Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator

Similar documents
The stochastic calculus

ESGs: Spoilt for choice or no alternatives?

Spectral Yield Curve Analysis. The IOU Model July 2008 Andrew D Smith

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Crashcourse Interest Rate Models

Interest Rate Curves Calibration with Monte-Carlo Simulatio

Market interest-rate models

1 The continuous time limit

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management

On modelling of electricity spot price

IMPA Commodities Course : Forward Price Models

Risk Neutral Valuation

Interest rate models and Solvency II

2.1 Mathematical Basis: Risk-Neutral Pricing

Fixed-Income Options

Alternative VaR Models

Conditional Density Method in the Computation of the Delta with Application to Power Market

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2009, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Gamma. The finite-difference formula for gamma is

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon

Empirical Distribution Testing of Economic Scenario Generators

Statistical Methods in Financial Risk Management

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

The Mathematics of Currency Hedging

The Black-Scholes Model

A new Loan Stock Financial Instrument

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2012, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

A new approach for scenario generation in risk management

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

The Black-Scholes Model

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS

Simulating Stochastic Differential Equations

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

FX Smile Modelling. 9 September September 9, 2008

Finance & Stochastic. Contents. Rossano Giandomenico. Independent Research Scientist, Chieti, Italy.

Calibration of Interest Rates

Monte Carlo Simulation of Stochastic Processes

Lecture 5: Review of interest rate models

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

(A note) on co-integration in commodity markets

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Interest rate models in continuous time

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes

Proxy Function Fitting: Some Implementation Topics

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29

The Black-Scholes Model

Brooks, Introductory Econometrics for Finance, 3rd Edition

3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency. Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors

Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2007, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Market Risk: FROM VALUE AT RISK TO STRESS TESTING. Agenda. Agenda (Cont.) Traditional Measures of Market Risk

Interest rate modelling: How important is arbitrage free evolution?

"Pricing Exotic Options using Strong Convergence Properties

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

MONTE CARLO EXTENSIONS

Extend the ideas of Kan and Zhou paper on Optimal Portfolio Construction under parameter uncertainty

Monte Carlo Methods in Financial Engineering

Credit Valuation Adjustment and Funding Valuation Adjustment

Credit Risk in Banking

Fast Convergence of Regress-later Series Estimators

Valuing the Probability. of Generating Negative Interest Rates. under the Vasicek One-Factor Model

θ(t ) = T f(0, T ) + σ2 T

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Practical application of Liquidity Premium to the valuation of insurance liabilities and determination of capital requirements

Valuation of Volatility Derivatives. Jim Gatheral Global Derivatives & Risk Management 2005 Paris May 24, 2005

Counterparty Risk Modeling for Credit Default Swaps

Economic Scenario Generators

AD in Monte Carlo for finance

Fast narrow bounds on the value of Asian options

2 Control variates. λe λti λe e λt i where R(t) = t Y 1 Y N(t) is the time from the last event to t. L t = e λr(t) e e λt(t) Exercises

Pricing with a Smile. Bruno Dupire. Bloomberg

Investment strategies and risk management for participating life insurance contracts

Fixed Income Modelling

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Analytical formulas for local volatility model with stochastic. Mohammed Miri

Characterization of the Optimum

Greek parameters of nonlinear Black-Scholes equation

UPDATED IAA EDUCATION SYLLABUS

Math 623 (IOE 623), Winter 2008: Final exam

Computational Finance Improving Monte Carlo

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

Accelerated Option Pricing Multiple Scenarios

Short-time-to-expiry expansion for a digital European put option under the CEV model. November 1, 2017

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2011, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam.

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Risk, Return, and Ross Recovery

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

INTEREST RATES AND FX MODELS

JDEP 384H: Numerical Methods in Business

Pricing Guarantee Option Contracts in a Monte Carlo Simulation Framework

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

Hedging Under Jump Diffusions with Transaction Costs. Peter Forsyth, Shannon Kennedy, Ken Vetzal University of Waterloo

European option pricing under parameter uncertainty

Transcription:

Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator Martin Schenk Actuarial & Insurance Solutions SAV 7 March 2014

Agenda Introduction Deterministic vs. stochastic approach Mathematical model Application of scenarios Calibration of input parameters 2

Introduction

Introduction There are a couple of purposes for which insurance companies use cash-flow models Solvency II MCEV LAT Planning (forecasts) etc. For each of these the cash-flow model needs to be fed with assumptions on future macroeconomic development. Deterministic models use one single (best-estimate) economic scenario which simulates the certainty equivalent (CEV) of future macroeconomic development. Stochastic models capture the future uncertainty (volatility) by using a set of scenarios which simulate the assumed range of future macroeconomic development. 4

Introduction The idea behind using the economic scenarios is assuming that the future economic situation (esp. asset yields or inflation) can be described by a mathematical model with a given distribution and the set of scenarios is a random sample of this distribution. Consequently, using a stochastic model and economic scenarios can help to answer e.g. the following crucial questions: what is the value of options and guarantees embedded in my insurance portfolio? what is the probability that my company will be running at a loss in 20 years? what is the confidence interval for a participant s fund value after 60 years? etc. 5

Introduction The idea behind using the economic scenarios is assuming that the future economic situation (esp. asset yields or inflation) can be described by a mathematical model with a given distribution and the set of scenarios is a random sample of this distribution. Consequently, using a stochastic model and economic scenarios can help to answer e.g. the following crucial questions: what is the value of options and guarantees embedded in my insurance portfolio? what is the probability that my company will be running at a loss in 20 years? what is the confidence interval for a participant s fund value after 60 years? etc. 5

Introduction The idea behind using the economic scenarios is assuming that the future economic situation (esp. asset yields or inflation) can be described by a mathematical model with a given distribution and the set of scenarios is a random sample of this distribution. Consequently, using a stochastic model and economic scenarios can help to answer e.g. the following crucial questions: what is the value of options and guarantees embedded in my insurance portfolio? what is the probability that my company will be running at a loss in 20 years? what is the confidence interval for a participant s fund value after 60 years? etc. 5

Introduction The idea behind using the economic scenarios is assuming that the future economic situation (esp. asset yields or inflation) can be described by a mathematical model with a given distribution and the set of scenarios is a random sample of this distribution. Consequently, using a stochastic model and economic scenarios can help to answer e.g. the following crucial questions: what is the value of options and guarantees embedded in my insurance portfolio? what is the probability that my company will be running at a loss in 20 years? what is the confidence interval for a participant s fund value after 60 years? etc. 5

Introduction The idea behind using the economic scenarios is assuming that the future economic situation (esp. asset yields or inflation) can be described by a mathematical model with a given distribution and the set of scenarios is a random sample of this distribution. Consequently, using a stochastic model and economic scenarios can help to answer e.g. the following crucial questions: what is the value of options and guarantees embedded in my insurance portfolio? what is the probability that my company will be running at a loss in 20 years? what is the confidence interval for a participant s fund value after 60 years? etc. 5

Deterministic vs. stochastic approach

Overview What are the general characteristics of an arbitrage-free 1 deterministic (CEV) economic scenario? all assets (bonds, equity) earn the same the time structure of the future yield curves is given by the initial yield curve (forward-spot relation) the discount rate is equal to the risk-free rate (1-yr forward) 1 No free lunch with vanishing risk 7

Overview What are the general characteristics of an arbitrage-free 1 deterministic (CEV) economic scenario? all assets (bonds, equity) earn the same the time structure of the future yield curves is given by the initial yield curve (forward-spot relation) the discount rate is equal to the risk-free rate (1-yr forward) 1 No free lunch with vanishing risk 7

Overview What are the general characteristics of an arbitrage-free 1 deterministic (CEV) economic scenario? all assets (bonds, equity) earn the same the time structure of the future yield curves is given by the initial yield curve (forward-spot relation) the discount rate is equal to the risk-free rate (1-yr forward) 1 No free lunch with vanishing risk 7

Overview What are the general characteristics of an arbitrage-free 1 deterministic (CEV) economic scenario? all assets (bonds, equity) earn the same the time structure of the future yield curves is given by the initial yield curve (forward-spot relation) the discount rate is equal to the risk-free rate (1-yr forward) 1 No free lunch with vanishing risk 7

Overview What are the general characteristics of an arbitrage-free deterministic (CEV) economic scenario? all assets (bonds, equity) earn the same the time structure of the future yield curves is given by the initial yield curve (forward-spot relation) the discount rate is equal to the risk-free rate (1-yr forward) Question: Which of these are valid also for stochastic scenarios? 8

Risk-neutral vs. real-world Intro Theory Model Application Calibration First, it is necessary to introduce a further split of the stochastic approach. Generally, there can be two types of stochastic scenarios: real-world risk-neutral The real-world scenarios are the "natural" ones. As you would expect, different assets have different volatility, and with higher volatility come higher yields (risk premium). Moreover, the real-world scenarios reflect the real probability distribution of economic variables. However, it is not that straightforward with risk-neutral scenarios. 9

Risk-neutral scenarios Intro Theory Model Application Calibration The "most common" definition of risk neutrality is that all assets are expected to earn the risk free rate (i.e there is no risk premium even for volatile assets). Equivalently, if we denote by Q(i, t) the value of a risky asset total return index in time t and by Q(0, t) we denote the risk-free total return index in time t, we get: [ ] Q(i, t) E = 1 i (1) Q(0, t) This has to hold for risk-neutral scenarios. However, does that mean that the expected value of a risky asset total return index is equal to the expected value of the cash total return index? In other words, does the following also have to hold? E [Q(i, t)] = E [Q(0, t)] i (2) 10

Risk-neutral scenarios Intro Theory Model Application Calibration The answer is: not necessarily. If the last equation would hold, it would imply that: ( ) Q(i, t) Cov Q(0, t), = 0 i (3) Q(0, t) However, as we could easily observe on the market, there is no reason why the return of a risky asset could not be correlated with the cash return. Therefore, we have to be extra careful how to define the risk-neutrality, what does the definition imply and what can we expect from risk-neutral scenarios defined in such a way. 11

Risk-neutral scenarios Intro Theory Model Application Calibration The answer is: not necessarily. If the last equation would hold, it would imply that: ( ) Q(i, t) Cov Q(0, t), = 0 i (3) Q(0, t) However, as we could easily observe on the market, there is no reason why the return of a risky asset could not be correlated with the cash return. Therefore, we have to be extra careful how to define the risk-neutrality, what does the definition imply and what can we expect from risk-neutral scenarios defined in such a way. 11

Risk-neutral scenarios Intro Theory Model Application Calibration The answer is: not necessarily. If the last equation would hold, it would imply that: ( ) Q(i, t) Cov Q(0, t), = 0 i (3) Q(0, t) However, as we could easily observe on the market, there is no reason why the return of a risky asset could not be correlated with the cash return. Therefore, we have to be extra careful how to define the risk-neutrality, what does the definition imply and what can we expect from risk-neutral scenarios defined in such a way. 11

Overview What are the general characteristics of an arbitrage-free deterministic (CEV) economic scenario? all assets (bonds, equity) earn the same the time structure of the future yield curves is given by the initial yield curve (forward-spot relation) the discount rate is equal to the risk-free rate (1-yr forward) Question: Which of these are valid also for stochastic scenarios? 12

Overview What are the general characteristics of an arbitrage-free deterministic (CEV) economic scenario? all assets (bonds, equity) earn the same the time structure of the future yield curves is given by the initial yield curve (forward-spot relation) the discount rate is equal to the risk-free rate (1-yr forward) Question: Which of these are valid also for stochastic scenarios? X 13

Overview What are the general characteristics of an arbitrage-free deterministic (CEV) economic scenario? all assets (bonds, equity) earn the same the time structure of the future yield curves is given by the initial yield curve (forward-spot relation) X the discount rate is equal to the risk-free rate (1-yr forward) Question: Which of these are valid also for stochastic scenarios? X 14

Overview What are the general characteristics of an arbitrage-free deterministic (CEV) economic scenario? all assets (bonds, equity) earn the same the time structure of the future yield curves is given by the initial yield curve (forward-spot relation) X the discount rate is equal to the risk-free rate (1-yr forward) Question: Which of these are valid also for stochastic scenarios? X X 15

Mathematical model

General There are a number of mathematical models which aim to describe the behaviour of various macroeconomic indicators such as interest rates, inflation etc. These models are usually based on an assumption that the behaviour of the selected indicators can be described by two components: a deterministic (non-random) function and a random noise (Wiener process) with zero mean. Such a model then describes the development of the selected indicator using a ordinary (stochastic) differential equation (stochastic ODE): dr t = β (t, r t ) dt + γ (t, r t ) dw t 17

Linear ODE s A special case of a stochastic ODE s are linear stochastic ODE s in which the functions β and γ are linear functions, i.e. in a form of β (t, r t ) = a t + b t r t γ (t, r t ) = c t + σ t r t Such ODE s are special in a sense that there exists an analytical solution to these equations, i.e. the resulting process r t can be explicitly calculated and does not need to be approached numerically. 18

One-factor models Intro Theory Model Application Calibration By selecting different coefficients a, b, c and σ one comes to various models which are often used, such as: Gaussian random walk dr t = αr t dt + σr t dw t Hull-White model of short-term interest rates dr t = (µ t αr t ) dt + σr t dw t Naturally, there exist more comprehensive models which, apart from the deterministic and random components, take into account a third component: a jump process (usually Poisson or compound Poisson process). This process causes random jumps in the modelled indicator and thus approaches the sudden drops/rises which can be observed in reality. 19

More advanced models Intro Theory Model Application Calibration Moreover, there also exist so-called multi-factor short-rate models which do not take into account jumps but assume more than one source of randomness instead. An example of such models can be e.g. Chen model of short term interest rates dr t = (µ t α t ) dt + σ t rt dw t dα t = (ρ t α t ) dt + σ t αt dw t dσ t = (ω t σ t ) dt + ϕ t σt dw t Both the models with jump processes and the multi-factor models have one common characteristic: a very difficult and comprehensive calibration of input parameters. You not only have to have a reliable and sufficiently "long" data, but you also have to make additional assumptions on e.g. correlations. 20

Selected model Intro Theory Model Application Calibration The ESG which will be described is built on the Hull-White short-term interest rate model. The pros and cons of using such model: Pros Cons Compared to more comprehensive models it is more intuitive; the resulting process can be derived analytically The calibration of input parameters is reasonably straightforward It is capable of modelling the term structure of interest rates It is a model which is widely used in industry, it has been widely scrutinised The assumptions (volatility, correlations) are fixed (i.e. not time-dependent) Less extreme behaviour than observed on the market (in the short-term perspective) 21

Model settings The general approach to the modelling of individual assets / indicators will be: the risk-free return index (denote Q(0, t)) will be modelled by the Hull-White model the "infinitely" long bond return index (denote Q(1, t)), equity return indices (denote Q(i, t), i = 2,..., n) and the real return index (denote Q(n + 1, t)) will be modelled by two components: the risk-free return index the risk premium above risk-free return, modelled by Gaussian random walk the ZCB price in time t with maturity period u (denote P(t, u), t u) will be modelled by combining the risk-free return index and the long bond return index 22

Model settings The previous description can be summarised by the following equation: ( Q(i, t) Q(i, 0) = Q(0, t) Q(0, 0) exp µ i 1 ) i 2 V ii t + Λ ij W(j, t) (4) where: µ i is an estimate of the risk premium of the given asset V ii is an estimate of the given asset s variance on top of the risk-free asset variance j=1 Λ = [Λ ij ] n+1 is the matrix of correlated volatilities i,j=1 W(j, t) is a n dimensional Wiener process Moreover, we can assume that Q(0, 0) = Q(i, 0) = 1. Remark: the long bond return is in fact the return of the "holding bonds with given duration" strategy. 23

Piece of math In order to derive the formulas for Q(0, t) and P(t, u), it is necessary to make the following vital assumption: dp(t, u) P(t, u) dq(0, t) = e α(u t) Q(0, t) + ( 1 e α(u t)) dq(1, t) Q(1, t) As a result, we can derive the formulas for Q(0, t) and P(t, u) (5) Q(0, t) = 1 P(0, t) exp { µ 1 (t 1 e αt where P(0, t) is the initial yield curve. α ) Λ 11 W(1, t) + V 11 X t ( t +V 11 2 1 )} e 2αt 4α 24

Piece of math In order to derive the formulas for Q(0, t) and P(t, u), it is necessary to make the following vital assumption: dp(t, u) P(t, u) dq(0, t) = e α(u t) Q(0, t) + ( 1 e α(u t)) dq(1, t) Q(1, t) As a result, we can derive the formulas for Q(0, t) and P(t, u) (5) Q(0, t) = 1 P(0, t) exp { µ 1 (t 1 e αt where P(0, t) is the initial yield curve. α ) Λ 11 W(1, t) + V 11 X t ( t +V 11 2 1 )} e 2αt 4α 24

Piece of math The derived formula for P(t, u), t u: P(t, u) = { P(0, u) ( P(0, t) exp Λ ) 11 1 e α(u t) (1 e αt )(1 e α(u t) ) X t + Λ 11 α ( V 11 1 (1 e 2αt )(1 e 2α(u t) )} ) 4α In both equations we used a process X t. By this we denote an Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process defined by: X t = t 0 e α(t s) dw(1, s) (6) 25

Piece of math Using the previously mentioned equation of the Hull-White model (with constant parameters): dr t = (µ αr t ) dt + σr t dw t and the Ito s lemma, we get r t = e αt r(0) + µ ( ) t 1 e αt + σe αt e αs dw s α where the last term corresponds with our Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process X t. 0 26

Deflators Generally, a deflator D(t) is a stochastic process which satisfies the following equation E [D(t)Q(i, t)] = 1 Naturally, there is a significant difference between deflators in case of risk-neutral and real-world scenarios. In our model, the deflator can be expressed in the following way: 1 D(t) = Q(0, t) exp n β j W(j, t) 1 n β 2 j 2 t j=1 where the parameters β i satisfy the following: µ i = i Λ ij β j j=1 i j=1 27

Deflators If we recall the fact that for the risk-neutral scenarios the risk premiums µ i are equal to 0, we obtain a simplified expression for risk-neutral scenarios. D(t) = 1 Q(0, t) Here it is useful to note that the risk-neutral deflator is an analogy to the discount rate in the deterministic approach (i.e. both are constructed from the risk-free rate). In case of real-world scenarios, one can easily see that the deflator can be split into two parts: "risk-neutral" part (represented by Q(0, t)) "compensation" part, combining the real-world probabilities and the risk-profile of Q(i, t) 28

Application of scenarios

Overview Generally, the use of scenarios was mentioned at the beginning of the presentation. However, now when we know more about the characteristics of risk-neutral and real-world scenarios, we can assess every situation from a better point of view. Calculation of TVFOG In case one needs to calculate the TVFOG embedded in an insurance (pension fund,...) portfolio, both risk-neutral and real-world scenarios can be used. However, there are a few points in favour of risk-neutral scenarios: simplicity: the risk-neutral scenarios are simpler, with more transparent deflators lean approach: in case you don t care about the future cash-flows distribution and need only present values, it is easier to generate and use risk-neutral scenarios convergence: the convergence for risk-neutral scenarios (esp. for deflators) is much faster than for real-world scenarios 30

Overview Projection of future development As already mentioned, there can be several purposes for which one needs to model the expected development of future cash flows, e.g.: estimation of a future event probability estimation of the confidence interval for a certain future value (fund, asset value,...) etc. For such projections, one needs the real probability distribution of economic variables. Hence, the real-world scenarios are the only correct option. 31

Calibration of input parameters

Initial yield curve Intro Theory Model Application Calibration As already mentioned, the model outputs (especially the shape of the yield curves and the equity return) significantly depend on the shape of the initial yield curve. The initial yield curve has to be interpolated/extrapolated from the individual term s yields available. There are a couple of methods how to do it, and when selecting one of them, one has to be aware of what is the desired outcome. I will briefly mention just two of the possible methods: Smith-Wilson method Nelson-Siegel-Svensson method 33

Smith-Wilson method Intro Theory Model Application Calibration One option how to interpolate/extrapolate the initial yield curve is the Smith-Wilson method. This method is based on defining a set of special polynomials and calculating a linear combination of these so that the resulting (spot) yield curve "hits" the actual yields for individual terms. Consequently, in case that the spot curve is not completely smooth, the implied forward curve may become "spiky". 34

Nelson-Siegel-Svensson method Another option how to interpolate/extrapolate the initial yield curve is the Nelson-Siegel-Svensson method. This method is based on defining a set of smooth functions and estimating their parameters so that the mean squared distance between the initial yields and the modelled yields is minimised. A big advantage of this method is that it produces smooth forward curve. 35

Input parameters Intro Theory Model Application Calibration Regarding the input parameters for the ESG, there are basically two possible approaches: derivation of market-implied parameters derivation of parameters from historical data Market-implied parameters these should be used if market values have to be replicated strongly depend on current market "mood" in some cases (e.g. inflation-linked bonds for deriving inflation parameters) may not be available Parameters derived from historical data built on the assumption that the history will repeat itself does not take into account any expected development history may not be available (e.g. for emerging markets) 36

Convergence As an example, the theoretical variance of the Q(i, t) index has the following form: Var[Q(i, t)] = E[Q(i, t)] 2 (exp ( ) 1 e 2αt {t(v ii Λ i1 Λ 11 + V 11 ) + V 11 2α ( ) } ) 1 e αt + (2Λ i1 Λ 11 V 11 ) 1 α Consequently, the number of simulations required for convergence to the theoretical mean value (on (1 α)% confidence level) can be expressed as: N = 1 ɛ 2 φ2 1 α Var(Q(i, t)) (7) 37

Convergence The following example demonstrates faster convergence of risk-neutral scenarios in case of deflated values of long bond return index and a couple of equity return indices. 38

Convergence Generally, the model is sensitive to input data. Therefore, convergence may become a real problem if the input parameters are unadvisable. So, how you determine the "admissible" parameters? In our particular model, the key indicator which determines the speed of convergence is the deflator, namely its "real-world part": n exp β j W(j, t) 1 n β 2 j 2 t j=1 However, what can be done when the parameters derived from hard data imply unfavourable risk parameters β i? There are basically two options: there do exist some variance reduction techniques, or one can consider adjusting the input parameters accordingto the Black-Litterman approach j=1 39

Convergence Generally, the model is sensitive to input data. Therefore, convergence may become a real problem if the input parameters are unadvisable. So, how you determine the "admissible" parameters? In our particular model, the key indicator which determines the speed of convergence is the deflator, namely its "real-world part": n exp β j W(j, t) 1 n β 2 j 2 t j=1 However, what can be done when the parameters derived from hard data imply unfavourable risk parameters β i? There are basically two options: there do exist some variance reduction techniques, or one can consider adjusting the input parameters accordingto the Black-Litterman approach j=1 39

Convergence Generally, the model is sensitive to input data. Therefore, convergence may become a real problem if the input parameters are unadvisable. So, how you determine the "admissible" parameters? In our particular model, the key indicator which determines the speed of convergence is the deflator, namely its "real-world part": n exp β j W(j, t) 1 n β 2 j 2 t j=1 However, what can be done when the parameters derived from hard data imply unfavourable risk parameters β i? There are basically two options: there do exist some variance reduction techniques, or one can consider adjusting the input parameters accordingto the Black-Litterman approach j=1 39

Convergence Regarding variance reduction, the idea is that either the random numbers behind the scenario generation or the resulting scenarios are "adjusted" a bit in order to speed up the convergence. antithetic variates - using "opposite" paths to reduce variance quasi Monte Carlo - using low-discrepancy sequences scaling of scenarios - adjusting the resulting scenarios for the price of distorted characteristics Alternatively, the Black-Litterman approach assumes that in an efficient market one might expect Sharpe ratios to be competed down. Consequently, risk premium is not required as an input and is calculated to satisfy some requirements on market equilibrium. All the described approaches can be used in specific cases and definitely are not to be used automatically. 40

Deloitte refers to one or more of Deloitte Touche Tohmatsu Limited, a UK private company limited by guarantee, and its network of member firms, each of which is a legally separate and independent entity. Please see www.deloitte.com/about for a detailed description of the legal structure of Deloitte Touche Tohmatsu Limited and its member firms. 2014 Deloitte Touche Tohmatsu. 41