Policy Brief. Higher Inflation in China: Risks for Inflation and Output in Advanced Economies. Klaus-Jürgen Gern, Björn van Roye and Joachim Scheide

Similar documents
Kiel Policy Brief. Looking Forward: Exiting Unconventional Monetary Policy. Mewael Tesfaselassie. No. 13 October 2009

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

The international environment

Meeting with Analysts

Japan's Economy and Monetary Policy

II.2. Member State vulnerability to changes in the euro exchange rate ( 35 )

Global Economic and Market Outlook for Gavyn Davies, Chairman, Fulcrum Asset Management

The Icelandic Economy

The Outlook for the World Economy

The Economic Situation of the European Union and the Outlook for

Structural Changes in the Maltese Economy

Japan's Economy and Monetary Policy

Globalisation and monetary policy

MID-TERM REVIEW OF THE 2014 MONETARY POLICY STATEMENT

The main assumptions underlying the scenario are as follows (see the table):

: Monetary Economics and the European Union. Lecture 8. Instructor: Prof Robert Hill. The Costs and Benefits of Monetary Union II

Minutes of the Monetary Policy Committee meeting, August 2016

THE GLOBAL ECONOMIC OUTLOOK. Corinne Luu ECO/MPD 23 March 2017

Projections for the Portuguese Economy:

Yukitoshi Funo: Economic activity and prices in Japan, and monetary policy

Outlook for Economic Activity and Prices (July 2018)

The main assumptions underlying the scenario are as follows (see the table):

Summary of Opinions at the Monetary Policy Meeting 1,2 on March 14 and 15, 2019

Oil Shocks and the Zero Bound on Nominal Interest Rates

Koji Ishida: Japan s economy, price developments and monetary policy

Hamid Rashid, Ph.D. Chief Global Economic Monitoring Unit Development Policy Analysis Division UNDESA, New York

Cyclical Convergence and Divergence in the Euro Area

Haruhiko Kuroda: Japan s economy and monetary policy

Czech Monetary Policy and Economic Outlook

The macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in the Netherlands Íde Kearney, 13 th September 2018.

September 2017 ECB staff macroeconomic projections for the euro area 1

On Abenomics and the Japanese Economy. Motoshige Itoh Member, Council on Economic and Fiscal Policy and Professor, University of Tokyo

Meeting with Analysts

Consumption, Income and Wealth

The Global Economy Modest Improvement

The role of central banks and governments in the crisis

The Saturday Economist UK Economic Outlook Q1 2015

Minutes of the Monetary Policy Council decision-making meeting held on 2 September 2015

Investment and its Financing: A Macro Perspective

Macroeconomic projections for Assumptions from the external surrounding. Baseline macroeconomic scenario for

Spain Economic Outlook Q FIRST QUARTER. Economic Outlook. Spain. Economic Outlook. Spain

Discussion of The initial impact of the crisis on emerging market countries Linda L. Tesar University of Michigan

Summary of Opinions at the Monetary Policy Meeting 1,2 on December 19 and 20, 2018

UN: Global economy at great risk of falling into renewed recession Different policy approaches are needed to address continued jobs crisis

Challenges For the Future of Chinese Economic Growth. Jane Haltmaier* Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. August 2011.

Inflation projection of Narodowy Bank Polski based on the NECMOD model

Lars Heikensten: The Swedish economy and monetary policy

Trade Reform and Macroeconomic Policy in Vietnam. Rod Tyers and Lucy Rees Australian National University

Determination of manufacturing exports in the euro area countries using a supply-demand model

Developments in inflation and its determinants

OECD Interim Economic Projections Real GDP 1 Percentage change September 2015 Interim Projections. Outlook

ECONOMIC OUTLOOK. World Economy Autumn No. 33 (2017 Q3) KIEL INSTITUTE NO. 33 (2017 Q3)

Comments on Jeffrey Frankel, Commodity Prices and Monetary Policy by Lars Svensson

Mr. Bäckström explains why price stability ought to be a central bank s principle monetary policy objective

Economic Activity, Prices, and Monetary Policy in Japan

SPANISH EXTERNAL SECTOR AND COMPETITIVENESS: SOME HIGHLIGHTS

POST-CRISIS GLOBAL REBALANCING CONFERENCE ON GLOBALIZATION AND THE LAW OF THE SEA WASHINGTON DC, DEC 1-3, Barry Bosworth

CNB Monetary Policy on its Way Back to Normal

EFN REPORT. ECONOMIC OUTLOOK FOR THE EURO AREA IN 2019 and Winter 2018/19

EFN REPORT. ECONOMIC OUTLOOK FOR THE EURO AREA IN 2015 and 2016

Macroeconomic and financial market developments. March 2014

Eurozone Economic Watch Higher growth forecasts for January 2018

World Economic Trend, Spring 2006, No. 9

Economic Update February 2014

Temporary Slowdown of Economic Activity in Austria Expected to Be Overcome Fast, but Downside Risks Increased

Summary and Economic Outlook

Reforms in a Debt Overhang

Notes on the monetary transmission mechanism in the Czech economy

EFN REPORT. ECONOMIC OUTLOOK FOR THE EURO AREA IN 2018 and Winter 2017/18

Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description

Czech Koruna and the Economic Outlook

Exam Number. Section

Monthly Economic Report

Summary of Opinions at the Monetary Policy Meeting 1,2 on September 20 and 21, 2017

Oil Price Movements and the Global Economy: A Model-Based Assessment. Paolo Pesenti, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, NBER and CEPR

What is the global economic outlook?

OVERVIEW. The EU recovery is firming. Table 1: Overview - the winter 2014 forecast Real GDP. Unemployment rate. Inflation. Winter 2014 Winter 2014

December 2018 Eurosystem staff macroeconomic projections for the euro area 1

Monthly Report of Prospects for Japan's Economy

Some Considerations for U.S. Monetary Policy Normalization

March 2018 ECB staff macroeconomic projections for the euro area 1

Monetary Policy on the Way out of the Crisis

Quarterly Currency Outlook

Outlook for Economic Activity and Prices (October 2014)

Haruhiko Kuroda: How to overcome deflation

Working Paper 141. Eurozone debt crisis: Impact on the economy. June 28, 2010 ECONOMIC RESEARCH & CORPORATE DEVELOPMENT

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Session 9. The Interactions Between Cyclical and Long-term Dynamics: The Role of Inflation

* + p t. i t. = r t. + a(p t

MINUTES OF THE MONETARY POLICY COMMITTEE MEETING 4 AND 5 NOVEMBER 2009

An interim assessment

THE EURO AREA: ECONOMIC SITUATION, PROSPECTS AND CHALLENGES

BANK OF FINLAND ARTICLES ON THE ECONOMY

6-05 WORKING PAPER. The Macroeconomic Effects of an Oil Price Shock on the World Economy. Federal Planning Bureau. A Simulation with the NIME Model

Focus III. The reduced volatility of output growth in the euro area

Financial Crises and Emerging Market Economies Challenges and medium term persepctives

MCCI ECONOMIC OUTLOOK. Novembre 2017

The Effectiveness of Non-traditional Monetary Policy and the Inflation Target Policy : The Case of Japan in Comparison with the US

Structural changes in the Maltese economy

How Serious of a Threat Is Global Deflation?

Transcription:

Kiel Policy Brief Higher Inflation in China: Risks for Inflation and Output in Advanced Economies Klaus-Jürgen Gern, Björn van Roye and Joachim Scheide No. 36 October 2011 Institut für Weltwirtschaft Kiel Kiel Institute for the World Economy ISSN 2195 7525

Kiel Policy Brief 36 1 / 7 Higher Inflation in China: Risks for Inflation and Output in Advanced Economies After the burst of the dotcom bubble at the beginning of the past decade there were serious concerns that increasing globalization would contribute to deflationary pressures in advanced economies. In particular, the increasing integration of China into the world economy was thought to exert downward pressure on merchandise goods prices due to an almost fully elastic labor supply (e.g. Roach 2002, World Bank 2002). At the same time, import price deflation increased the room for advanced economies central banks to pursue expansionary monetary policies, as it was possible to accept higher domestic price inflation without acceleration of the general consumer price inflation. At the current juncture, by contrast, there are growing concerns that the period of imported price stability in the advanced economies has come to an end as inflation in China has started to accelerate. The inflationary environment in China has changed substantially in recent years. The rate of change in consumer prices began accelerating in 2007 and following a temporary decline in the wake of the global financial crisis surged again to 6.5 percent in July 2011, the highest rate in three years (Figure 1). As a matter of fact, part of this acceleration was due to strong increases in food prices, especially the price of pork, which at least to some extent will be temporary in nature. However, there are also some indications of an increase in core inflation that is rooted in supply constraints in the Chinese economy. Particularly, wage inflation has accelerated markedly in the second half of the last decade with the exception of the year of the great global recession 2009 (Figure 2). Figure 1: Inflation in China 2000 2011 Figure 2: Wage inflation and export prices in China 2000 2011 12 20 16 8 4 12 8 4 Wages 0-4 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 Monthly data; change over previous year. Source: National Bureau of Statistics of China. 0-4 -8-12 -16 Unit labour costs Export prices 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 Yearly data; change over previos year; wages: Average wages in manufacturing; Unit labour costs:own calculation derived from wages and productivity. Source: National Bureau of Statistics of China, CEIC. One reason for the higher wage growth in China is improved qualification of labor. This is the result of rising literacy, numeracy

Kiel Policy Brief 36 2 / 7 and educational attainment even of unskilled and semi-skilled employees and substantial increase in human capital embodied in skilled workers. The investment in human capital has helped labor productivity growth to remain strong. More recently a new employment contract law may have contributed to surging labor cost in manufacturing. The law protects rights of workers, improves working conditions, and requires payments to compulsory social insurance schemes. In combination with minimum wage legislation the new law appears to strengthen the bargaining power of employees, thus contributing to wage increases (Banister and Cook 2011: 45). A third factor behind rising compensation costs is the growing shortage of labor. Until recently Chinese manufacturers have been able to draw from a seemingly unlimited supply of labor. However, in the year 2003, reports of emerging shortages of manufacturing workers started to appear in the Pearl River Delta and subsequently spread to other parts of the country. The tightness in the labor market for manufacturing workers was temporarily eased by the global economic crisis which led to large numbers of lay-offs of migrant workers. This labor tightness easing, however, proved to be premature as the economy recovered quickly, and it proved to be difficult to get the necessary quantities of rural migrant workers to return to the manufacturing centers. Against this background, unit labor cost growth in the manufacturing industry accelerated to 8 percent in 2010 (ECB 2011), and export prices surged after the financial crisis. In addition, since June 2010 the People s Bank of China resumed its policy of letting the Renminbi gradually appreciate against the US-Dollar. As a consequence, in the advanced countries import prices for Chinese goods denominated in US-Dollars increased. Empirical work on the effects of globalization on consumer price inflation in the advanced economies so far has found little evidence of a significant impact (see Kamin et al. 2004 and Feyzioglu and Willard 2008). While Pain et al. (2006) find significant effects, they discriminate between two different effects which point into different directions: On the one hand, globalization dampens inflation due to lower import prices resulting from the exploitation of labor cost differentials, on the other hand strong growth in Table 1: Imports from China (% of GDP) Emerging Markets and Developing Country 2000 2005 2010 Economies leads to higher commodity OECD total 0.75 1.57 2.02 prices which result into higher import United States 0.84 1.61 2.07 Japan 0.98 2.33 2.34 prices in the advanced economies. The EU 27 0.63 1.27 2.35 Germany 0.75 1.59 3.30 deflationary effect was mostly found to France 0.61 1.17 1.85 be dominant. However, the effects of a Italy 0.49 0.89 2.00 UK 0.42 1.01 1.63 change in Chinese export prices may be OECD total 2010: partly estimated. more substantial today as the share of Source: OECD, Foreign Trade Statistics, Main Economic imports from China in GDP of advanced Indicators; United Nations Commodity Trade Statistics. economies has risen considerably over the past years (Table 1). The share has more than doubled since 2000 for the total

Kiel Policy Brief 36 3 / 7 OECD. The rise has been most pronounced for the European Union with the share of Chinese imports in GDP having almost quadrupled over the past decade. A model simulation In a simulation with the global econometric model NiGEM 1 we analyze the impact of a more limited potential output growth in China on consumer prices and output in the advanced economies. We impose lower Chinese trend output on the model by reducing the labor productivity growth rate by 1 percentage point permanently relative to the baseline. In China, lower production capacities lead to a significant increase in inflation and to a reduction in output relative to the baseline (Figure 3). The effects on output and inflation in the advanced economies depend on assumptions regarding exchange rates and monetary policy. In order to isolate the direct effects emerging from higher import prices, we assume the Euro/US-Dollar and the Yen/US-Dollar exchange rates to be exogenous in the sense that they do not move with the model dynamics. 2 With respect to monetary policy it is assumed that the ECB, the Federal Reserve and the Bank of Japan follow Taylor rules, i.e. they decide on the interest rate depending on current inflation and the output gap. 3 The Chinese central bank is assumed to follow US monetary policy (crawling peg) in order to prevent the exchange rate from strong appreciation. 4 Wages, long-run interest rates, equities and inflation are assumed to have forward looking components. 1 NiGEM is a large scale macroeconometric model that can be used for policy simulations and economic forecasts developed by the National Institute of Economic and Social Research (NIESR). All simulations are relative to a baseline scenario provided by NIESR. NiGEM is an estimated model, which uses a New-Keynesian framework in that agents are presumed to be forward-looking but nominal rigidities slow the process of adjustment to external events. Most countries in the OECD are modeled separately. The rest of the world is modeled through regional blocks: Latin America, Africa, East Asia, Developing Europe, OPEC and a Miscellaneous group mainly in West Asia. All models contain the determinants of domestic demand, export and import volumes, prices, current accounts and net assets, and the OECD countries are more complex than those of the non-oecd countries. See NIESR http://nimodel.niesr.ac.uk/logon/introduction.php?sw=0&ftyp=1&t=2&b=1. 2 A simulation with endogenous exchange rates yields qualitatively similar results. However, the magnitude of the effects changes, crucially depending on the assumptions regarding the agents expectations. The results for a scenario with endogenous exchange rates are available on request. 3 The Taylor rules also contain interest rate smoothing. The parameters differ between the countries and are set to estimated values by NiGEM. 4 This assumption is made for convenience and is not crucial for the argument. Chinese authorities could allow the exchange rate to appreciate stronger in order to contain domestic inflationary pressures. This would, however, have no (significant) effect on Chinese export prices in US-Dollar or output in China, and hence on advanced economies, as there would be no difference of Chinese appreciation in real terms.

Kiel Policy Brief 36 4 / 7 Figure 3: Impact of a reduction in trend labor productivity in China 2011 2021 China Japan age points 2,0 age points 0,6 GDP 1,5-0,5 0,5 0,4-1,0-2,5 1,0 0,3-1,5 Inflation (rhs) 0,5-2,0 0,2 0,1-5,0 2011 2016 2021-2,5 2011 2016 2021 United States Euro Area age points 0,6 age points 0,6 0,5 0,5-0,5 0,5 1,0 0,4-1,0 0,4 0,3 0,3 1,5 0,2-1,5 0,2 2,0 0,1-2,0 0,1 2,5 2011 2016 2021-2,5 2011 2016 2021 Yearly data; Simulationof one percentage point permanent shock to trend labour productivity in China per year. GDP: age deviation from baseline scenario; Inflation: Absolute deviation of the yearly inflation rate from baseline scenario. Source: NiGEM Database; own simulations using NiGEM. The shock to trend productivity in China leads to a progressive increase in Chinese inflation and Chinese export prices. At the end of the simulation period after ten years the inflation rate is about 1.5 percentage points higher than in the baseline scenario. Due to the reduction of production capacities, Chinese output is about 5 percent lower at the end of the simulation period. Since the Euro/US-Dollar exchange rate is exogenous, higher Chinese export prices immediately lead to higher import prices in the Euro Area, in the United States and in Japan. Accelerating import price inflation also results in stronger pressures on consumer prices in these countries. The effect is stronger in the Euro Area than in the United States, since the weight of Chinese products in the import price index is higher

Kiel Policy Brief 36 5 / 7 here. At the end of the simulation period, the Euro Area inflation rate is 0.6 percentage points higher; in the United States and Japan inflation rises by 0.55 and 0.5 percentage points, respectively. In response to higher consumer price inflation, the central banks raise their interest rates, depressing consumption and investment. However, central banks do not react as strongly as would be necessary to bring inflation back to its target, since they also consider the output loss. While the reduction of Chinese productivity is a permanent shock to the growth rate and the productivity level is therefore reduced each period, advanced economies central banks in the model do not anticipate the permanent nature of the change in Chinese productivity growth. As a result, they allow long run inflation to be slightly higher than the target. The negative effect on output is slightly higher in the United States and in Japan than in the Euro Area, because consumption and investment in the former countries are more sensitive to increases in the interest rate. In particular, real income and domestic demand is dampened stronger than in the Euro Area. As a consequence, the output loss in the United States and in Japan amounts to 1.6 percent in ten years relative to the baseline scenario, whereas output in the Euro Area is 1.2 percent lower. Short-term interest rates rise stronger in the Euro Area since the European Central Bank puts higher weight on inflation. In addition, the monetary stance of the Federal Reserve is less restrictive because of the stronger drop in output. Due to the large output effects on the Japanese economy the reaction of the Bank of Japan is also quite pronounced. At the end of the simulation period the Fed Funds Rate and the short-term interest rate in Japan are about 55 basis points higher, while the repo rate in the Euro Area is almost 65 basis points higher than in the baseline scenario. Altogether, the simulation exercise supports the presumption that structurally higher inflation in China will lead to higher interest rates in the advanced economies. With higher imported inflation, interest rates will have to rise stronger than otherwise as central banks will have to fight domestic inflation in order to reduce the overall consumer price inflation back to target. Consequently, with higher interest rates, also output will be substantially lower than in the baseline scenario. Conclusions The period of imported price stability in the advanced economies, resulting from low production costs in China due to an almost elastic labor supply may come to an end as inflation in China has started to accelerate. Higher inflation in China leads to upward pressures on consumer prices in the advanced countries. This result is supported by a simulation using the global econometric model NiGEM. Central banks face a trade-off between stabilizing inflation and supporting demand in order to reduce the output loss resulting from the fall in real incomes associated with higher inflation and lower exports

Kiel Policy Brief 36 6 / 7 to China due to reduced output growth there. With higher imported inflation, interest rates in advanced economies will be higher than otherwise as central banks will have to depress domestic inflation in order to reduce overall CPI inflation back to target. However, for the advanced economies, this should not be seen as the end of benefits from globalization since other Emerging Markets may reduce the inflationary pressures. In addition, a composition effect may leave the deflationary impact of trade with China intact as long as the absolute level of costs in China is low enough to give an incentive to substitute higher cost domestically produced goods with Chinese production. References Banister, J., and G. Cook (2011). China s Employment and Compensation Costs in Manufacturing through 2008. Monthly Labor Review (March): 39 52. Feyzioglu, N.T., and L.B. Willard (2008). Does China Have Inflationary Effects on the USA and Japan? China & World Economy 16 (1): 1 16. Kamin, S.B., M. Marazzi and J.W. Schindler (2004). Is China Exporting Deflation? International Finance Discussion Papers 791. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Pain, N., I. Coske and M. Sollie (2006). Globalisation and Inflation in the OECD Economies. OECD Economics Department Working Papers 524. Paris. Roach, S. (2002). The China Factor. Morgan Stanley Global Economic Forum. October 14. World Bank (2002). China is Becoming the World s Manufacturing Powerhouse. Transition Newsletter. October/November. Washington, D.C.

Kiel Policy Brief 36 7 / 7 Imprint Publisher: Editorial team: Kiel Institute for the World Economy Hindenburgufer 66 D 24105 Kiel Phone +49 (431) 8814 1 Fax +49 (431) 8814 500 Margitta Führmann Helga Huss Prof. Dr. Henning Klodt (responsible for content, pursuant to 6 MDStV) Dieter Stribny The Kiel Institute for the World Economy is a foundation under public law of the State of Schleswig-Holstein, having legal capacity. Sales tax identification number DE 811268087. President: Vice President: Prof. Dennis Snower, Ph.D. Prof. Dr. Rolf J. Langhammer Supervisory authority: Schleswig-Holstein Ministry of Science, Economic Affairs and Transport 2011 The Kiel Institute for the World Economy. All rights reserved.