next proposition. Proposition 7. Total welfare is highest when firms compete in price with the public firm playing the leader and the private firm the follower. Proof. By Propositions 3 and 6 we need only to compare the total welfare under price competition with the public firm as the leader and that under quantity competition with the private firm as the leader. The difference in total welfare of concern here is given by W W = (7 + γ 5γ γ 3 ) (a c) (+γ)(4 3γ ) (7 + γ) (a c) 8(+γ) from which follows the proposition. = γ ( γ) (a c) 8(+γ)(4 3γ ) >0 (8)

Applied Mathematics 5 Hence if the government can influence the nature of competition (between price and quantity) it will try to make firms compete in price and make the public firm the leader in the price leader-follower game. 5. Conclusion Using a simple differentiated goods linear demand framework this paper has studied and compared total welfare in a mixed duopoly with sequential moves. Both quantity leader-follower models and price leader-follower models are considered. It is found that total welfare is affected by which firm is the leader and whether firms compete in quantity or price. Appendix In this appendix we extend the analyses in the text by allowing the two firms to have different levels of unit costs of production. Let c i denote the constant unit production cost of firm i (i =). In the following we present the counterparts of the four lemmas in the text. They correspond to the four relevant scenarios: leader-follower model with the public firm as leader under quantity competition leader-follower model with the private firm as leader under quantity competition leader-follower model with the public firm as leader under price competition and leader-follower model with the private firm as leader under price competition. We start with the quantity competition models. The firms best-responses in quantity as follower are now given by q = a c γq q =a c γq. (A.) Applying the same procedures introduced in the text we obtain the following lemmas regarding the quantity competition leader-follower models. Lemma A.. When the firms compete in quantity with the public firm as the leader the equilibrium is given by the following. Π = γ[( γ)a+γc c ][(4 3γ)a 4c +3γc ] (4 3γ ) Π = 4[( γ) a+γc c ] (4 3γ ). W = ((7 6γ)a (4c +3c )a +6γ (c +c )a+4(c ) +3(c ) 6γc c ) ((4 3γ )). (A.4) (A.5) Lemma A.. When the firms compete in output with the private firm as the leader the equilibrium is given by the following. p =c p = ( γ) a + γc +c. (A.6) q = ( γ γ )a ( γ )c +γc ( γ ) q = ( γ) a + γc c. ( γ ) (A.7) Π =0 Π = [( γ) a + γc c ]. (A.8) 4( γ ) W = ((7 6γ γ )a (4c +3c 3γc 3γc γ c ) p = γ( γ)a+( γ )c γc 4 3γ p = ( γ)a+γc +( 3γ )c 4 3γ. q = (4 3γ) a 4c +3γc 4 3γ q = [( γ)a+γc c ] 4 3γ. (A.) (A.3) a+(4 γ )(c ) +3(c ) 6γc c ) (8( γ )). From Lemmas A. and A. W W = 3γ [( γ) a + γc c ] 8( γ )(4 3γ ) (A.9) <0. (A.0) This confirms that the result in Proposition 3 continues to hold when the two firms have differing unit costs of production.

6 Applied Mathematics We next work with the price competition models. The firms best-responsesinpriceasfollowerarenowgivenby p = ( γ) a + c +γp p =c γc +γp. (A.) Applying the same procedures introduced in the text we obtain the following lemmas regarding the price competition leader-follower models. Lemma A.3. When the firms compete in price with the public firm as the leader the equilibrium is given by the following. p = γ( γ)a+( γ )c γc 4 3γ p = ( γ) ( γ )a+γ( γ )c +( γ )c 4 3γ. (A.) q = ((4 3γ 4γ +γ 3 +γ 4 )a ( γ ) c +γ(3 γ )c ) Lemma A.4. When the firms compete in price with the private firm as the leader the equilibrium is given by the following. = γ( γ)a+( γ )c γc ( γ ) p = ( γ) a + γc +( γ )c. ( γ ) p (A.6) q = ( γ) a c +γc γ q = ( γ) a + γc c. ( γ ) (A.7) Π = γ[( γ)a c +γc ][( γ)a+γc c ] ( γ ) Π = [( γ) a + γc c ] 4( γ ). (A.8) (( γ )(4 3γ )) q = ( γ ) (a c) ( + γ) (4 3γ ). (A.3) W = ((7 6γ 9γ +8γ 3 )a +( γ) [( 4 γ+4γ )c (3 4γ )c ]a+(4 5γ ) (c ) +(3 4γ )(c ) γ(3 4γ )c c ) Π = (γ[( γ)a+γc c ] (8( γ ) ). (A.9) [(4 3γ 4γ +γ 3 +γ 4 )a From Lemmas A.3 and A.4 ( γ ) c +γ(3 γ )c ]) (( γ )(4 3γ ) ) (A.4) W W = γ (5 4γ )[( γ)a+γc c ] 8( γ ) (4 3γ ) >0. (A.0) Π = ( γ ) [( γ) a + γc c ] ( γ )(4 3γ ). W = ((7 6γ 6γ +4γ 3 +γ 4 )a +( γ) [( 4 γ+3γ +γ 3 )c (3 γ )c ]a +( γ ) (c ) +(3 γ )(c ) γ (3 γ )c c ) (( γ )(4 3γ )). (A.5) This confirms that the result in Proposition 6 continues to hold when the two firms have differing unit costs of production. Finally we compare the total welfare under price competition with the public firm as the leader and that under quantity competition with the private firm as the leader. From the results above the difference in total welfare of concern here is given by W W = γ [( γ) a + γc c ] >0. (A.) 8( γ )(4 3γ ) It follows that the result in Proposition 7 also continues to hold when the two firms have differing unit costs of production.

Applied Mathematics 7 References [] W. Merril and N. Schneider Government firms in oligopoly industries: a short run analysis Quarterly Economics vol. 80 pp. 400 4 966. [] T. Matsumura Partial privatization in mixed duopoly Journal of Public Economics vol. 70 no. 3 pp. 473 483 998. [3] G.DeFrajaandF.Delbono Gametheoreticmodelsofmixed oligopoly Economic Surveysvol.4pp. 7989. [4] D. Pal Endogenous timing in a mixed oligopoly Economics Lettersvol.6no.pp.8 85998. [5] J. C. Bárcena-Ruiz Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly: price competition Economicsvol.9no.3pp.63 7 007. [6] T. Matsumura and A. Ogawa Price versus quantity in a mixed duopoly Economics Lettersvol.6no.pp.74 770. [7] A. Dixit A model of duopoly suggesting a theory of entry barriers Bell Economicsvol.0pp.0 3979. [8] J. Häckner A note on price and quantity competition in differentiated oligopolies Economic Theory vol.93 no. pp. 33 39 000. [9] J. Hsu and X. H. Wang On welfare under Cournot and Bertrand Competition in differentiated oligopolies Review of Industrial Organizationvol.7no.pp.85 9005.

Advances in Operations Research Advances in Decision Sciences Applied Mathematics Algebra Probability and Statistics The Scientific World Journal International Differential Equations Submit your manuscripts at International Advances in Combinatorics Mathematical Physics Complex Analysis International Mathematics and Mathematical Sciences Mathematical Problems in Engineering Mathematics Discrete Mathematics Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society Function Spaces Abstract and Applied Analysis International Stochastic Analysis Optimization