Provision versus Appropriation in Symmetric and Asymmetric Social Dilemmas. James C. Cox, Elinor Ostrom, Vjollca Sadiraj, and James M.

Similar documents
Rational Choice and Moral Monotonicity. James C. Cox

ANDREW YOUNG SCHOOL OF POLICY STUDIES

In reality; some cases of prisoner s dilemma end in cooperation. Game Theory Dr. F. Fatemi Page 219

Prisoner s dilemma with T = 1

Topic 3 Social preferences

Social preferences I and II

Game Theory. Wolfgang Frimmel. Repeated Games

Games of Incomplete Information ( 資訊不全賽局 ) Games of Incomplete Information

Endogenous Shifts Over Time in Patterns of Contributions in Public Good Games

Agenda. Game Theory Matrix Form of a Game Dominant Strategy and Dominated Strategy Nash Equilibrium Game Trees Subgame Perfection

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Graduate School of Management and Economics

Social Norms, Information and Trust among Strangers: Theory and Evidence

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 2. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

USING LOTTERIES TO FINANCE PUBLIC GOODS: THEORY AND EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE

Game Theory I 1 / 38

Game Theory I 1 / 38

Tit for tat: Foundations of preferences for reciprocity in strategic settings

Introduction to Game Theory Lecture Note 5: Repeated Games

Today. Applications of NE and SPNE Auctions English Auction Second-Price Sealed-Bid Auction First-Price Sealed-Bid Auction

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Econ 601 Prof. James Peck Extra Practice Problems Answers (for final)

Bargaining or Searching for a Better Price? - An Experimental Study

ECON 803: MICROECONOMIC THEORY II Arthur J. Robson Fall 2016 Assignment 9 (due in class on November 22)

Exercises Solutions: Game Theory

PhD Qualifier Examination

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

Moral Costs and Rational Choice: Theory and Experimental Evidence

Introduction to Multi-Agent Programming

The nature of voluntary public good

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

Journal of Public Economics

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 5

Game Theory Lecture #16

On Delays in Project Completion With Cost Reduction: An Experiment

Cooperation and Reciprocity in Carbon Sequestration Contracts

preferences of the individual players over these possible outcomes, typically measured by a utility or payoff function.

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 4

Simon Fraser University Fall Econ 302 D200 Final Exam Solution Instructor: Songzi Du Wednesday December 16, 2015, 8:30 11:30 AM

Common Pool Resource Management and the Effect of Heterogeneous Users: an Experimental Investigation

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

Outline for today. Stat155 Game Theory Lecture 13: General-Sum Games. General-sum games. General-sum games. Dominated pure strategies

Cheap talk and cooperation in Stackelberg games

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Psychology and Economics Field Exam August 2012

Homework #2 Psychology 101 Spr 03 Prof Colin Camerer

Seeds to Succeed? Sequential Giving to Public Projects 1

Announcement, Observation, and Honesty in the Voluntary Contributions Game

Debt and (Future) Taxes: Financing Intergenerational Public Goods

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 12

CeDEx Discussion Paper Series ISSN Discussion Paper No Simon Gächter, Daniele Nosenzo, Elke Renner and Martin Sefton March 2009

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 4

Tit for Tat: Foundations of Preferences for Reciprocity in Strategic Settings

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

Introduction to Game Theory

Other Regarding Preferences

Sequential-move games with Nature s moves.

Public Goods Provision with Rent-Extracting Administrators

Altruism and Noisy Behavior in One-Shot Public Goods Experiments

Chapter 11: Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers

Lecture 5 Leadership and Reputation

Epistemic Experiments: Utilities, Beliefs, and Irrational Play

SI Game Theory, Fall 2008

Game Theory. VK Room: M1.30 Last updated: October 22, 2012.

Econ 711 Homework 1 Solutions

5.2 Definitions. pure public good. pure private good. commons: tendency of overusing. nonexcludability. nonrivalry. excludable & rivalry

Game Theory Problem Set 4 Solutions

Game Theory: Global Games. Christoph Schottmüller

EconS 301 Intermediate Microeconomics. Review Session #13 Chapter 14: Strategy and Game Theory

Cooperation and Rent Extraction in Repeated Interaction

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts

Endowment inequality in public goods games: A re-examination by Shaun P. Hargreaves Heap* Abhijit Ramalingam** Brock V.

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Second Midterm Examination Answers

An introduction on game theory for wireless networking [1]

MATH 4321 Game Theory Solution to Homework Two

MS&E 246: Lecture 5 Efficiency and fairness. Ramesh Johari

Journal of Economic Psychology

Overuse of a Common Resource: A Two-player Example

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1

Seeds to Succeed: Sequential Giving to Public Projects

Advanced Microeconomic Theory EC104

Solution to Tutorial 1

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014

Solution to Tutorial /2013 Semester I MA4264 Game Theory

When Equality Trumps Reciprocity

ECE 586GT: Problem Set 1: Problems and Solutions Analysis of static games

Game Theory Notes: Examples of Games with Dominant Strategy Equilibrium or Nash Equilibrium

Right Contract for Right Workers? Incentive Contracts for Short-term and Long-term Employees

Chair of Communications Theory, Prof. Dr.-Ing. E. Jorswieck. Übung 5: Supermodular Games

Mechanism Design: Single Agent, Discrete Types

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals.

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

Game Theory - Lecture #8

Repeated games. Felix Munoz-Garcia. Strategy and Game Theory - Washington State University

Strategy -1- Strategy

Suggested solutions to the 6 th seminar, ECON4260

A brief introduction to evolutionary game theory

Rent Shifting and the Order of Negotiations

Lecture 1: Normal Form Games: Refinements and Correlated Equilibrium

CHAPTER 14: REPEATED PRISONER S DILEMMA

The Strategic Advantage of Inequality Averse Preferences

Transcription:

Provision versus Appropriation in Symmetric and Asymmetric Social Dilemmas James C. Cox, Elinor Ostrom, Vjollca Sadiraj, and James M. Walker

Much-studied Social Dilemmas for Symmetric Agents In a standard provision (or public good) game: Agents simultaneously choose contributions They share equally in the produced public good The central question is the significance of under-provision In a standard appropriation (or common-pool resource) game Symmetric agents simultaneously choose extractions They share equally in the remaining common pool The central question is the significance of over-exploitation

Power Asymmetries Natural environments with public-good and common-pool social dilemmas are often characterized by power asymmetries. Our central question is how power asymmetries affect the significance of under-provision and over-exploitation.

Participants in the Experiments Undergraduate students at o Georgia State o Indiana University

Experiment Design A. Construct pairs of provision and appropriation games with symmetric and asymmetric power: All game pairs are strategically equivalent for homo economicus theory and all non-reciprocal social preference theories (Fehr-Schmidt, 1999; Bolton-Ockenfels, 2000; Charness-Rabin, 2002; Cox-Sadiraj, 2007, 2010) Asymmetric power games are not isomorphic for revealed altruism theory (Cox, Friedman, and Gjerstad, 2007; Cox, Friedman, and Sadiraj, 2008) B. Conduct experiments with the games: one shot (single round)

Specific Questions for Effects of Power Asymmetry I. Do FMs in provision or appropriation games behave differently when there (a) are or (b) are not SMs with unequal power? II. How do SMs with unequal power ( bosses and kings ) actually behave? III. In light of I and II, what differences are there in the overall level of cooperation achieved, in final outcomes, and in their distribution? IV. Are the data consistent with: A. Non-reciprocal (social and economic man) preference theories? B. Revealed altruism theory?

Endowments Baseline Game: 4 Simultaneous Movers PG: Each individual begins with 10 tokens worth $1 each in a Private Fund (PF) AG: Each group begins with an endowment of 40 tokens worth $3 each in a Group Fund (GF) Feasible Actions PG: Each token x {0,1,,10} moved from PF to GF by person j reduces value of PF by $1 and increases value of GF by $3 AG: Each token {0,1,,10} y moved from GF to PF by person j reduces value of GF by $3 and increases PF by $1

Baseline Game: 4 Simultaneous Movers (cont.) Payoffs PG: Individual s payoff = individual s PF + GF/4 AG: Individual s payoff = individual s PF + GF/4 Group Maximum Payoff PG: 40 tokens PUT IN the GF with value of $120 AG: 40 tokens LEFT IN the GF with value of $120

Boss Game: 3 First Movers, 1 Second Mover First Movers Feasible Actions First Movers ( workers ) have same feasible actions as in baseline game; each can contribute (BPG) or remove (BAG) up to 10 tokens Boss s Feasible Actions BPG: Boss moves after seeing decisions of 3 First Movers; she can contribute up to 10 tokens BAG: Boss moves after seeing decisions of 3 First Movers; she can remove up to 10 tokens

King Game: 3 First Movers, 1 Second Mover First Movers Feasible Actions First Movers ( peasants ) have same feasible actions as in baseline game; each can contribute (KPG) or remove (KAG) up to 10 tokens King s Feasible Actions KPG: King moves after seeing decisions of 3 First Movers; he can contribute himself or remove FM contributions to GF KAG: King moves after seeing decisions of 3 First Movers; he can forgo extraction himself or remove any remaining amount in GF

Simultaneous-Move Provision Game Payoff Equivalence Each of N agents is endowed with e tokens in a Private Fund and can transfer xj {1,2,, e} to the Group Fund. Each token transferred reduces the value of PF by $1 and increases the value of GF by $M, where M < N. The money payoff to representative agent i is N p i i j j 1 e x M x / N

Payoff Equivalence (cont.) Simultaneous-Move Appropriation Game The group of N agents is endowed with a Group Fund containing E = Ne tokens worth $M each. Each agent can transfer zj {1,2,, e} to her Private Fund. Each token transferred reduces the value of GF by $M and increases the value of PF by $M, where M < N. The money payoff to representative agent i is N z M ( E z ) / N a i i j j 1

If e x j z j, for j = 1,2,, N then a i i i i 1 Payoff Equivalence (cont.) N e x M ( Ne ( e x )) / N N e xi M ( Ne Ne xi / N i 1 N p i j / i j 1 e x M x N for i = 1,2,, N

Hypotheses Proposition 1. Assume homo economicus preferences. Agents have a dominant strategy to contribute zero to the Group Fund in a provision game or extract the maximum amount possible from the Group Fund in an appropriation game. Hypothesis 1: Average earnings of players in a provision or appropriation game will be the minimum possible amount $e.

Hypotheses (cont.) Proposition 2. Assume either social preferences or homo economicus preferences. In the simultaneous-move games, a vector of appropriations g* into Individual Funds in the appropriation game a. is a Nash equilibrium if and only if the vector of amounts g* retained in Individual Funds is a Nash equilibrium in the provision game b.allocates to player i the same payoff in the appropriation game as does the vector of amounts g* retained in Individual Funds in the provision game. Hypothesis 2: Average earnings of players are the same in the simultaneous provision and appropriation games.

Hypotheses (cont.) Proposition 3. For fixed (homo economicus and social) preferences, in the sequential-move games a vector of appropriations g* into Individual Funds in the appropriation game a. is an outcome of a Nash equilibrium if and only if the vector of amounts retained g* in Individual Funds is an outcome of a Nash equilibrium in the provision game b.allocates to player i the same payoff as the vector of amounts retained g* in Individual Funds in the provision game. Hypothesis 3: Average earnings of players are the same in the sequential provision and appropriation games.

Hypotheses (cont.) Proposition 4. For sequential-move finite (provision or appropriation) games, for any vector of first movers choices x, the total group payoff from B (x,br (x)) in the boss game is (weakly) higher than the total group payoff from in the king game. K (x,br (x)) Hypothesis 4: For any given contributions of the first movers, the total group earnings in a sequential king game are not larger than total group earnings in a sequential boss game.

Hypotheses (cont.) Proposition 5. Let first movers retain g-n in their Individual Funds in the provision game and add g -N to their Individual Funds in the appropriation game. A second mover with reciprocal preferences characterized by Axioms R and S will add more to his Individual Fund in the appropriation game than he retains in his Individual Fund in the provision game. Hypothesis 5: Bosses (resp. kings ) contributions to the Group Fund in the provision game are larger than the amounts they leave in the Group Fund in the appropriation game.

Table 1. Nob. of Ind. Subject (and Group) Observations by Treatment Simultaneous Games Boss Games King Games 32 28 76 Provision (8 Groups) (7 Groups) (19 Groups) Games 36 32 76 Appropriation (9 Groups) (8 Groups) (19 Groups) Games

Table 2. Experimental Earnings by Subject Type and Treatment Simultaneous Games Boss Games First Mover Sec. Mover First Mover King Games Sec. Mover Provision Games $24.19 $19.53 $21.43 $16.43 $21.92 Approp. Games $22.39 $20.84 $21.31 $11.04 $22.10

$120 Maximum Possible Payoffs $100 $96.76 $80 $80.00 $71.26 $89.56 $83.50 $60 $54.74 $40 Minimum Possible Payoffs $20 PG BPG KPG AG BAG KAG Figure 1. Average Group Earnings by Treatment

Results Result 1: Average group earnings across the two baseline conditions (PG and AG) are very similar. Earnings are well above the minimum predicted by the dominant strategy equilibrium for the special case of homo economicus preferences (which is $40). Result 1 is inconsistent with Hypothesis 1 but consistent with Hypothesis 2.

Result 2: Average earnings are lower in the asymmetric power BPG and BAG treatments than in the symmetric power PG and AG treatments, and are even lower in the asymmetric power KPG and KAG treatments. The second part of result 2 is consistent with Hypothesis 4. Power asymmetries decrease efficiency (or realized surplus) in both provision and appropriation settings. Low efficiency is especially a feature of the king treatment for the appropriation setting, which is inconsistent with Hypothesis 3 but consistent with Hypothesis 5. Treatment KAG comes closest to manifesting a strong form tragedy of the commons.

Result 3: Pooling across decision groups (n=70), least squares analysis of total allocations to the Group Fund leads to the following results related to selective tests of equality. Group Fund differences between treatments in provision settings are statistically significant for PG vs. BPG and for PG vs. KPG. Group Fund differences between treatments in appropriation settings are significant for AG vs. KAG and for BAG vs. KAG. Group Fund differences are significantly lower for KAG than for KPG. Lower allocation to the Group Fund in KAG than in BAG is consistent with (an equivalent restatement of) Hypothesis 4. Lower allocation to the Group Fund in KAG than in KPG is inconsistent with (an equivalent restatement of) Hypothesis 3.

Figure 2. Ave. First Mover Decisions Represented as $ in Group Fund $30 Maximum Possible Contribution 24 $21.27 18 $16.44 $15.84 $18.57 $16.74 12 $13.41 6 PG BPG KPG AG BAG KAG

Result 4: Pooling across first mover decisions (n=227), least squares analysis of token allocations to the Group Fund (tokens left in the Group Fund) leads to the following results related to selective tests of equality. Group Fund differences between treatments in provision settings are statistically significant for PG vs. KPG. Group Fund differences between treatments in appropriation settings are significant for AG vs. KAG.

Figure 3. Ave. Sec. Mover Decisions Represented as $ in Group Fund $30 Maximum Feasible Allocation 15 $10.62 $15.00 0 $-0.63-15 $-18.16-30 BPG KPG BAG KAG Minimum Feasible Allocation Equals $0.00 Minimum Feasible Allocation Equals -$47.52 Minimum Feasible Allocation Equals $0.00 Minimum Feasible Allocation Equals -$40.23

Result 5: Only one coefficient estimate is statistically significant, the negative coefficient for the dummy variable for the KAG treatment. The coefficient for the KPG treatment is negative but insignificant. The significance of the coefficient for the KAG treatment is consistent with implications of reciprocal preferences, as stated in Hypothesis 5, but inconsistent with the implications of fixed preferences stated in Hypothesis 3.