HOW DOES 401(K) AUTO-ENROLLMENT RELATE TO THE EMPLOYER MATCH AND TOTAL COMPENSATION?

Similar documents
DO INDIVIDUALS KNOW WHEN THEY SHOULD BE SAVING FOR A SPOUSE?

IS PENSION INEQUALITY GROWING?

CAN EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT EXPLAIN THE RISE IN LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION AT OLDER AGES?

A NUDGE ISN T ALWAYS ENOUGH

DOG BITES MAN: AMERICANS ARE SHORTSIGHTED ABOUT THEIR FINANCES

HOW DO INHERITANCES AFFECT THE NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX?

WHY DON T LOWER-INCOME INDIVIDUALS HAVE PENSIONS?

HOW IMPORTANT IS MEDICARE ELIGIBILITY IN THE TIMING OF RETIREMENT?

HOW LONG DO UNEMPLOYED OLDER WORKERS SEARCH FOR A JOB?

MODERNIZING SOCIAL SECURITY: HELPING THE OLDEST OLD

SHOULD YOU CARRY A MORTGAGE INTO RETIREMENT?

HOW HAVE WORKERS RESPONDED TO OREGON S AUTO-IRA?

ARE PEOPLE CLAIMING SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS LATER?

HOW MUCH TO SAVE FOR A SECURE

USING PARTICIPANT DATA TO IMPROVE 401(k) ASSET ALLOCATION

HOW DOES WOMEN WORKING AFFECT SOCIAL SECURITY REPLACEMENT RATES?

AN ANNUITY THAT PEOPLE MIGHT ACTUALLY BUY

Research Report. The Population of Workers Covered by the Auto IRA: Trends and Characteristics. AARP Public Policy Institute.

AN ANNUITY THAT PEOPLE MIGHT ACTUALLY BUY

THE IMPACT OF LEAKAGES ON 401(K)/IRA ASSETS

WHY DID POVERTY DROP FOR THE ELDERLY?

401(k) PLANS AND RACE

THE IMPACT OF INTEREST RATES ON THE NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX

IMPACT OF PUBLIC SECTOR ASSUMED RETURNS ON INVESTMENT CHOICES

401(k) PLANS ARE STILL COMING UP SHORT

WRITTEN TESTIMONY SUBMITTED BY LORI LUCAS EXECUTIVE VICE PRESIDENT CALLAN ASSOCIATES

DO INCOME PROJECTIONS AFFECT RETIREMENT SAVING?

THE IMPACT OF INTEREST RATES ON THE NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2007 REPORT IN PERSPECTIVE

THE IMPACT OF RAISING CHILDREN ON RETIREMENT SECURITY

THE STATE OF PRIVATE PENSIONS: CURRENT 5500 DATA

HOW MUCH DOES HOUSING AFFECT RETIREMENT SECURITY? AN NRRI UPDATE

EMPLOYERS (LACK OF) RESPONSE TO THE RETIREMENT INCOME CHALLENGE

MEDICARE COSTS AND RETIREMENT SECURITY

NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX: HOW MUCH LONGER DO WE NEED TO WORK?

JOB TENURE AND THE SPREAD OF 401(K)S

WHY ARE OLDER WORKERS AT GREATER RISK OF DISPLACEMENT?

Automatic enrollment: The power of the default

THE STRUCTURE OF 401(k) FEES

THE IMPACT OF AGING BABY BOOMERS ON LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION

THE IMPACT OF INFLATION ON SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS

HOUSEHOLDS AT RISK : A CLOSER LOOK AT THE BOTTOM THIRD

center for retirement research

REDUCING DEFAULT RATES OF REVERSE MORTGAGES

Do Defaults Have Spillover Effects? The Effect of the Default Asset on Retirement Plan Contributions

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2006 UPDATE IN PERSPECTIVE

Will Automatic Enrollment Reduce Employer Contributions to 401(k) Plans? Mauricio Soto and Barbara A. Butrica

CRS Report for Congress

DO YOUNG ADULTS WITH STUDENT DEBT SAVE LESS FOR RETIREMENT?

EMPIRICAL REGULARITY SUGGESTS RETIREMENT RISKS

Volume Title: Social Security Policy in a Changing Environment. Volume Author/Editor: Jeffrey Brown, Jeffrey Liebman and David A.

HOW HAS THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AFFECTED THE CONSUMPTION OF RETIREES?

WikiLeaks Document Release

HOW IMPORTANT ARE INHERITANCES FOR BABY BOOMERS?

Automatic enrollment, employer match rates, and employee compensation in 401(k) plans

IS ADVERSE SELECTION IN THE ANNUITY MARKET A BIG PROBLEM?

WORKERS RESPONSE TO THE MARKET CRASH: SAVE MORE, WORK MORE?

Making the Most of Your Match

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2014 UPDATE IN PERSPECTIVE

OVER THE PAST TWO DECADES THERE HAS BEEN

THE U.K. S AMBITIOUS NEW RETIREMENT SAVINGS INITIATIVE

Written. Before the. Regarding. September 2009

PUBLIC SECTOR WORKERS AND JOB SECURITY

HOW RETIREMENT PROVISIONS AFFECT TENURE OF STATE AND LOCAL WORKERS

DOES SOCIOECONOMIC STATUS LEAD PEOPLE TO RETIRE TOO SOON?

ESTIMATING PENSION COVERAGE USING DIFFERENT DATA SETS

NRRI UPDATE SHOWS HALF STILL FALLING SHORT

THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AND STATE/LOCAL DEFINED BENEFIT PLANS

Dodged a bullet? "Rothification" likely to reduce retirement saving

IS WORKING LONGER A GOOD PRESCRIPTION FOR ALL?

STATE WAGE-PAYMENT LAWS, THE PENSION PROTECTION ACT OF 2006, AND 401(k) SAVING BEHAVIOR. Gary V. Engelhardt CRR WP

A primer on reverse mortgages

MAKING YOUR NEST EGG LAST A LIFETIME

PPI Briefing Note Number 99 (PhD Series No 2) Page 1

HOW SENSITIVE IS PUBLIC PENSION FUNDING TO INVESTMENT RETURNS?

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2011 UPDATE IN PERSPECTIVE

Opting out of Retirement Plan Default Settings

PENSION COVERAGE AND RETIREMENT SECURITY

DO STATE ECONOMICS OR INDIVIDUAL CHARACTERISTICS DETERMINE WHETHER OLDER MEN WORK?

DO PUBLIC PENSIONS HELP RECRUIT AND RETAIN HIGH-QUALITY WORKERS?

FIGURE 1: NATIONAL SAVING HAS PLUMMETED OVER PAST QUARTER CENTURY

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2018 UPDATE IN PERSPECTIVE

The Impact of Employer Matching on Savings Plan Participation under Automatic Enrollment

Does Borrowing Undo Automatic Enrollment s Effect on Savings?

The Benefits of. Presented By:

Demographic Change, Retirement Saving, and Financial Market Returns

Racial, Ethnic, and Gender Differentials in Employer-Sponsored Pensions

HOW MUCH DO OLDER WORKERS VALUE EMPLOYEE HEALTH INSURANCE?

THE NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX: AFTER THE CRASH

CAN PBGC SAVE MULTIEMPLOYER PLANS?

Some Considerations for Empirical Research on Tax-Preferred Savings Accounts.

PENSION WEALTH AND INCOME: 1992,

The Limitations of Defaults

STATE AND LOCAL PENSION COSTS: PRE- CRISIS, POST-CRISIS, AND POST-REFORM

Who Uses the Roth 401(k), and How Do They Use It?

Vanguard Research February 2016

REDUCING COSTS OF 401(k) PLANS WITH ETFs AND COMMINGLED TRUSTS

Prepared remarks for testimony before the Maryland Joint Committee on Pensions

For Better or For Worse: Default effects and 401(k) Savings Behavior

MAKING MAXIMUM USE OF TAX-DEFERRED RETIREMENT ACCOUNTS. Janette Kawachi, Karen E. Smith, and Eric J. Toder

Transcription:

October 2013, Number 13-14 RETIREMENT RESEARCH HOW DOES 401(K) AUTO-ENROLLMENT RELATE TO THE EMPLOYER MATCH AND TOTAL COMPENSATION? By Barbara A. Butrica and Nadia S. Karamcheva* Introduction Many workers eligible for 401(k) plans fail to participate and those who do participate often save too little. In response, policy experts have advocated auto-enrollment, in which employees are signed up at a default contribution rate unless they opt out. Over the past decade, a number of employers have adopted auto-enrollment, and these policies have clearly boosted participation. But the effect of auto-enrollment on workers total 401(k) saving is unclear, because it depends partly on employer decisions about plan design and worker compensation. And these decisions could be affected by the increase in employers 401(k) matching contributions generated by auto-enrollment. This brief, based on a recent paper, examines the relationship between auto-enrollment and employer decisions on matching contributions and overall compensation. 1 The discussion proceeds as follows. The first section considers why and how auto-enrollment could affect these decisions. The second section discusses the data used in the analysis. The third section explores whether auto-enrollment is associated with employers use of low match rates or low default employee contribution rates. The fourth section examines whether auto-enrollment is related to lower spending on non-401(k) compensation or higher spending on total compensation. The final section concludes that auto-enrollment is associated with relatively low match rates and default rates, but does not affect wages or total compensation. This finding suggests that firms with auto-enrollment may offset higher 401(k) participation costs by trimming their per-participant contributions. Auto Enrollment and Employer Compensation Auto-enrollment emerged in the late 1990s and spread rapidly after it was encouraged by the Pen- Protection Act of 2006. 2 In recent years, though, sion industry surveys suggest that its growth has moder- 3 One barrier to more widespread adoption is ated. the increase in the cost of employer matching contri- from increased 401(k) participation. 4 These butions costs naturally rise because, absent other changes in compensation policies, employers with auto-enroll- contribute to the 401(k) accounts of a larger ment percentage of their workforce. * Barbara A. Butrica is a senior research associate at the Income and Benefits Policy Center at the Urban Institute. Nadia S. Karamcheva is a research associate at the Income and Benefits Policy Center at the Urban Institute. Both of the authors are affiliated researchers of the at Boston College.

2 When faced with rising 401(k) costs, a company adopting auto-enrollment has four options. First, it could directly reduce its matching costs by lowering the match rate per dollar of employee contribution and/or by lowering the ceiling on the percent of contributions it will match. These changes would reduce the per-participant match, allowing the company to potentially accommodate an increase in participation without raising total 401(k) costs. Second, the firm could indirectly reduce its matching contributions by setting a default employee contribution rate below the level needed to obtain the maximum employer match. Participants could override the default and choose a higher saving rate but, in practice, participants tend to stay where they are put. 5 Third, the company could decide to offset higher match costs by reducing its employees wages or other non-401(k) benefits. Finally, it could keep its compensation policies the same and simply allow total compensation costs to rise. Few researchers have examined employers compensation decisions under auto-enrollment. An initial study showed that firms with auto-enrollment have lower match rates than those without it. But these conclusions remain tentative due to significant data limitations. For example, the authors did not have actual match rate data for a number of companies so they estimated the rates based on the ratio of total employer contributions to total employee contributions. 6 The study summarized in this brief reexamines the issue using better and more recent data and more broadly analyzes the relationship between auto-enrollment and total compensation. Data This study uses restricted data from the National Compensation Survey (NCS) conducted by the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. The NCS is a large nationally representative survey that collects data from establishments on earnings, pensions and other benefits, and characteristics such as establishment size, region, and industry. Importantly for this study, the pension data include details on plan type, match structure, match rates, employer contributions, and automatic enrollment. As a result, there is no need to rely on estimates of match rates. The analysis uses NCS data from 2010/2011. The sample is restricted to single-employer defined contribution plans with a match, specifically those designated as savings and thrift plans with a flat match rate structure. 7 The final sample includes about 1,200 savings and thrift plans. To make the findings repre- of employees, the analyses are weighted by sentative workers rather than plans. These data make it possible to examine employer behavior under auto-enrollment to assess which of the four options or combination of options em- choose in response to the higher cost pres- ployers sures from increased 401(k) participation. The next two sections discuss the results, covering the options on specific 401(k) design parameters and the options involving broader compensation choices, respectively. Does Auto-Enrollment Relate to Match Rates or Default Contribution Rates? A preliminary step is to simply confirm whether the auto-enrollment plans in the sample have higher participation rates. Indeed, their participation rates are 10 percentage points higher than the plans without auto-enrollment 77 percent vs. 67 percent. 8 All things equal, these higher rates will increase employers total compensation costs. If employers seek to offset the higher match costs by adjusting the parameters of their 401(k) plan, they can directly reduce their match rate policy and/or set a low default employee contribution. Match Rate Policy The first question examined is whether employers with auto-enrollment have lower maximum matches than employers without auto-enrollment. The maximum match rate is determined by the match rate the percentage of each dollar of employee contributions that is matched and the match ceiling the limit on the percentage of contributions that are matched. If a worker contributes up to the match ceiling, they receive the maximum employer match. For example, if a 401(k) plan has a match rate of 50 cents per dollar up to a ceiling of 6 percent of pay, the maximum match rate is 3 percent of pay. As shown in Figure 1 on the next page, workers covered by auto-enrollment have a maximum match rate of 3.2 percent of pay compared to 3.5 percent for those in plans without auto-enrollment, and this difference is statistically significant.

Issue in Brief 3 Figure 1. Maximum Match Rate for Workers in 401(k)s, With and Without Auto-Enrollment, 2010-11 4% 2% 0% 3.2% With auto-enrollment 3.5% Without auto-enrollment While this finding shows that, on average, plans with auto-enrollment have lower match rates, this difference might be driven by factors other than the automatic enrollment provision. For example, a larger percentage of the workers covered by autoenrollment in the sample have defined benefit plans in addition to 401(k)s. Since these workers have an additional source of pension coverage, their employers might offer less generous 401(k) matches. If so, defined benefit plan coverage could be driving the lower matches in auto-enrollment plans. To test this possibility, regression analysis was used with the maximum match rate as the dependent variable and auto-enrollment as the main independent variable, and including controls such as defined benefit coverage, industry size, type, and location, and degree of unionization. The results of the regression support the descriptive finding plans with auto-enrollment have a maximum match rate that is 0.38 percentage points lower than those without an automatic provision, even after controlling for other factors (see Figure 2). 9 The coefficient for defined benefit coverage turned out to be positive rather than negative but not statistically significant. With respect to industry type, firms in the financial, insurance, and real estate industries have significantly higher maximum match rates as do larger firms and those in metropolitan areas. Default Contribution Rates The second question is whether employers with autoenrollment choose low default employee contribution rates, which are very influential in determining actual employee contribution rates. For this analysis, it is not possible to compare firms with auto-enrollment to those without, because only firms with autoenrollment have default contribution rates. Within the sample of workers with auto-enrollment plans, the key benchmark is to compare the default contri- Figure 2. Relationship Between Selected Factors and the Maximum 401(k) Match Rate, 2010-11 Auto-enrollment -0.38 Share of workers with DB plan 0.09 Size of 500 or more participants 0.21 Financial, insurance, and real estate 1.09 Metropolitan area 0.26 Share of union workers -0.18-0.6 0 0.6 1.2 Note: The solid bars indicate the coefficient is statistically significant at least at the 10-percent level.

4 bution rates to the contribution rate needed for the maximum employer match. If the default rates are significantly lower, it suggests that employers may be using low default rates to limit their own contributions. One point to keep in mind is that some plans with auto-enrollment also include a feature that automatically increases the default rate over time up to a certain limit. These auto-escalation plans are included in the sample. On average, the default contribution rate for the auto-enrollment plans is 3.4 percent; it drops to 2.8 percent if plans with an auto-escalation feature are classified by their initial default rate rather than their full escalation default rate. To receive the maximum match in the sample plans, workers would need to contribute an average of 5.1 percent (see Figure 3). So the default rate is set well below the rate needed for the maximum match. One other benchmark of potential interest here is the average employee contribution rate in all 401(k) plans, including those without auto-enrollment. These data were not available for the sample plans, but employer surveys typically find a median rate of 6.0 percent, again well above the default rate used by employers with auto-enrollment. 10 Overall, these results suggest that, in addition to offering lower maximum match rates than plans without autoenrollment, employers with auto-enrollment may be using their default employee contribution rate to help offset the higher costs that come with higher participation rates. Figure 3. Default Employee Contribution Rate Compared to Match Ceiling for Workers with Auto-Enrollment Plans, 2010-11 6% 4% 2% 3.4% 5.1% Does Auto-Enrollment Affect Compensation Costs? The third and fourth questions examined in this analysis concern employers actual compensation costs where the rubber meets the road rather than their 401(k) plan design decisions. Recall that rising 401(k) costs could prompt employers to reduce wages or other non-401(k) compensation. Or, alternatively, employers could decide to simply allow their total compensation costs to rise. The compensation questions are examined using a series of regression equations with various measures of compensation as the dependent variables and auto-enrollment as the main independent variable. Again, controls are included for a variety of employer and workforce characteristics. Table 1 reports the relationship between autoenrollment and selected measures of compensation from different equations. The results of this exercise show no evidence that total compensation, 401(k) costs, non-401(k) costs, or wages differ between plans with and without auto-enrollment. These findings support the notion that employers with auto-enrollment may be aiming to keep their compensation costs roughly constant. While they end up spending more on workers who would not have participated without auto-enrollment, they spend less on workers who would have signed up anyway. Table 1. Relationship Between Auto-enrollment and Selected Measures of Employer Compensation Costs, 2010-11 Dependent variable Total costs Total 401(k) costs Non-401(k) costs Wages Effect of auto-enrollment Note: None of the effects are statistically significant. 0% Default contribution rate Match ceiling

Issue in Brief 5 Conclusion Employer decisions on 401(k) plan design have a significant influence on how much workers save for retirement both directly through employer matching contributions and, for auto-enrollment plans, indirectly through setting the default employee contribution rate. Auto-enrollment policies are very successful at raising participation rates but may not boost workers total retirement saving if firms aim to keep their 401(k) compensation costs at a constant level. While auto-enrollment will increase saving for workers who would not have participated without it, those who would have participated on their own may end up saving less due to relatively low employer match rates and low default contribution rates. Auto-enrollment policies are still quite new and future changes in plan design such as more widespread use of auto-escalation could have more positive effects on retirement saving levels. Therefore, it will be important to continue monitoring auto-enrollment both on the employer and the worker side to more fully assess its long-term impact on retirement saving. Endnotes 1 Butrica and Karamcheva (2012). 2 Specific provisions designed to encourage the adoption of auto-enrollment included: 1) providing more attractive safe harbor rules for satisfying non-discrimination requirements, such as a lower required maximum employer match of 3.5 percent (compared to 4.0 percent for plans without auto-enrollment); 2) preempting state payroll-withholding laws; and 3) relieving employers of fiduciary liability for the performance of default investments. 3 Vanguard (2013). 4 A 2011 survey found that 73 percent of plans that responded that they were unlikely to adopt autoenrollment (during that year) cited higher costs as a primary barrier (Hess and Xu, 2011). 5 See Madrian and Shea (2001) and Nessmith, Utkus, and Young (2007). 6 A contrasting study (VanDerhei 2010) found that firms adopting auto-enrollment had higher effective match rates than they did prior to instituting autoenrollment, but this study focused on large 401(k) plan sponsors. 7 The NCS does not collect data on the plan features of zero-match plans and only includes detailed information on the match structure of plans with flat matches. 8 A regression analysis with these data also confirmed that auto-enrollment is associated with higher participation rates. For other studies supporting the link between auto-enrollment and higher participation, see Beshears et al. (2009), Choi et al. (2002, 2004), and Madrian and Shea (2001). 9 Separate regressions were run to determine whether the lower maximum match is due to a lower match rate or a lower match ceiling. These results show that a lower match rate is the driver. For full results, see Butrica and Karamcheva (2012). 10 Vanguard (2013).

6 References Beshears, John, James J. Choi, David Laibson, and Brigitte C. Madrian. 2009. The Impact of Employer Matching on Savings Plan Participation under Automatic Enrollment. In Research Findings in the Economics of Aging, edited by David A. Wise. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Butrica, Barbara A. and Nadia S. Karamcheva. 2012. Automatic Enrollment, Employee Compensation, and Retirement Security. Working Paper 2012-25. Chestnut Hill, MA: at Boston College. Choi, James J., David Laibson, Brigitte C. Madrian, and Andrew Metrick. 2004. For Better or For Worse: Default Effects and 401(k) Saving Behavior. In Perspectives in the Economics of Aging, edited by David A. Wise. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Choi, James J., David Laibson, Brigitte C. Madrian, and Andrew Metrick. 2002. Defined Contribution Pensions: Plan Rules, Participant Decisions, and the Path of Least Resistance. In Tax Policy and the Economy, Volume 16, edited by James Poterba. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Hess, Pamela and Yan Xu. 2011. 2011 Trends and Experiences in Defined Contribution Plans: Paving the Road to Retirement. London: Aon Hewitt. Nessmith, William E., Stephen P. Utkus, and Jean A. Young. 2007. Measuring the Effectiveness of Automatic Enrollment. Valley Forge, PA: The Vanguard. Madrian, Brigitte C. and Dennis F. Shea. 2001. The Power of Suggestion: Inertia in 401(k) Participation and Savings Behavior. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 116(4): 1149-87. VanDerhei, Jack. 2010. The Impact of Automatic Enrollment in 401(k) Plans on Future Retirement Accumulations: A Simulation Study Based on Plan Design Modifications of Large Plan Sponsors. Issue Brief No. 341. Washington, DC: Employee Benefit Research Institute. Vanguard. 2013. How America Saves 2013. Valley Forge: PA.

RETIREMENT RESEARCH About the Center The mission of the at Boston College is to produce first-class research and educational tools and forge a strong link between the academic community and decision-makers in the public and private sectors around an issue of critical importance to the nation s future. To achieve this mission, the Center sponsors a wide variety of research projects, transmits new findings to a broad audience, trains new scholars, and broadens access to valuable data sources. Since its inception, the Center has established a reputation as an authoritative source of information on all major aspects of the retirement income debate. Affiliated Institutions The Brookings Institution Massachusetts Institute of Technology Syracuse University Urban Institute Contact Information Boston College Hovey House 140 Commonwealth Avenue Chestnut Hill, MA 02467-3808 Phone: (617) 552-1762 Fax: (617) 552-0191 E-mail: crr@bc.edu Website: http://crr.bc.edu 2013, by Trustees of Boston College, Center for Retirement Research. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that the authors are identified and full credit, including copyright notice, is given to Trustees of Boston College,. The research reported herein was performed pursuant to a grant from the U.S. Social Security Administration (SSA) funded as part of the Retirement Research Consortium. The opinions and conclusions expressed are solely those of the authors and do not represent the opinions or policy of SSA, any agency of the federal government, or the Center for Retirement Research at Boston College.