An Estimate of the Effect of Currency Unions on Trade and Growth* First draft May 1; revised June 6, 2000

Similar documents
DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

AN ESTIMATE OF THE EFFECT OF COMMON CURRENCIES ON TRADE AND INCOME* Jeffrey Frankel and Andrew Rose

AN ESTIMATE OF THE EFFECT OF COMMON CURRENCIES ON TRADE AND INCOME* Jeffrey Frankel and Andrew Rose

What Should Academics Tell Policy-Makers. About Monetary Union? Discussion of Coleman and Wyplosz

Comments on Optimal Currency Areas. by Alesina, Barro, and Tenreyro. Andrew K. Rose. UC Berkeley and NBER

John F. Kennedy School of Government Harvard University Faculty Research Working Papers Series

3 Dollarization and Integration

Trade and Openness. Econ 2840

Dollarization. By ALBERTO ALESINA AND ROBERT J. BARRO* MA This research is supported by the National Science Foundation.

Gains from Trade 1-3

Trade versus Currency Agreements: Which Causes What to Economies?*

Chapter 4. Economic Growth

Estimating the Effect of Currency Unions on Trade and Output November 28, 2001

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael

The Effects of Common Currencies on Trade

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF CURRENCY UNIONS. Silvana Tenreyro Robert J. Barro. Working Paper

The Gravity Model of Trade

Chapter 10: International Trade and the Developing Countries

Ten Lessons Learned from the Korean Crisis Center for International Development, 11/19/99. Jeffrey A. Frankel, Harpel Professor, Harvard University

Deep Determinants. Sherif Khalifa. Sherif Khalifa () Deep Determinants 1 / 65

Online Appendices for

Appendix A Gravity Model Assessment of the Impact of WTO Accession on Russian Trade

What Firms Know. Mohammad Amin* World Bank. May 2008

On the Determinants of Exchange Rate Misalignments

MACROECONOMICS. Economic Growth II: Technology, Empirics, and Policy MANKIW. In this chapter, you will learn. Introduction

Do Domestic Chinese Firms Benefit from Foreign Direct Investment?

Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch. ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin

Economic Growth and Convergence across the OIC Countries 1

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom

REGULATION, INVESTMENT, AND GROWTH ACROSS COUNTRIES

Are we there yet? Adjustment paths in response to Tariff shocks: a CGE Analysis.

MA Advanced Macroeconomics 3. Examples of VAR Studies

The Time Cost of Documents to Trade

Comment on Rodríguez and Rodrick, Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic s Guide to the Cross-National Evidence

Impact of Fed s Credit Easing on the Value of U.S. Dollar

Working Paper No China s Structural Adjustment from the Income Distribution Perspective

Discussion of Beetsma et al. s The Confidence Channel of Fiscal Consolidation. Lutz Kilian University of Michigan CEPR

Gravity with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle

Summary of: Trade Liberalization, Profitability, and Financial Leverage

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

Macroeconomic Effects from Government Purchases and Taxes. Robert J. Barro and Charles J. Redlick Harvard University

This is a repository copy of Asymmetries in Bank of England Monetary Policy.

Do Closer Economic Ties Imply Convergence in Income - The Case of the U.S., Canada, and Mexico

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS THE UNIVERSITY OF NEW BRUNSWICK FREDERICTON, CANADA

The Impact of U.S. Trade Agreements on Growth in Output and Labor Productivity of FTA Partner Countries

GLOBAL BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS REVIEW Volume 5 Issue 2, 2003

The World Economy from a Distance

The End of State Income Convergence

Expansions (periods of. positive economic growth)

5+1 charts on how Hungary can catch up with France

MONEY SUPPLY ANNOUNCEMENTS AND STOCK PRICES: THE UK EVIDENCE

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

THE EFFECT OF CURRENCY UNIONS ON TRADE : TOWARDS BETTER ESTIMATION TECHNIQUES

Trade Openness and Inflation Episodes in the OECD

Bilateral Free Trade Agreements. How do Countries Choose Partners?

Economic Integration and the Co-movement of Stock Returns

SOME REFLECTIONS ON MACROECONOMIC POLICY: WHAT NEEDS TO BE DONE TO SUSTAIN GROWTH AND ACHIEVE A FULLY-EMPLOYED ECONOMY

Regional convergence in Spain:

VERIFYING OF BETA CONVERGENCE FOR SOUTH EAST COUNTRIES OF ASIA

Research on the Relationship between Sino-EU Trade and Economic Growth

Sovereign Debt and Economic Growth in the European Monetary Union

Exchange Rate Uncertainty and Optimal Participation in International Trade

Solow instead assumed a standard neo-classical production function with diminishing marginal product for both labor and capital.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CAN AN INCREASED BUDGET DEFICIT BE CONTRACTIONARY? Martin Feldstein. Working Paper No. l43)4

Lecture 20: Exchange Rate Regimes. Prof.J.Frankel

Interest groups and investment: A further test of the Olson hypothesis

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ARE GOVERNMENT SPENDING MULTIPLIERS GREATER DURING PERIODS OF SLACK? EVIDENCE FROM 20TH CENTURY HISTORICAL DATA

The Economic Impact of Right to Work Policy in West Virginia

EC201 Intermediate Macroeconomics Problem Set 1 Solution

10. Fiscal Policy and the Government Budget

Journal of Eastern Europe Research in Business & Economics

3. If the price of a British pound increases from $1.50 per pound to $1.80 per pound, we say that:

BETA CONVERGENCE IN THE EXPORT VOLUMES IN EU COUNTRIES

ECON 3312 Macroeconomics Exam 3 Spring 2016

Cross-Country Studies of Unemployment in Australia *

Suggested answers to Problem Set 5

Conditional Convergence: Evidence from the Solow Growth Model

Lectures 13 and 14: Fixed Exchange Rates

IS READY ROMANIA FOR EURO ADOPTION? FROM STRUCTURAL CONVERGENCE TO BUSINESS CYCLE SYNCHRONIZATION

Econ 102 Final Exam Name ID Section Number

THE EFFECT OF SOCIAL SECURITY ON PRIVATE SAVING: THE TIME SERIES EVIDENCE

Is Higher Volatility Associated with Lower Growth? Intranational Evidence from South Korea

Government expenditure and Economic Growth in MENA Region

Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for?

ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY. Term Test #2. December 13, 2017

Local Government Spending and Economic Growth in Guangdong: The Key Role of Financial Development. Chi-Chuan LEE

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities

Impact of Fdi on Macroeconomic Parameters of Growth and Development : A Post Liberalisation Analysis

The Short and Long-Run Implications of Budget Deficit on Economic Growth in Nigeria ( )

HONG KONG INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY RESEARCH

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong

INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS. Allison Heyse

Expectations Theory and the Economy CHAPTER

2. Aggregate Demand and Output in the Short Run: The Model of the Keynesian Cross

READING 20: DREAMING WITH BRICS: THE PATH TO

User Guide and Explanatory Note for the ESCAP Trade Analytics Portal

THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN MONEY AND EXPENDITURE IN 1982

Lecture 3: New Trade Theory

Social Security and Saving: A Comment

Transcription:

An Estimate of the Effect of Currency Unions on Trade and Growth* First draft May 1; revised June 6, 2000 Jeffrey A. Frankel Kennedy School of Government Harvard University, 79 JFK Street Cambridge MA 02138-5801 Fax: (617) 496-5747 E-mail: jeffrey_frankel@harvard.edu URL: http://ksgnotes1.harvard.edu/people/jeffrey_frankel Andrew K. Rose Haas School of Business Berkeley, CA 94720-1900 Fax: (510) 642-4700 E-mail: arose@haas.berkeley.edu URL: http://haas.berkeley.edu/~arose Summary: 8 ds pages Abstract Gravity-based cross-sectional evidence indicates that currency unions stimulate trade as much or more than do free trade areas. Thus currencies are a source of the home-country bias in trade. This paper extends such findings to estimate the ultimate benefits of currency unions, via trade, in terms of income per capita. We use a large data set of economic and geographic variables for over 200 countries and dependencies to quantify the implications of currency unions for trade and growth, pursuing a two-stage approach. Our estimates at the first stage suggest that a currency union more than triples trade with the partners in question. Our estimates at the second stage suggest that every one percent increase in trade (relative to GDP) raises income per capita by roughly 1/3 of a percent over a 20-year period. We combine the two estimates to derive a prediction for the effects of currency union on growth. Our results support the hypothesis that the beneficial effects of currency unions on economic performance come specifically through the promotion of trade or other interactions with major trading partners, rather than, as commonly thought, through a commitment to non-inflationary monetary policy, or other macroeconomic influences. JEL Classification Numbers: F11 F33 O40 * This paper was written for the Conference on Currency Unions, organized by Alberto Alesina and Robert Barro, Hoover Institution, Stanford University, May 19-20, 2000. Jeffrey A. Frankel is Harpel Professor and Director of the NBER program in International Finance and Macroeconomics. Andrew K. Rose is Rocca Professor, Research Associate of the NBER, and Research Fellow of the CEPR. The data sets and a current version of the paper are available at Rose s web site.

2 An Estimate of the Effect of Currency Unions on Trade and Growth: Summary Many countries are for the first time considering the possibility of abandoning independent currencies and adopting rigid institutional commitments, including currency boards (Argentina and Estonia), dollarization (El Salvador and Ecuador), or full currency union (the members of the European Monetary Union). Proponents tout such currency arrangements as the ultimate credible commitment to non-expansionary monetary policy. The idea is that when the central bank ties its hands so it could not in the future expand the money supply even if it wanted to, workers expect lower inflation. As a result, the country achieves lower inflation for any given level of output. Indeed, in the long run, the enhanced monetary stability promotes higher real economic growth. One study, for example, finds that currency boards raise long-term growth by as much as 1.8 per cent per year. We find that currency unions are indeed good for the performance of the economy in the long run, as indicated by a statistical association with economic growth. The channel, however, is via a substantial stimulus to trade among the members, rather than via macroeconomic influences. In theory, as well as according to statistical evidence, trade is good for growth, and this is as true of trade that is stimulated by currency unions as of other sources of trade. This paper investigates both stages: the influence of currency unions on trade and the influence of trade on growth. Currency unions go beyond reducing the variability of bilateral exchange rates. They eliminate altogether the risk of future changes in the exchange rate, as well as the transactions costs incurred from converting one currency into another. Thus they facilitate imports and exports. Past studies have not been able to find major effects over

3 time of exchange rate variability on trade. But by focusing on a cross-section of country pairs, we are able to find a large effect of currency unions. We estimate that when one country adopts the currency of another, trade between them eventually triples in magnitude. We arrive at this estimate by studying trade between pairs of countries. We use the gravity model, so-called because it says that trade between two countries is inversely related to the distance between them and proportionate to the product of their sizes, much as the gravitational attraction between two heavenly bodies is inversely related to the distance between them and proportionate to the product of their masses. The model has been very successful at predicting trade patterns. Measures of distance that are relevant for trade between a pair of countries include physical distance, measures related to adjacency and landlockedness, and linguistic differences. Each has strong negative effects on trade. Measures of country size that are relevant are GDP, population, and land area. They have positive effects on trade. After holding constant for all these important determinates, we can discern the independent effect on bilateral trade that comes when the two partners share a common currency. We also hold constant for past colonial history and ongoing political unions. Like the other gravity variables, these influences are significant statistically, but the independent effect of the currency union remains as well. Our data to study bilateral trade include 41,678 bilateral trade observations -- drawn from pairs among 186 countries, including in this definition of country dependencies, territories, overseas departments, colonies. The data set spans six

4 different years between 1970 and 1995. [Our growth equation uses a data set of annual observations for 210 countries.] The three-fold effect of currency unions on trade that we find sounds very large, and indeed it is. But it becomes plausible when one recalls findings that Canadian provinces are 12 to 20 times more inclined to trade with each other than with US states, after holding constant for distance and size. Something has to explain such findings of home country bias. The currency difference is as good a candidate as any other explanation. Our results show that among components of home bias, the currency union variable ranks in explanatory power roughly equal with the role of Free Trade Areas, behind the colonial relationship, and ahead of linguistic links and the residual political union variable. We checked whether the stimulus to trade between members of a currency union might come at the expense of trade with non-members. Such a diversion of trade away from non-members would imply less overall stimulus to total trade, and less likelihood of positive effects on real income. We found no evidence whatsoever of trade-diversion from currency unions. Indeed, we found that countries that belong to currency unions have higher overall openness, as measured by the ratio of trade to GDP, by 14 percent, as compared to countries that do not. [This estimate again holds constant for domestic size and income, along with overall remoteness from trading partners, and dummy variables such as landlockedness.] The foregoing estimate, however, does not yet take into account whether the country in question shares the currency of a large trading partner or a small one.

5 The next stage in our analysis is to investigate the effect of trade on growth. The proposition that trade has a positive effect on real income is almost as old as economic theory itself. It derives from the principle of comparative advantage. More recently, trade theorists have studied how an increase in trade might potentially have more than a one-time effect on the level of real income; it might raise the rate of economic growth on a long-term basis. Intensive economic interaction with the rest of the world speeds innovation and the adoption of new ideas, adding to technological and managerial knowhow and productivity. Many empirical studies have confirmed a statistical relationship across countries between openness and the level or growth rate of real income. This is true even after holding constant for such other important determinants of growth as investment in physical capital (plant and equipment), investment in human capital (schooling) and initial income (the convergence phenomenon, whereby countries that start further behind have the potential to catch up). Correlation does not necessarily imply causality, however. Trade may be correlated with growth because richer countries trade more, rather than the other way around. This is the problem of simultaneity: growth causes trade, while simultaneously trade causes growth. For example, countries tend to reduce tariffs as they become more developed. If a country engages in a lot of trade because it has low tariffs, the observed correlation with growth could be attributable to an effect of growth on tariffs and thereby on trade.. Our statistical method for getting around this problem isolates that variation in trade that is specifically attributable to the exogenous influences captured by the gravity model. The influence of trade on growth turns out to be as strong or stronger when this

6 technique is used, which we believe is free from the simultaneity problem. If a country engages in a lot of trade because it is located close to other large countries, the observed correlation with growth cannot be attributed to an effect of growth on location and trade. It must be because higher trade leads to growth. We seek to explain 1990 income per capita across countries. We begin by holding constant only for country size [as measured by population]. We estimate an apparent correlation whereby each increase in the trade/gdp ratio (which we are calling openness) of 1 percentage point is associated with an increase in per capita income of 0.7 percent. But the openness variable may in part be standing in for a host of other variables. So we hold constant for 1970 income per capita, investment, two measures of schooling, and population growth. Controlling for these influences brings the coefficient on trade down to 0.25, which says that, holding constant for 1970 income, income in 1990 was 1/4 per cent higher for every 1.0 percentage point increase in the trade/gdp ratio. The equation also implies a process of partial convergence of income levels over 20 years, estimated at a speed equal to one quarter of the total distance from the 1970 starting point to the long run equilibrium. It follows that in the truly long run, the effect of a currency union on income is four times as large as the 1990 effect. This estimate is still subject to the critique that it might reflect reverse causation, of income on trade. Our preferred way of addressing the simultaneity problem is to focus on a measure of trade that is built up from the bilateral predictions of the gravity model. When the trade coefficient is estimated with this technique, as already noted, it is at least as strong as when it is estimated without it. Every one percentage point increase in

7 openness is estimated to raise the level of income by an estimated 0.33 per cent, over the twenty year period. In the truly long run, the effect on income is again four times as large: 1.3 per cent for every one percentage point of trade/gdp. Finally, we combine our estimated effect of currency unions on trade with our estimated effect of trade on growth, to derive a combined prediction of the effect of currency unions on growth. Our predictions are based on the estimate that currency unions triple trade among the members. But the question of the ultimate effect should depend on who is adopting what currency. For example, our statistics imply generally that dollarization should raise an average country s income by roughly 4 per cent over 20 years. But the answer varies according to whether or not the country in question is a natural trading partner of the United States. El Salvador and Ecuador trade a lot with the United States, relative to their GDPs. The reasons are that they are small, the United States is large, and the distance is not great. As a consequence, our estimate is that dollarization should have a sufficiently large effect on the overall trade undertaken by El Salvador or Ecuador, that it could raise their incomes by as much as 20 percent over a 20-year period. But these countries trade much less with Europe, so that adopting the euro would have less effect on their overall trade and would thus be of less benefit to them. Conversely, Poland trades a lot with Western Europe, so that adopting the euro would raise income an estimated 20 per cent, while dollarizing would have much less benefit. (In each of these three examples, trade with the regional hegemon is about half of the country s total trade. This implies that tripling the trade with the hegemon doubles the country s total trade.)

8 It is possible that our results, which we attribute to the bilateral trade channel, are in part due to other economic interactions that run along geographic lines that are similar to trade -- investment, communication, migration. But we do offer evidence against the conventional belief that the long-term growth effects of currency unions come through macroeconomic influences. This follows from a demonstration of support for the hypothesis that the effects depend on the members being natural trading partners. We find no sign that simply belonging to a currency union in itself has any effect on a country s growth, beyond the effect achieved when the link is to major trading partners. Thus it seems that the growth benefits do not come through the central bank credibility route, but rather through the trade route. An implication for policy of the usual hypothesis, that the benefits come via monetary stability, would be that it does not much matter to what country one pegs one s currency, as long as it is to a country with a currency that is strong and stable in value. A conclusion from our analysis, however, is that geography belongs in the decision to whom one should link. Countries tend naturally to trade more with large neighbors; thus the benefits to adopting the currency of a large neighbor, other things equal, will exceed the benefits to adopting the currency of a country that is smaller or more distant. The analysis is subject to many qualifications. For one thing, our sample of currency union members tends to consist of small dependencies. We cannot be confident that the results generalize to large countries like the members of the European Monetary Union. [Indeed, the spirit of the paper is that countries that are too small to achieve economies of scale domestically are particularly dependent on the benefits of economic interaction through currency unions and trade.] For another thing, although we have held

9 constant for many influences, there may be others that we have not yet captured. Finally, we do not know if the beneficial effects of currency unions on trade come quickly or might appear only with very long lags.