Regional restriction, strategic commitment, and welfare

Similar documents
Volume 29, Issue 2. Equilibrium Location and Economic Welfare in Delivered Pricing Oligopoly

Relative Performance and Stability of Collusive Behavior

Welfare and Profit Comparison between Quantity and Price Competition in Stackelberg Mixed Duopolies

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Urban unemployment, privatization policy, and a differentiated mixed oligopoly

Quota bonuses in a principle-agent setting

The Timing of Endogenous Wage Setting under Bertrand Competition in a Unionized Mixed Duopoly

On supply function competition in a mixed oligopoly

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

CORVINUS ECONOMICS WORKING PAPERS. Quota bonuses as localized sales bonuses. by Barna Bakó, András Kálecz-Simon CEWP 1/2016

What Industry Should We Privatize?: Mixed Oligopoly and Externality

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly

PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION AND ENTRY TIMING IN A CONTINUOUS TIME SPATIAL COMPETITION MODEL

Price versus Quantity in a Mixed Duopoly under Uncertainty

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

Research Article Welfare Comparison of Leader-Follower Models in a Mixed Duopoly

Follower Payoffs in Symmetric Duopoly Games

DEMAND UNCERTAINTY, PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION, AND ENTRY TIMING UNDER SPATIAL COMPETITION

Maximin and minimax strategies in asymmetric duopoly: Cournot and Bertrand

Advertisement Competition in a Differentiated Mixed Duopoly: Bertrand vs. Cournot

The endogenous choice of delegation in a duopoly with input outsourcing to the rival

Efficiency, Privatization, and Political Participation

Demand-Enhancing Investment in Mixed Duopoly

Endogenous choice of decision variables

HORIZONTAL MERGERS, FIRM HETEROGENEITY, AND R&D INVESTMENTS

Research Article Extended Games Played by Managerial Firms with Asymmetric Costs

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

Endogenous Price Leadership and Technological Differences

Market Structure and Privatization Policy under International Competition

Technology transfer in a linear city with symmetric locations

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

Organizational Structure and the Choice of Price vs. Quantity in a Mixed Duopoly

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

Switching Costs and the foreign Firm s Entry

epub WU Institutional Repository

Export subsidies, countervailing duties, and welfare

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Patent Licensing in a Leadership Structure

Cournot-Bertrand competition in a unionized mixed duopoly

Ex-ante versus ex-post privatization policies with foreign penetration in free-entry mixed markets

Cournot-Bertrand Comparison in a Mixed Oligopoly

A NOTE ON MARKET COVERAGE IN VERTICAL DIFFERENTIATION MODELS WITH FIXED COSTS

Strategic Managerial Delegation in a Mixed. Duopoly with Capacity Choice: Partial. Delegation or Full Delegation

Price Leadership in a Homogeneous Product Market

Profit Share and Partner Choice in International Joint Ventures

Wage-Rise Contract and Entry Deterrence: Bertrand and Cournot

Mixed Motives of Simultaneous-move Games in a Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

CEREC, Facultés universitaires Saint Louis. Abstract

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model

Export performance requirements under international duopoly*

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Strategic export policy, monopoly carrier, and product differentiation

VERTICAL RELATIONS AND DOWNSTREAM MARKET POWER by. Ioannis Pinopoulos 1. May, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract

Chapter 7: Product Differentiation

To sell or not to sell : Patent licensing versus Selling by an outside innovator

Measuring the Benefits from Futures Markets: Conceptual Issues

How to Supply Safer Food: A Strategic Trade Policy Point of View

Price undertakings, VERs, and foreign direct investment. The case of foreign rivalry # Jota Ishikawa * and Kaz Miyagiwa **

Volume 29, Issue 1. Second-mover advantage under strategic subsidy policy in a third market model

Foreign direct investment and export under imperfectly competitive host-country input market

Solution Problem Set 2

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Mixed Duopoly with Price Competition

Export Taxes under Bertrand Duopoly. Abstract

IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND TRADE POLICY

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation

FDI Spillovers and Intellectual Property Rights

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser.

Outsourcing versus technology transfer: Hotelling meets Stackelberg

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Trade Liberalization and Labor Unions

A new model of mergers and innovation

The Effects of Specific Commodity Taxes on Output and Location of Free Entry Oligopoly

Outsourcing versus technology transfer: Hotelling meets Stackelberg

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Profitable Mergers. in Cournot and Stackelberg Markets:

Outsourcing under Incomplete Information

Switching Costs, Relationship Marketing and Dynamic Price Competition

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

Assets with possibly negative dividends

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

Games and Economic Behavior

Sam Bucovetsky und Andreas Haufler: Preferential tax regimes with asymmetric countries

Endogenous Product Differentiation and International Competition

research paper series

Analysis of a highly migratory fish stocks fishery: a game theoretic approach

A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition. Markus Reisinger & Monika Schnitzer University of Munich University of Munich

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2012

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

SF2972 GAME THEORY Infinite games

Export Subsidies and Oligopoly with Switching Costs

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies?

Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem

Optimal Trade Policies for Exporting Countries under the Stackelberg Type of Competition between Firms

Transcription:

Regional restriction, strategic commitment, and welfare Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo Noriaki Matsushima Institute of Social and Economic Research, Osaka University April 6, 2010 Abstract We investigate the effects of restricting locations of firms into Hotelling duopoly models. In the standard location-price models, the equilibrium distance between firms is too large from the viewpoint of consumer welfare. Thus, restricting locations of firms and reducing the distance between firms improve consumer welfare, through lower prices and smaller transportation costs for consumers. We introduce strategic reward contracts (strategic commitment) into the location-price models. We find that in contrast to the above existing result, restriction of the locations of firms reduces consumer welfare. Restricting locations of the firms reduces transportation costs but increases the prices through the change of strategic commitments by the firms, and it yields a counterintuitive result. JEL classification: R52, R32, L13 Key words: product selection, strategic commitment, delegation, Hotelling, locational restriction Corresponding author: Noriaki Matsushima, Institute of Social and Economic Research, Osaka University, Mihogaoka 6-1, Ibaraki, Osaka 567-0047, Japan. Phone: +81-6-6879-8571, Fax: +81-6-6878-2766, E-mail: nmatsush@iser.osaka-u.ac.jp 1

1 Introduction In this paper, we consider the effects of regional restrictions on consumer welfare. We use two standard location-price models on the Hotelling line one that restricts the locations of firms within the city (d Aspremont et al. (1979)) and the other does not impose any such restriction (Tabuchi and Thisse (1995) and Lambertini (1997)). The latter two papers show that the firms locate outside the city if they are allowed to do so. The outside locations yield higher equilibrium prices and larger transportation costs of consumers. Thus, it is obvious that restricting the locations of firms improves consumer welfare. In our paper, however, we show that this welfare property does not hold under a plausible strategic environment. We introduce strategic reward contracts that are quite popular in the literature on management science and industrial organization. We find that the symmetric equilibrium price in which the firms are not allowed to locate outside the city is higher than that in which the firms are allowed to locate outside if the firms can make strategic commitments through reward contracts. On the other hand, the restriction on the firms locations reduces the transportation costs of consumers. The higher price and the lower transportation costs represent a trade-off. In this setting, the negative effect dominates the positive one that is, restricting the locations of firms reduces consumer welfare when firms can make strategic commitments through reward contracts. Moreover, we show that the symmetric equilibrium price without strategic reward contracts is higher (smaller) than that with them when the firms are (not) allowed to locate outside the city. The matter discussed here is related to the following fact. In many countries, large stores often locate in suburban areas where the population densities are quite small. Regulations governing stores locations in suburban areas have been repeatedly discussed to realize a compact city that will yield reduction in the environmental damage arising from commute to and from stores, and will also help consumers who do not drive and/or own cars. For example, in Japan, the so called Three Laws of Community Building have been in force since 2000 and 2

were further strengthened in 2006; even then, there are discussions on further regulations with regard to the centralization of the store locations. 1 Given such discussions, it is important to discuss whether or not regional restrictions on suburban areas are beneficial. There are two closely related articles that discuss optimal zoning. Using a standard Hotelling model a la d Aspremont et al. (1979), Lai and Tsai (2004) show that restricting the locations of firms reduces both transport costs and prices, resulting in an improvement in consumer surplus as well as total social surplus. Chen and Lai (2008) discuss optimal zoning in a spatial Cournot model. There are at least two differences between these two papers and our paper. First, we consider the relation between the strategic commitments of firms and equilibrium outcomes whereas these two papers do not. Second, we mainly consider whether or not the firms should be allowed to locate outside the linear city whereas the above two papers discuss zoning policies within the city. Our setting is closely related to the problem of urban sprawl whereas the two papers are related to the problem of zoning within a city. We now briefly mention the importance of studying the case where ownership and management are separated. Traditional economic theories assume that the single aim of the firms is profit maximization. In large companies, however, ownership and management are separated, and managerial decision processes are rather complex. In his classical paper, Baumol (1958) mentioned that managers may be guided by objectives other than pure profit-maximization, and he suggested a sales-maximization model as a more realistic alternative. Later, economists noticed that the owners of firms have strategic incentives to link sales to managers rewards. Fershtman (1985), Vickers (1985), Fershtman and Judd (1987), and Sklivas (1987) made pathbreaking contributions in this regard. They considered the separation of owners and managers, and examined the following two-stage game: in the first stage, the owner makes the manager s 1 Before 2000, there existed a Law on the Locations of Large Stores, which restricted, rather than promoted, the placement of large stores in the city s central district. For the emergence of Big Box retail stores in the U.S., see Denning and Lary (2005), Haltiwanger et al. (in press), and the references therein. 3

contract and announces it publicly; in the second stage, after observing the contract, the manager maximizes the payoff given the reward contract. In these papers, the managers rewards are proportional to a linear combination of profits and outputs or sales. Since the model formulation of the abovementioned works is quite realistic and explains many of the actual behaviors of the firms, their model has become one of the most popular models in the fields of industrial organization and management science (Jansen et al., 2007). Subsequent works on this separation of ownership and management showed that the reward contract is crucially dependent on model formulation such as price or quantity competition (strategic complement or substitute). In the context of price competition, the managers rewards are usually decreasing in the firms sales; further, this also holds in the location-price model where the firms locations are restricted within the city. Our result suggests, however, that this does not hold in the location-price model where the firms are allowed to locate outside the city. As mentioned earlier, the managers rewards are increasing in the sales of the firms and this yields aggressive price competition and improves consumer welfare. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 formulates the model. Section 3 presents the equilibrium outcomes in the two models. We compare the outcomes and the results derived by the standard location models. Section 4 shows the main result. Section 5 discusses the applicability of the main result. Section 6 concludes the paper. 2 Model Consider a linear city along the unit interval [0, 1], where consumers are uniformly distributed along the interval. Firm i (i = 1, 2) is allowed to locate at x i [α, β] where α 0 and β 1. If α = 0 and β = 1, the model corresponds to that in d Aspremont et al. (1979), i.e., the firms are allowed to locate within the city. If α is sufficiently small and β is sufficiently large, the model corresponds to that in Tabuchi and Thisse (1995) and Lambertini (1997). Without loss of generality, we assume that x 1 x 2. 4

Each consumer buys exactly one unit of the good, which can be produced by either firm 1 or 2. Let p i denote the price of firm i (i = 1, 2). The utility of the consumer located at x is given by u x = { v t(x1 x) 2 p 1 if bought from firm 1, v t(x 2 x) 2 p 2 if bought from firm 2, (1) where v is a positive constant and sufficiently large, and t represents the exogenous parameter of the transport cost incurred by the consumer. For a consumer living at x(p 1, p 2, x 1, x 2 ), where v t(x 1 x(p 1, p 2, x 1, x 2 )) 2 p 1 = v t(x 2 x(p 1, p 2, x 1, x 2 )) 2 p 2, (2) the utility is the same regardless of the firm chosen. We can rewrite (2) as follows: x(p 1, p 2, x 1, x 2 ) = x 1 + x 2 2 + p 2 p 1 2t(x 2 x 1 ). Thus, the demand facing firm 1, D 1, and that facing firm 2, D 2, are given by D 1 (p 1, p 2, x 1, x 2 ) = min{max(x(p 1, p 2, x 1, x 2 ), 0), 1}, D 2 (p 1, p 2, x 1, x 2 ) = 1 D 1 (p 1, p 2, x 1, x 2 ). (3) We assume that the owners of both the firms hire a manager to delegate the price and the location decisions. The manager is offered a contract that is publicly observable. In this contract, the manager receives a fixed salary and a bonus related to the firm s profits and market share. In particular, if profits π i are positive, the manager of firm i receives a bonus that is proportional to the linear combination 2 U i = π i + λ i D i, where the weight λ i is a real number chosen by owner i in order to maximize his profits, and profits π i (the owner i s profits) are represented by π 1 = (p 1 c)d 1 (p 1, p 2, x 1, x 2 ), π 2 = (p 2 c)d 2 (p 1, p 2, x 1, x 2 ), 2 We use this contract form because of analytical simplicity. As in the other major strand in the literature, such as Fershtman and Judd (1987) and Sklivas (1987), we can use sales in the reward contract, that is U i = π i + λ ip id i. Under this setting, we derive similar results. 5

where c is the marginal cost of both the firms. Note that, in this model, D i is not only the quantity supplied by firm i but also the market share of firm i because the total demand is normalized to 1. Thus, we can say that the model setting in this paper follows that in Jansen et al. (2007). 2 Consumer surplus is given by CS = D1 0 1 (v p 1 t(x x 1 ) 2 )dx + (v p 2 t(x 2 x) 2 )dx. D 1 The game runs as follows. In the first stage, each owner seeks to maximize his profits by properly choosing the weight in the manager s contract λ i. In the second stage, manager i chooses its location x i, and in the third stage, manager i chooses its price p i [c, ). 3 Note that, we consider two cases concerning the location choices of the firms in the second stage: (i) the firms are not permitted to locate outside the line and (ii) the firms are permitted to locate outside the line. 3 3 Equilibrium In this section, we derive the equilibrium locations, the managers contracts, profits, and consumer surplus in the two models. One is the model wherein α = 0 and β = 1. The other is the model wherein α is sufficiently small and β is sufficiently large that the restriction α x i β is not binding. First, we investigate the price competition stage. Given the locations of the firms and the contract terms, (x 1, x 2, λ 1, and λ 2 ), the managers face Bertrand competition. The manner of competition is common between the two models. Let the superscript B denote the equilibrium 3 Now suppose that we add the following stage before the first stage: each owner determines whether or not it offers an incentive contract to its manager. In this case, both owner offer incentive contracts in equilibrium when the locations are not restricted. 6

outcome at the price-competition stage given x 1, x 2, λ 1, and λ 2. The equilibrium prices are Then, the managers rewards are given by 3.1 Locations are restricted p B 1 = 3c 2λ 1 λ 2 + t(2 + x 1 + x 2 )(x 2 x 1 ), 3 p B 2 = 3c 2λ 2 λ 1 + t(4 x 1 x 2 )(x 2 x 1 ). 3 U1 B = (λ 1 λ 2 + t(2 + x 1 + x 2 )(x 2 x 1 )) 2, 18t(x 2 x 1 ) U2 B = (λ 2 λ 1 + t(4 x 1 x 2 )(x 2 x 1 )) 2. 18t(x 2 x 1 ) As a benchmark, we consider the case in which the locations of the firms are restricted within the linear city, that is, α = 0 and β = 1. We consider the location choices by the managers. If the difference determined in the first stage ( λ 1 λ 2 ) is not so large, 4 the maximum differentiation appears in equilibrium, that is, x 1 = 1 x 2 = 0. Then the profits of the firms, the managers rewards, and the consumer surplus are given by π R i = (3t 2λ i λ j )(3t + λ i λ j ) 18t, U R i = (3t + λ i λ j ) 2 18t CS R = v 36tc 18t(λ i + λ j ) (λ i λ j ) 2 + 39t 2, (i = 1, 2, i j), 36t, p R i = 3(c + t) 2λ i λ j, 3 where the superscript R denotes the equilibrium outcome in the case where the locations are restricted. We now obtain the equilibrium value of λ i (i = 1, 2). independently chooses λ i so as to maximize its profit π i = π R i In the first stage, each owner i. The first-order condition is 3t + 4λ i λ j = 0, i = 1, 2, i j. (4) 18t 4 This difference is related to the discussion on the large cost difference in Matsumura and Matsushima (2009) and Meza and Tombak (2009). 7

From (4), we have the following lemma: Lemma 1 When the firms locations are restricted, each owner i chooses λ i at λ ER 1 = λ ER 2 = t. (5) The profits and the consumer surplus are as follows: x ER 1 = 0, x ER 2 = 1, p ER i = c + 2t, πi ER = t, CS ER = v If each owner is unable to set a negative value of λ i, the result is x ER 1 = 0, x ER 2 = 1, λ ER i = 0, p ER i = c + t, πi ER = t 2, CSER = v 12c + 25t, (i = 1, 2). (6) 12 12c + 13t, (i = 1, 2). (7) 12 In the standard location-price model in d Aspremont et al. (1979), the equilibrium outcome is as follows: Result 1 (d Aspremont et al., 1979): Suppose that each owner directly manages its own firm. When the firms are not allowed to locate outside the linear city, the equilibrium outcome is x 1 = 0, x 2 = 1, p 1 = p 2 = c + t, π 1 = π 2 = t 2 12c + 13t, CS = v. (8) 12 Henceforth, we refer to this case as the non-delegation case. From (6), (7), and (8), we have the following proposition: Proposition 1 Suppose that the firms are not allowed to locate outside the linear city. If each owner can set a negative value of λ i, the following three properties hold. The equilibrium prices in the delegation case are higher than those in the non-delegation case. The consumer surplus in the delegation case is smaller than that in the non-delegation case. The equilibrium profits in the delegation case are larger than those in the non-delegation case. If each owner is unable to set a negative value of λ i, the equilibrium outcomes in the delegation case and in the non-delegation case are the same. 8

We now mention the intuition behind the result. In the two cases, the firms fully maximize the degree of product differentiation within the Hotelling line. The incentive contracts λ i (i = 1, 2) only affect the price strategies. A higher value of λ i leads to a lower price p i because the manager i tends to put more stress on the sales volume. Because of the strategic complementarity, the competition between the firms is intensified. Anticipating this, each owner sets a lower λ i so as to mitigate the subsequent price competition. 3.2 Locations are not restricted We now consider the case in which the locations of the firms are not restricted. In other words, α is sufficiently small and β is sufficiently large that the constraint α x i β is not binding. The result in the third stage (price competition) has already been derived. We consider the location choices by the managers. The first-order conditions lead to x 1 = 4(λ 1 λ 2 ) 3t 12t, x 2 = 15t 4(λ 2 λ 1 ). 12t The resulting profits of the firms, the managers rewards, and the consumer surplus are given by πi U = (9t + 4(λ i λ j ))(9t 2(λ i + 2λ j )), 108t U U i = (9t + 4(λ i λ j )) 2 108t, p U i = 6c + 9t 2(λ i + 2λ j ), 6 CS U = v 432tc + 765t2 216(λ i + λ j )t + 16(λ i λ j ) 2, (i = 1, 2, i j), 432t where the superscript U denotes the equilibrium outcome in the case where the locations are unrestricted. We now obtain the equilibrium value of λ i (i = 1, 2). independently chooses λ i so as to maximize its profit π i = π U i In the first stage, each owner i. The first-order condition is 9t 8λ i 4λ j 54t = 0, i = 1, 2, i j. (9) From (9), we have the following lemma: 9

Lemma 2 When the firms locations are not restricted, each owner i chooses λ i at The profits and the consumer surplus are as follows: x EU 1 = 1 4, xeu 2 = 5 4, peu i = c + 3t 4, πeu i = 3t 8, CSEU = v λ EU 1 = λ EU 2 = 3t 4. (10) 48c + 49t, (i = 1, 2). (11) 48 In the standard location-price model in Tabuchi and Thisse (1995), the equilibrium outcome is as follows: Result 2 (Tabuchi and Thisse, 1995): Suppose that each owner directly manages its own firm. When the firms are allowed to locate outside the linear city, the equilibrium outcome is x 1 = 1 4, x 2 = 5 4, p 1 = p 2 = c + 3t 2, π 1 = π 2 = 3t 38c + 85t, CS = v. (12) 4 38 From (11) and (12), we have the following proposition: Proposition 2 Suppose that the firms are allowed to locate outside the linear city. The equilibrium prices in the delegation case are smaller than those in the non-delegation case. The consumer surplus in the delegation case is larger than that in the non-delegation case. The equilibrium profits in the delegation case are smaller than those in the non-delegation case. Proposition 2 is quite different from Proposition 1. When the firms are allowed to locate outside the linear city, price competition in the delegation case is tougher than that in the non-delegation case. We now mention the intuition behind this result. The incentive contracts λ i (i = 1, 2) affect not only the price strategies but also the location strategies. A higher value of λ i leads to a lower price p i because the manager i tends to put more stress on the sales volume. In the case where the firms are allowed to locate outside, a lower price p i caused by a higher value of λ i also affects the location choices of the firms. The rival firm j (j i) moves far away from the center to escape the tougher competition resulting from the higher value of λ i. As a result, the quantity supplied by firm i substantially increases. This demand-enhancing 10

effect dominates the competition-enhancing effect because of the strategic complementarity of the price strategies. Anticipating this, each owner sets a higher λ i ; this accelerate competition. 4 Main result We compare the equilibrium outcomes in the two models discussed above and mention welfare implications. Comparing (6) and (7) with (11), we have the following proposition. Proposition 3 Suppose that α is sufficiently small and β is sufficiently large that is, the firms are allowed to locate outside the linear city. In this case, the profits of the firms are lower than those in the case where the locations are restricted (α = 0, β = 1). The consumer surplus is higher than in the case where the locations are restricted (α = 0, β = 1). In our delegation case, the restriction on the locations of firms that reduces the distance between the firms mitigates competition and then reduces consumer welfare. At first glance, the relation between the location restriction and consumer welfare is counterintuitive. As explained in the previous section, no restriction on the locations accelerates the competition between the firms because of the demand-enhancing effect resulting from the high-powered incentive contracts. Note that, since this result holds with and without the non-negative constraint of λ i (i = 1, 2), Proposition 3 is highly robust. Proposition 3 is in sharp contrast to the relation between the results obtained in d Aspremont et al. (1979) and Tabuchi and Thisse (1995). These two papers show that the profits are higher when the locations are unrestricted. Moreover, they show that when the locations are unrestricted, the consumer surplus is lower. Proposition 3 indicates that incorporating the separation of ownership and management and the reward contracts of the managers into the models of d Aspremont et al. (1979) and Tabuchi and Thisse (1995) drastically changes the results. 11

5 R&D competition In the previous sections, we have incorporated strategic reward contracts into the Hotelling models. Some readers might suspect that the setting of strategic reward contract is artificial. However, similar results are obtained in the border class of strategic commitment games. In this section, we remove strategic reward contracts from the basic model and introduce strategic R&D competition instead. We believe that the discussion in this section shows a broad applicability of our result discussed in the previous sections. Each firm maximizes its own profit. The profit of firm i (i = 1, 2) is given by π i = (p i (c e i ))D i I(e i ), where e i denote the level of R&D activity of firm i and I(e i ) is the investment cost. The game runs as follows. In the first stage, firm i (i = 1, 2) engages in R&D and chooses e i. The marginal cost of firm i is c e i, and investment cost is I(e i ) = γe 2 i where γ is a positive constant. To secure interior solutions, we assume that γt 1/5. In the second stage, after observing R&D level of the rival, firm i chooses its location x i. In the third stage, after observing the location of the rival, firm i chooses its price p i [c e i, ). Again, we consider two cases concerning the location choices of the firms in the second stage: (i) the firms are not permitted to locate outside the line and (ii) the firms are permitted to locate outside the line. First, we investigate the price competition stage. The manner of competition is common between the two models. Given the locations of the firms and the ex post costs, the firms face Bertrand competition. Let the superscript B denote the equilibrium outcome at the price-competition stage given x 1, x 2, e 1, and e 2. The equilibrium prices are p B 1 = 3c 2e 1 e 2 + t(2 + x 1 + x 2 )(x 2 x 1 ), 3 p B 2 = 3c 2e 2 e 1 + t(4 x 1 x 2 )(x 2 x 1 ). 3 12

Then, the profits of the firms are given by π1 B = (e 1 e 2 + t(2 + x 1 + x 2 )(x 2 x 1 )) 2 18t(x 2 x 1 ) π2 B = (e 2 e 1 + t(4 x 1 x 2 )(x 2 x 1 )) 2 18t(x 2 x 1 ) I(e 1 ), I(e 2 ). Locations are restricted We consider the location choices. As in Section 3.1, if the difference determined in the first stage ( e 1 e 2 ) is not so large, the maximum differentiation appears in equilibrium, that is, x 1 = 1 x 2 = 0. Then the profits of the firms and the consumer surplus are given by π R i = (3t + e i e j ) 2 18t I(e i ), p R i = 3(c + t) 2e i e j, 3 CS R = v 36tc 18t(e i + e j ) (e i e j ) 2 + 39t 2, (i = 1, 2, i j), 36t where the superscript R denotes the equilibrium outcome in the case where the locations are restricted. We now obtain the equilibrium value of e i (i = 1, 2). In the first stage, each firm i independently chooses e i so as to maximize its profit π i = π R i. The first-order condition is 3t + e i e j 18tγe i 9t = 0, i = 1, 2, i j. (13) From (13), we have the following lemma: Lemma 3 When the firms locations are restricted, each firm i chooses e i at The profits and the consumer surplus are as follows: x ER 1 = 0, x ER 2 = 1, p ER i = c + t 1 6γ, πer e ER 1 = e ER 2 = 1 6γ. (14) i = 18tγ 1 36γ, CS ER = v c 13t 12 + 1 6γ. (15) 13

Locations are not restricted The result in the third stage (price competition) has already been derived. We consider the location choices by the firms. The first-order conditions lead to x 1 = 4(e 1 e 2 ) 3t 12t, x 2 = 15t 4(e 2 e 1 ). 12t The resulting profits of the firms and the consumer surplus are given by π U i = (9t + 4(e i e j )) 2 108t I(e i ), p U i = 6c + 9t 2(e i + 2e j ), 6 CS U = v 432tc + 765t2 216(e i + e j )t + 16(e i e j ) 2, (i = 1, 2, i j), 432t where the superscript U denotes the equilibrium outcome in the case where the locations are unrestricted. We now obtain the equilibrium value of e i (i = 1, 2). In the first stage, each firm i independently chooses e i so as to maximize its profit π U i. The first-order condition is 9t + 4e i 4e j 27γte i 27t = 0, i = 1, 2, i j. (16) From (16), we have the following lemma: Lemma 4 When the firms locations are not restricted, each firm i chooses e i at The profits and the consumer surplus are as follows: x EU 1 = 1 4, xeu 2 = 5 4, peu i = c + 3t 2 1 3γ, πeu e EU 1 = e EU 2 = 1 3γ. (17) i = 27tγ 4 36γ Comparing (14) with (17), we have the following proposition., CS EU = v c 85t 48 + 1 3γ. (18) Proposition 4 Suppose that α is sufficiently small and β is sufficiently large that is, the firms are allowed to locate outside the linear city. In this case, the equilibrium investment levels e i is larger than those in the case where the locations are restricted (α = 0, β = 1). 14

The login behind the proposition is similar to the basic model. The investments e i (i = 1, 2) affect not only the price strategies but also the location strategies when the locations are not restricted. The unrestricted location choices induce the firms to invest more. Comparing (15) with (18), we have the following proposition. Proposition 5 Suppose that α is sufficiently small and β is sufficiently large that is, the firms are allowed to locate outside the linear city. In this case, the profits of the firms are lower than those in the case where the locations are restricted (α = 0, β = 1) if and only if tγ < 1/3. The consumer surplus is higher than in the case where the locations are restricted (α = 0, β = 1) if and only if tγ < 8/33 0.2424. The prices are lower than those in the case where the locations are restricted (α = 0, β = 1) if and only if tγ < 1/3. The result on consumer surplus depends on the cost of R&D. When R&D cost γ is small, we obtain a similar result to the basic model (strategic reward contract model), i.e., regional restriction again raises the market prices and reduces consumer welfare. Without regional restriction, aggressive competition in R&D stage lowers the prices substantially and it improves consumer welfare. When R&D cost is large, this competition accelerating effect becomes weak. As a result, the loss of consumer welfare caused by a larger distance between the firms dominates the gain caused by the aggressive cost-reducing R&D. Thus, regional restriction can reduce consumer welfare. We emphasize, however, that regardless of R&D costs, regional restriction reduces the level of strategic commitments (R&D investments). The reduction, in itself, is harmful for consumer welfare. This is a general property among strategic commitment games. Remark If we consider quality-improving investments, we can again show that the equilibrium consumer surplus in which the locations are not restricted can be larger than that in which the locations are restricted unless the investment costs of the firms are too large. Consider the following model. The additional product quality for each firm is h i, and h i depends on its investment activities with cost I i (h i ) = γh i, where h i is endogenously determined by firm i 15

(i = 1, 2). In the context of quality-improving investment, this setting is applicable to the situation in which each firm engages in efforts for product variety expansion and it incurs the cost for store capacity (land) to put those products in the store. In this case, it is natural that the value of γ depends on the locations of firms. It is also natural that if a firm locates outside the linear city, the value of γ is smaller than that in which it locates inside the linear city. This is because land prices in the suburban area (outside) is lower than those in the urban area (inside). Under this setting, given that the firms are allowed to locate outside the linear city, consumer welfare would tend to be higher than in the case where the locations are restricted. 6 Concluding Remarks In this paper, we investigate the effects of the location restriction on consumer welfare. We use two standard location-price models on the Hotelling line one restricts the firms locations within the Hotelling line and the other does not impose any such restriction. We incorporate strategic reward contracts into the models. We find that the former model with the location restrictions yields smaller consumer welfare than the latter. This means that the restrictions on locations reduce consumer welfare. This result is quite different from the two results derived by the standard models (d Aspremont et al. (1979) and Tabuchi and Thisse (1995)). We think that our result provides a caveat to the recent debate on urban sprawl in the U.S. and Japan. Our paper also sheds light on the value of strategic commitment in Hotelling models. In the model without location restrictions, the firms have strong incentives for exhibiting aggressive behavior in the subsequent stages; in contrast, in the model with location restrictions, the firms have strong incentives for exhibiting less aggressive behavior. Thus, our result indicates that the strategic value of commitment crucially depends on the model formulation of the location choices. Our result depends on the assumption that the managers choose both the locations and 16

the prices. If the owners choose the locations and the managers choose the prices, our results do not hold. Here, less aggressive behavior is exhibited in both cases with and without the restriction of locations because the owners have already chosen the locations. However, no restrictions on the locations always reduces consumer surplus. 17

References Baumol, W., 1958. On the theory of oligopoly. Economica 25, 187 198. Chen, C.-S., Lai, F.-C., 2008. Location choice and optimal zoning under Cournot competition. Regional Science and Urban Economics 38, 119 126. d Aspremont, C., Gabszewicz, J.-J., Thisse, J.-F., 1979. On Hotelling s stability in competition. Econometrica 47, 1145 1150. Denning, B.P., Lary, R.M., 2005. Retail store size-capping ordinances and the dormant commerce clause doctrine. Urban Lawyer 37: 907 955. Fershtman, C., Judd, K. L., 1987. Equilibrium incentives in oligopoly. American Economic Review 77, 927 940. Haltiwanger, J., Jarmin, R., Krizan, C.J., in press. Mom-and-Pop meet big-box: complements or substitutes?, Journal of Urban Economics. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jue.2009.09.003 Hotelling, H., 1929. Stability in competition. Economic Journal 39, 41 57. Jansen, T., van Lier, A., van Witteloostuijn, A., 2007. A note on strategic delegation: The market share case. International Journal of Industrial Organization 25, 531 539. Lambertini, L., 1997. Unicity of the equilibrium in the unconstrained Hotelling model. Regional Science and Urban Economics 27, 785 798. Lai, F.-C., Tsai, J.-F., 2004. Duopoly location and optimal zoning in a small open city. Journal of Urban Economics 55, 614 626. Matsumura, T., Matsushima, N., 2009. Cost differentials and mixed strategy equilibria in a Hotelling model. Annals of Regional Science 43, 215 234. Meza, S., Tombak, M., 2009. Endogenous location leadership. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 27, 687 707. Sklivas, S.D., 1987. The strategic choice of managerial incentives. RAND Journal of Economics 18, 452 458. Tabuchi, T., Thisse, J.-F., 1995. Asymmetric equilibria in spatial competition. International Journal of Industrial Organization 13, 213 227. Vickers, J., 1985. Delegation and the theory of the firm. Economic Journal 95, 138 147. 18