Non-Time-Separable Utility: Habit Formation

Similar documents
INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model

Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice

Intertemporally Dependent Preferences and the Volatility of Consumption and Wealth

Limits to Arbitrage. George Pennacchi. Finance 591 Asset Pricing Theory

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

1 Dynamic programming

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

The Role of Risk Aversion and Intertemporal Substitution in Dynamic Consumption-Portfolio Choice with Recursive Utility

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle

The Life Cycle Model with Recursive Utility: Defined benefit vs defined contribution.

Asset Pricing in Production Economies

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

Equilibrium Asset Returns

2.1 Mean-variance Analysis: Single-period Model

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

Chapter 6 Money, Inflation and Economic Growth

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory II

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Topic 7: Asset Pricing and the Macroeconomy

Introduction: A Shortcut to "MM" (derivative) Asset Pricing**

Optimal investments under dynamic performance critria. Lecture IV

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Multiperiod Market Equilibrium

Slides 4. Matthieu Gomez Fall 2017

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

An Equilibrium Model of the Term Structure of Interest Rates

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers. Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel)

RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

The stochastic calculus

Introduction. The Model Setup F.O.Cs Firms Decision. Constant Money Growth. Impulse Response Functions

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Consumption and Asset Pricing

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES STRATEGIC ASSET ALLOCATION IN A CONTINUOUS-TIME VAR MODEL. John Y. Campbell George Chacko Jorge Rodriguez Luis M.

FINANCIAL OPTIMIZATION. Lecture 5: Dynamic Programming and a Visit to the Soft Side

Robust Portfolio Choice with External Habit Formation and Equilibrium Asset Prices

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2009

Basics of Asset Pricing. Ali Nejadmalayeri

The representative agent of an economy with external habit-formation and heterogeneous risk-aversion

Slides III - Complete Markets

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Influence of Real Interest Rate Volatilities on Long-term Asset Allocation

Homework 3: Asset Pricing

Consumption, Investment and the Fisher Separation Principle

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

Lifetime Portfolio Selection: A Simple Derivation

Catching Up with the Joneses: Heterogeneous Preferences and the Dynamics of Asset Prices

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

TAKE-HOME EXAM POINTS)

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Incorporating Managerial Cash-Flow Estimates and Risk Aversion to Value Real Options Projects. The Fields Institute for Mathematical Sciences

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

Disagreement, Speculation, and Aggregate Investment

Portfolio Selection with Randomly Time-Varying Moments: The Role of the Instantaneous Capital Market Line

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

Dynamic Portfolio Choice II

BACHELIER FINANCE SOCIETY. 4 th World Congress Tokyo, Investments and forward utilities. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Continuous Time Research and Development Investment and Innovation: Effects on Price and Dividend Paths *

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Continuous Time Bewley Models

The Equity Premium Puzzle, the consumption puzzle and the investment puzzle with Recursive Utility: Implications for optimal pensions.

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture 3 : The Ramsey Growth Model

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance

Lecture 4A The Decentralized Economy I

Asset Prices in General Equilibrium with Transactions Costs and Recursive Utility

Solutions to Problem Set 1

What Do International Asset Returns Imply About Consumption Risk-Sharing?

In the Name of God. Macroeconomics. Sharif University of Technology Problem Bank

Long Run Labor Income Risk

Prospect Theory and Asset Prices

Consumption and Savings (Continued)

Macroeconomics Sequence, Block I. Introduction to Consumption Asset Pricing

Dynamic asset allocation when bequests are luxury goods

Why Surplus Consumption in the Habit Model May be Less Pe. May be Less Persistent than You Think

Inflation & Welfare 1

Stock Price, Risk-free Rate and Learning

OPTIMIZATION PROBLEM OF FOREIGN RESERVES

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

Public Information and Effi cient Capital Investments: Implications for the Cost of Capital and Firm Values

Transcription:

Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Non-Time-Separable Utility: Habit Formation I. Introduction Thus far, we have considered time-separable lifetime utility specifications such as E t Z T t U[C(s), s] ds (1) where U[C(s), s] is often taken to be of the form U[C(s), s]=e ρ(s t) u[c(s)] (2) so that utility at date s depends only on consumption at date s and not consumption at previous or future dates. As discussed previously, there is evidence that this type of utility specification has difficulties matching the empirical characteristics of U.S. consumption and the returns on the stock market relative to a risk-free asset (the equity risk premium). The lack of empirical support has led researchers to explore different, non-time-separable specifications for lifetime utility. In these notes we consider utility functions in which past consumption plays a role in determining current utility. Such non-time-separate utility functions are said to display habit persistence. We summarize two models of this type that are based the articles of George Constantinides (1990) Habit Formation: A Resolution of the Equity Premium Puzzle, Journal of Political Economy 98, p.519-543 and of John Campbell and John Cochrane (1999) By Force of Habit: A Consumption-Based Explanation of Aggregate Stock Market Behavior, Journal of Political Economy 107, p.205-251. These models provide an interesting contrast in terms of their assumptions regarding the economy s aggregate supplies of assets and the techniques we use to solve them. The model in the Constantinides paper is a simple example of a Cox, 1

Ingersoll, and Ross Econometrica (1985) production economy where asset supplies are perfectly elastic. It is solved using a Bellman equation approach. In contrast, the Campbell - Cochrane paper assumes a Lucas Journal of Economic Theory (1978) endowment economy where asset supplies are perfectly inelastic. Its solution is based on the economy s stochastic discount factor. II. Assumptions of the Constantinides Model A.1. Technology: A single capital-consumption good can be invested in up to two different technologies. The first is a risk-free technology whose output, η 1 (t), followstheprocess dη 1 /η 1 = rdt. (3) The second is a risky technology whose output, η 2 (t), followstheprocess dη 2 /η 2 = µdt + σ dw. (4) Note that the specification of technologies fixes the expected rates of return and variances of the safe and risky investments. In this setting, individuals asset demands determine equilibrium quantities of the assets supplied rather than asset prices. Since r, µ, andσ are assumed to be constants, there is a constant investment opportunity set. A.2 Preferences: Representative agents maximize expected utility of consumption, c(t), of the form E 0 Z 0 e ρt γ 1 [c(t) x(t)] γ dt (5) where x(t) e at x 0 + b Z t 0 e a(t s) c(s) ds. (6) 2

Note that if x 0 = b =0, utility is time-separable with constant relative risk aversion parameter 1 γ. Forb 6= 0, thevariablex(t), which is an exponentially weighted average of past consumption, can be thought of as a subsistence level of consumption. Because current utility depends not only on current consumption but on past consumption, through x(t), itisnot time-separable, but exhibits habit persistence. An increase in consumption at date t decreases current marginal utility but increases the marginal utility of consumption at future dates. Of course, there are more general ways of modeling habit persistence, for example, u[c(t), z(t)] where z(t) is any function of past consumption levels. However, (5) and (6) is an analytically convenient specification. A.3 Additional Parametric Assumptions: 1 γ > 0 (7) W 0 > x 0 > 0 (8) r + a > b > 0 (9) ρ γr γ(µ r)2 2(1 γ)σ 2 > 0 (10) 0 m µ r (1 γ)σ 2 1 (11) where W 0 istheinitialwealthoftherepresentativeindividual. Thereasonsformakingthese parametric assumptions are the following. Condition (7) is required for utility to be concave. Note that c(t) needs to be greater than x(t) for the individual to avoid infinite marginal utility. 1 Conditions (8) and (9) ensure that an admissible (feasible) consumption and portfolio choice 1 Note that lim c(t) x(t) [c (t) x (t)] (1 γ) =. 3

strategy exists that enables c(t) >x(t). To see this, note that the dynamics for the individual s wealth is given by dw = {[(µ r)α(t)+r]w c(t)} dt + σα(t)w dw (12) where α(t), 0 α(t) 1 is the proportion of wealth that the individual invests in the risky technology. Now if α(t) =0for all t, that is, one invests only in the riskless technology, and consumption equals a fixedproportionofwealth,c(t) =()W(t), then dw = {rw ()W } dt = (b a) Wdt (13) which is a first order differential equation in W having initial condition W(0) = W 0.Itssolution is W (t) = W 0 e (b a)t > 0 (14) so that wealth always stays positive. This implies c(t) =() W 0 e (b a)t > 0 and c(t) x(t) = ()W 0 e (b a)t e at x 0 + b Z t 0 e a(t s) () W 0 e (b a)s ds Z t = () W 0 e (b a)t e at x 0 + b()w 0 e at 0 e bs ds h i = () W 0 e (b a)t e at x 0 +()W 0 e at (e bt 1) = e at [()W 0 x 0 ] (15) which is greater than zero by assumption (8). Condition (10) is a transversality condition. It ensures that if the individual follows an optimal policy (which will be derived below), the expected utility of consumption over an infinite horizon is finite. As will be seen, condition (11) ensures that the individual wishes to 4

put positive levels of wealth in both the safe and risky technologies, that is, the individual s optimal portfolio choice has an interior solution. m turns out to be the optimal choice of the risky asset portfolio weight for the time-separable constant relative risk aversion case. 2 III. Consumption and Portfolio Choice in the Constantinides Model The solution technique presented here is different from that found in Constantinides s Appendix A, which, he mentions, is based on a martingale approach presented in the working paper M. Davis and A. Norman (1987) Portfolio Selection with Transactions Costs, Imperial College, London. The current notes use a dynamic programming approach, similar to S. Sundaresan (1989) Intertemporally Dependent Preferences and the Volatility of Consumption and Wealth, Review of Financial Studies 2, p.73-89, which is based on R. Merton (1971) Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules in a Continuous-Time Model, Journal of Economic Theory 3, p.373-413. The individual s maximization problem is max {c, α} E t Z t e ρ s γ 1 [c(s) x(s)] γ ds e ρ t J(W(t), x(t)) (16) subject to the intertemporal budget constraint given by equation (12). Given the assumption of an infinite horizon, we can simplify the analysis by separating out the factor of the indirect utility function that depends on calendar time, t. The discounted indirect utility function depends on two state variables, wealth, W (t), and the state variable x(t), the current subsistence level of consumption. Since there are no changes in investment opportunities (µ, σ, andr are all constant), there are no other relevant state variables. Similar to wealth, x(t) is not completely exogenous but depends on past consumption. We can work out its dynamics using equation (6): dx/dt = ae at x 0 + bc(t) ab Z t 0 e a(t s) c(s) ds, or (17) 2 Also, see R. Merton (1971) Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules in a Continuous-Time Model, Journal of Economic Theory 3, p.373-413 or J. Ingersoll (1987) Theory of Financial Decision Making Rowman and Littlefield, Totowa, NJ, p.275. 5

dx = [bc(t) ax(t)]dt. (18) Thus, changes in x(t) are instantaneously deterministic. The Bellman equation is then 0 = max u(c(t), x(t), t)+l[e ρt J] ª {c, α} = max e ρt γ 1 (c x) γ + e ρt J W [((µ r)α + r)w c] {c, α} (19) + 1 2 e ρt J WW σ 2 α 2 W 2 + e ρt J x (bc ax) ρe ρt J }. The first order conditions with respect to c and α are: (c x) γ 1 = J W bj x, or (20) 1 c = x +[J W bj x ] γ 1, and (µ r)wj W + ασ 2 W 2 J WW = 0, or α = (µ r) σ 2 J W ( WJ WW ). (21) Note that the additional term bj x in (20) reflects the fact that an increase in current consumption has the negative effect of raising the level of subsistence consumption, which decreases future utility. The form of (21), which determines the portfolio weight of the risky asset, is more traditional. Substituting (20) and (21) back into (19), we obtain the equilibrium partial differential equation: 1 γ γ [J W bj x ] γ 1 γ J2 W J WW (µ r) 2 2σ 2 +(rw x)j W +(b a)xj x ρj = 0. (22) For the time-separable, constant relative risk aversion case (a = b = x =0), we showed in 6

earlier notes that a solution for J is of the form J(W )=kw γ, and since u = e ρ t c γ /γ, and u c = e ρ t J W, optimal consumption is proportional to wealth: c 1 = (γk) (γ 1) W = W ρ rγ 1 2 ( γ r)2 )(µ 1 γ σ 2 / (1 γ) (23) and α = m (24) where m is defined above in condition (11). These results for the time-separable case might suggest a functional form for the non-timeseparable case that looks like J(W, x) = k 0 [W + k 1 x] γ. (25) Making this guess, substituting it into (22), and setting the coefficients on x and W equal to zero, we find k 0 = ()hγ 1 (r + a)γ (26) where h γ(µ r)2 ρ γr (r + a)(1 γ) 2(1 γ)σ 2 > 0 (27) and k 1 1 =. (28) Using equations (20) and (21), this implies c = x(t)+h W(t) x(t) (29) 7

and α = m 1 x(t)/w(t). (30) Interestingly, since r + a > b, by assumption, the individual always demands less of the risky asset compared to the case of no habit persistence. Thus we would expect lower volatility of wealth over time. h i In order to find the dynamics of c, consider the change in the term W(t) x(t) r+a b. Recall that the dynamics of W (t) and x (t) are given in equations (12) and (18), respectively. Using these, one finds d W (t) x(t) = ½ ¾ [(µ r)α + r]w c bc ax dt + σα Wdw. (31) Substituting in for α and c from (29) and (30), one obtains d W (t) x(t) = W (t) x(t) [ ndt+ mσ dw] (32) where n r ρ 1 γ + (µ r)2 (2 γ) 2(1 γ) 2 σ 2. (33) Using this and (29), one can show (see Appendix A in Constantinides) dc c = n + b (n + a)x ³ dt + 1 x mσ dw. (34) c c Constantinides Theorem 2 specifies parametric conditions for which the ratio x c x has a stationary distribution. However, one sees from the stochastic term in (34), 1 x c mσ dw, that consumption growth is smoother than in the case of no habit persistence. This is the intuition for why habit persistence can imply very smooth consumption paths, even though risk aversion, γ, may not be of a very high magnitude. The lower demand for the risky asset, relative to the time-separable case, can result in a higher equilibrium excess return on the risky asset and, hence, help explain the puzzle of a large equity premium. 8

IV. Assumptions of the Campbell - Cochrane Model A.1 Technology: Campbell and Cochrane consider a discrete-time endowment economy. Date t aggregate consumption, which also equals aggregate output, is denoted, and it is assumed to follow an independent and identically distributed lognormal process ln (+1 ) ln ( )=g + ν t+1 (35) where v t+1 N 0, σ 2. A.2 Preferences: It is assumed that there is a representative agent who maximizes expected utility of the form E 0 " X t=0 # δ t ( X t ) 1 γ 1 1 γ (36) where γ > 0 and X t denotes the habit level. X t is related to past consumption in the following manner. Define the surplus consumption ratio, S t,as S t X t (37) Then the log of surplus consumption is assumed to follow the auto-regressive process 3 ln (S t+1 )=(1 φ)ln S + φ ln (S t )+λ (S t ) ν t+1 (38) 3 This process is locally equivalent to ln (X t)=φ ln (X t 1) +λ ln () or ln (X t)=λ P i=0 φi ln ( i). The reason for the more complicated form in (38) is that it ensures that consumption is always above habit since S>0. This precludes infinite marginal utility. 9

where λ (S t )= 1 S q 1 2 ln (S t ) ln S 1 (39) and r γ S = σ 1 φ (40) The lifetime utility function in (36) looks somewhat similar to (5) of the Constantinides model. However, while Constantinides assumes that an individual s habit level depends on his or her own level of past consumption, Campbell and Cochrane assume the an individual s habit level depends on everyone else s past consumption. Thus, in the Constantinides model, the individual s choice of consumption, c t,affects his future habit level, x s, for all s>t,and he takes this into account in terms of how it affects his expected utility when he chooses c t. This type of habit formation is referred to as internal habit. In contrast, in the Campbell and Cochrane model, the individual s choice of consumption,,doesnotaffect her future habit level, X s, for all s>t,sothatsheviewsx t as exogenous when choosing.thistypeofhabit formation is referred to as external habit or keeping up with the Joneses. 4 The external habit assumption simplifies the representative agent s decision making because habit becomes an exogenous state variable that depends on aggregate, not the individual s, consumption. V. Consumption, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing in the Campbell - Cochrane Model Because habit is exogenous to the individual, the individual s marginal utility of consumption is 4 A similar modeling was developed by A. Abel (1990) Asset Prices under Habit Formation and Catching Up with the Joneses, American Economic Review 80, p.38-42. 10

u c (,X t )=( X t ) γ = S γ t C γ t (41) and the representative agent s stochastic discount factor is m t,t+1 = δ u c (+1,X t+1 ) u c (,X t ) = δ µ St+1 γ µ γ Ct+1 (42) S t If we define r ft as the continuously-compounded risk-free real interest rate between dates t and t +1,thenitequals r ft = ln (E t [m t,t+1 ]) = ln (δ)+γg 1 γ (1 φ) (43) 2 which, by construction, turns out to be constant over time. One can also derive a relationship for the date t price of the market portfolio of all assets, denoted P t. Recall that since we have an endowment economy, aggregate consumption equals the economy s aggregate output, which equals the aggregate dividends paid by the market portfolio. Therefore, P t = E t [m t,t+1 (+1 + P t+1 )] (44) or, equivalently, one can solve for the price - dividend ratio for the market portfolio. µ P t +1 = E t m t,t+1 1+ P t+1 +1 " µst+1 γ µ 1 γ µ Ct+1 = δe t S t 1+ P t+1 +1 # (45) As in the Lucas model, this stochastic difference equation can be solved forward to obtain P t = δe t " µst+1 S t γ µ Ã 1 γ Ct+1 1+δ µ St+2 S t+1 γ µ Ct+2 +1 1 γ µ 1+ P!# t+2 (46) +2 11

= E t "δ = E t " X µ St+1 i=1 S t γ µ 1 γ µ γ µ 1 γ Ct+1 + δ 2 St+2 Ct+2 +...# δ i µ St+i S t γ µ # 1 γ Ct+1 S t The solutions can then be computed numerically by simulating the lognormal processes for and S t. In this model, note that the coefficient of relative risk aversion is given by η t = u cc u c = γ S t (47) which is time-varying and is relatively high when S t is relatively low, that is, when consumption is low (a recession). This allows the model to explain a high risk-premium on risky assets (the market portfolio). To see this, recall the relationship between the Sharpe ratio and the coefficient of relative risk aversion when consumption is lognormally distributed: E [r i ] r f σ ri η tσ c (48) Campbell and Cochrane show that the model can match the equity risk-premium because the average level of η t can be set fairly high. Moreover, the model predicts that the equity riskpremium increases during a recession (when η t is high), a phenomenon that seems to be present in the post-war U.S. stock market. 12