Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation

Similar documents
Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels

Equilibrium Asset Returns

Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 2 Solutions

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Fixed-Income Options

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

An Equilibrium Model of the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Black-Scholes Option Pricing

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Mean-Variance Analysis

Basics of Derivative Pricing

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Martingale Approach to Pricing and Hedging

Financial Derivatives Section 5

The Black-Scholes Equation

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Derivatives Options on Bonds and Interest Rates. Professor André Farber Solvay Business School Université Libre de Bruxelles

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

The Black-Scholes Model

Option Pricing Models for European Options

The Black-Scholes Model

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Equilibrium Term Structure Models. c 2008 Prof. Yuh-Dauh Lyuu, National Taiwan University Page 854

25. Interest rates models. MA6622, Ernesto Mordecki, CityU, HK, References for this Lecture:

TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING

One-Factor Models { 1 Key features of one-factor (equilibrium) models: { All bond prices are a function of a single state variable, the short rate. {

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Lecture 18. More on option pricing. Lecture 18 1 / 21

The Black-Scholes Model

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

Black-Scholes-Merton Model

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

(1) Consider a European call option and a European put option on a nondividend-paying stock. You are given:

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Options

Lecture Notes 1

The Binomial Model. Chapter 3

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 1 Solutions

Stochastic Differential Equations in Finance and Monte Carlo Simulations

Path Dependent British Options

Extensions to the Black Scholes Model

Risk Neutral Pricing Black-Scholes Formula Lecture 19. Dr. Vasily Strela (Morgan Stanley and MIT)

The British Russian Option

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing

Interest-Sensitive Financial Instruments

Introduction to Financial Derivatives

Expected Utility and Risk Aversion

Derivative Securities Fall 2012 Final Exam Guidance Extended version includes full semester

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS

Towards a Theory of Volatility Trading. by Peter Carr. Morgan Stanley. and Dilip Madan. University of Maryland

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Extensions of the SABR Model for Equity Options

The Binomial Model. The analytical framework can be nicely illustrated with the binomial model.

Option Pricing. Simple Arbitrage Relations. Payoffs to Call and Put Options. Black-Scholes Model. Put-Call Parity. Implied Volatility

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

MFE/3F Questions Answer Key

Foreign Exchange Derivative Pricing with Stochastic Correlation

A note on the term structure of risk aversion in utility-based pricing systems

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle

Introduction to Financial Derivatives

Risk Neutral Modelling Exercises

Lecture 5: Review of interest rate models

Put-Call Parity. Put-Call Parity. P = S + V p V c. P = S + max{e S, 0} max{s E, 0} P = S + E S = E P = S S + E = E P = E. S + V p V c = (1/(1+r) t )E

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing

Credit Risk : Firm Value Model

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Thursday, September 12, 13

Continuous time; continuous variable stochastic process. We assume that stock prices follow Markov processes. That is, the future movements in a

Robust portfolio optimization

OPTIONS. Options: Definitions. Definitions (Cont) Price of Call at Maturity and Payoff. Payoff from Holding Stock and Riskfree Bond

Finance II. May 27, F (t, x)+αx f t x σ2 x 2 2 F F (T,x) = ln(x).

Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model. Chapter 13

θ(t ) = T f(0, T ) + σ2 T

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

European call option with inflation-linked strike

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 1 Solutions

Aspects of Financial Mathematics:

ECON Micro Foundations

PREPRINT 2007:3. Robust Portfolio Optimization CARL LINDBERG

Pricing Convertible Bonds under the First-Passage Credit Risk Model

Degree project. Pricing American and European options under the binomial tree model and its Black-Scholes limit model

FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS WITH ADVANCED TOPICS MTHE7013A

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

The stochastic calculus

Basics of Asset Pricing Theory {Derivatives pricing - Martingales and pricing kernels

Risk, Return, and Ross Recovery

Introduction to Energy Derivatives and Fundamentals of Modelling and Pricing

A new approach for scenario generation in risk management

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing

Outline One-step model Risk-neutral valuation Two-step model Delta u&d Girsanov s Theorem. Binomial Trees. Haipeng Xing

SOA Exam MFE Solutions: May 2007

Dynamic Principal Agent Models: A Continuous Time Approach Lecture II

non linear Payoffs Markus K. Brunnermeier

Transcription:

Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 1/ 36

Introduction Asset prices are modeled as following di usion processes, permitting the possibility of continuous trading. This environment can allow a market with an underlying asset, a contingent claim, and the risk-free asset to be dynamically complete. We illustrate the Black-Scholes-Merton portfolio hedging argument that results in a partial di erential equation for a contingent claim s price. Examples are The Black-Scholes (1973) option pricing model. The Vasicek (1977) equilibrium term structure model. The Merton (1973b) stochastic interest rate option pricing model. Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 2/ 36

Portfolio Dynamics in Continuous Time The insight of Black and Scholes (1973) and Merton (1973) is that when assets follow di usion processes, an option s payo can be replicated by continuous trading in its underlying asset and a risk-free asset. Consider an investor who can trade in any n di erent assets whose prices follow di usion processes. De ne S i (t) as the price per share of asset i at date t, where i = 1; :::; n. The instantaneous rate of return on the i th asset is ds i (t) = S i (t) = i dt + i dz i (1) with expected return and variance i and 2 i. Let F (t) be the net cash out ow per unit time from the portfolio at date t. Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 3/ 36

Portfolio Dynamics in Continuous Time cont d First consider the analogous discrete-time dynamics where each discrete period is of length h. Let w i (t) be the number of shares held by the investor in asset i from date t to t + h. The date t portfolio value is denoted as H (t) and equals the prior period s holdings at date t prices: nx H (t) = w i (t h)s i (t) (2) The net cash out ow over the period is F (t) h which must equal the net sales of assets: nx F (t) h = [w i (t) w i (t h)] S i (t) (3) Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 4/ 36

Portfolio Dynamics in Continuous Time cont d To derive the limits of equations (2) and (3) as of date t and as h! 0, convert backward di erences, such as w i (t) w i (t h), to forward di erences. Update one period: F (t + h) h = = nx [w i (t + h) w i (t)] S i (t + h) nx [w i (t + h) w i (t)] [S i (t + h) S i (t)] + nx [w i (t + h) w i (t)] S i (t) (4) and Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 5/ 36

Portfolio Dynamics in Continuous Time cont d H (t + h) = nx w i (t) S i (t + h) (5) Taking the limits of (4) and (5) as h! 0: F (t) dt = nx dw i (t) ds i (t) + nx dw i (t) S i (t) (6) and H (t) = nx w i (t) S i (t) (7) Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 6/ 36

Portfolio Dynamics in Continuous Time cont d Applying Itô s lemma to (7), the dynamics of the portfolio s value are dh (t) = nx w i (t) ds i (t) + nx dw i (t)s i (t) + Substituting (6) into (8), we obtain nx dw i (t) ds i (t) (8) dh (t) = nx w i (t) ds i (t) F (t) dt (9) Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 7/ 36

Portfolio Dynamics in Continuous Time cont d Thus, the value changes by capital gains income less net cash out ows. Substitute ds i (t) in (1) into (9), dh (t) = = nx w i (t) ds i (t) F (t) dt (10) nx w i (t) [ i S i dt + i S i dz i ] F (t) dt De ne the proportion of H (t) invested in asset i as! i (t) = w i (t)s i (t)=h (t), then (10) becomes Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 8/ 36

Portfolio Dynamics in Continuous Time cont d dh (t) = nx! i (t) H (t) [ i dt + i dz i ] F (t) dt (11) Collecting terms in dt, " nx # dh (t) =! i (t) H (t) i F (t) dt + nx! i (t) H (t) i dz i (12) Note from (7) that P n! i (t) = 1. Adding a riskfree asset that P pays r(t), so that its portfolio proportion is 1 n! i (t), we obtain Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 9/ 36

Portfolio Dynamics in Continuous Time cont d dh (t) = " nx #! i (t) ( i r) H (t) + rh (t) F (t) dt + nx! i (t) H (t) i dz i (13) which is a continuous-time formulation of wealth dynamics. Having derived the dynamics of an arbitrary portfolio, we now consider the Black-Scholes dynamic hedge portfolio that replicates contingent claims. Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 10/ 36

Black-Scholes Model Assumptions Let S(t) be the date t price per share of a stock that follows the di usion process ds = S dt + S dz (14) with time-varying but constant. Let r be the constant rate of return on a risk-free investment B(t): db = rbdt (15) Next, let there be an European call option written on the stock whose date t value is c(s; t). Its maturity value at date T is c(s(t ); T ) = max[ 0; S(T ) X ] (16) Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 11/ 36

Black-Scholes Model Assume that c (S; t) is twice-di erentiable in S and once- in t. Itô s lemma states that the option s value follows the process @c @c dc = S + @S @t + 1 @ 2 c 2 @S 2 2 S 2 dt + @c S dz (17) @S Consider a self- nancing (F (t) = 0 8t), zero net investment portfolio that is short one unit of the call option and hedged with the stock and risk-free asset. Zero net investment implies that the amount invested in the risk-free asset must be B (t) = c (t) w (t) S (t) where w(t) is the number of shares of stock. Thus, the hedge portfolio H(t) has instantaneous return dh (t) = dc(t)+w (t) ds (t)+[c (t) w (t) S (t)] rdt (18) Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 12/ 36

Black-Scholes Model Substituting (14) and (17) into (18), we obtain @c @c dh (t) = S + @S @t + 1 @ 2 c 2 @S 2 2 S 2 dt @c S dz @S +w (t) (S dt + S dz) + [c (t) w (t) S (t)] rdt (19) Set w (t) = @c=@s to hedge the return on the option. Then, @c @c dh (t) = S + @S @t + 1 @ 2 c 2 @S 2 2 S 2 @c dt S dz @S + @c @c (S dt + S dz) + c (t) @S @S S (t) rdt @c 1 = @t 2 2 S 2 @2 c @c + rc (t) rs (t) dt(20) @S 2 @S Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 13/ 36

Black-Scholes Model The portfolio is hedged, so dh(t) is riskfree and must equal r. It is also costless, so H(0) = 0 and dh (0) = rh (0) dt = r 0dt = 0 (21) so H (t) = 0 8t and dh (t) = 0 8t. This implies @c @t + 1 2 2 S 2 @2 c @S 2 + r S @c @S r c = 0 (22) This partial di erential equation has boundary condition c(s(t ); T ) = max[ 0; S(T ) X ] (23) Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 14/ 36

Black-Scholes Formula (1973) The solution to (22) subject to (23) is where c(s(t); t) = S(t) N(d 1 ) X e r (T t) N(d 2 ) (24) d 1 = ln (S(t)=X ) + r + 1 2 2 (T t) p T t d 2 = d 1 p T t (25) and N() is the standard normal distribution function. Similar to the binomial model, (24) does not depend on, but only on S(t) and. Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 15/ 36

Black-Scholes Formula (1973) cont d From put-call parity, the value of a European put is p(s(t); t) = c(s(t); t) + X e r (T t) S(t) (26) = X e r (T t) N( d 2 ) S(t)N( d 1 ) Taking the partial derivatives of (24) and (26) gives the hedge ratios @c @S = N (d 1) (27) @p @S = N ( d 1) (28) which implies 0 < @c=@s < 1 and 1 < @p=@s < 0. Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 16/ 36

Vasicek (1977) Model When the prices of default-free bonds depend on continuous-time stochastic processes, continuous trading and the no-arbitrage condition place restrictions on their prices. We now consider the Vasicek (1977) one-factor term structure model where uncertainty is determined by the yield on the shortest-maturity bond, r(t). De ne P (t; ) as the date t price of a bond that makes a single payment of $1 at date T = t +. The rate of return on the bond is dp(t;) P(t;) and P(t; 0) = $1. The instantaneous-maturity yield, r (t), is de ned as dp (t; ) lim r (t) dt (29)!0 P (t; ) Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 17/ 36

Process for r(t) r (t) is assumed to follow the Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process: dr(t) = [r r (t)] dt + r dz r (30) where, r, and r are positive constants. For r (0) = r = 0:05, = 0:3, and r = 0:02, a typical path is Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 18/ 36

Price Process Assume that bond prices of all maturities depend on only a single source of uncertainty r (t); P(r(t); (t)) where T t. Using Itô s lemma, dp (r; ) = @P @P dr + @r @t dt + 1 @ 2 P 2 @r 2 (dr)2 (31) = P r (r r) + P t + 1 2 P rr 2 r dt + Pr r dz r = p (r; ) P (r; ) dt p () P (r; ) dz r where subscripts on P denote partial derivatives and h P r (r r )+P t + 1 2 Prr 2 r i Pr r p (r; ) P(r ;) and p () P(r ;). Now make a portfolio containing one bond of maturity 1 and p( 1 )P(r ; 1 ) p( 2 )P(r ; 2 ) units of a bond with maturity 2. Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 19/ 36

Hedge Portfolio Since both bond values depend on dz r, the portfolio is hedged if we continually readjust the amount of the 2 -maturity bond to equal p( 1 )P(r ; 1 ) p( 2 )P(r ; 2 ) as r (t) changes. The value of this hedge portfolio, H (t), is H (t) = P (r; 1 ) = P (r; 1 ) p ( 1 ) P (r; 1 ) p ( 2 ) P (r; 2 ) P (r; 2) (32) p ( 1 ) 1 p ( 2 ) and the hedge portfolio s instantaneous return is dh (t) = dp (r; 1 ) p ( 1 ) P (r; 1 ) p ( 2 ) P (r; 2 ) dp (r; 2) (33) Substituting for dp(r; i ) i = 1; 2 from (31): Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 20/ 36

Hedge Portfolio cont d dh (t) = p (r; 1 ) P (r; 1 ) dt p ( 1 ) P (r; 1 ) dz r p ( 1 ) p ( 2 ) P (r; 1) p (r; 2 ) dt + p ( 1 ) P (r; 1 ) dz r = p (r; 1 ) P (r; 1 ) dt p ( 1 ) p ( 2 ) P (r; 1) p (r; 2 ) dt Since the portfolio return is riskless, its rate of return must equal the instantaneous riskless interest rate, r (t): p ( 1 ) dh (t) = p (r; 1 ) p ( 2 ) p (r; 2 ) P (r; 1 ) dt (34) p ( 1 ) = r (t) H (t) dt = r (t) 1 P (r; 1 ) dt p ( 2 ) Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 21/ 36

Bond Risk Premium The second line is from our de nition of H(t) in (32). Equating the two, we get the equality of bond Sharpe ratios: p (r; 1 ) p ( 1 ) r (t) = p (r; 2 ) r (t) p ( 2 ) (35) Condition (35) requires all bonds to have a uniform market price of interest rate risk, as all risk is represented by dz r. Cox, Ingersoll and Ross (1985a,b) derive this price of risk from general equilibrium, but for now we simply assume it is a constant q: p (r; ) r (t) = q (36) p () or p (r; ) = r (t) + q p () (37) Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 22/ 36

Bond Risk Premium cont d Substituting p (r; ) and p () from (33) into (37): P r (r r) + P t + 1 2 P rr 2 r = rp q r P r (38) which can be rewritten as 2 r 2 P rr + (r + q r r) P r rp + P t = 0 (39) Since d = dt, so that P t @P (39) can be rewritten as @t = @P @ P, equation 2 r 2 P rr + [ (r r) + q r ] P r rp P = 0 (40) subject to the boundary condition that at = 0, P (r; 0) = 1. Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 23/ 36

Bond Risk Premium cont d Equation (40) has a solution of the form P (r (t) ; ) = A () e B()r (t) (41) Substituting back into (40) gives ordinary di erential equations for A and B with boundary conditions A ( = 0) = 1 and B ( = 0) = 0 and solutions: B () 1 e A () exp " (B () ) r + q r (42) 1 2 # r 2 r B () 2 2 2 4 (43) Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 24/ 36

Characteristics of Bond Prices Using equation (41) in our de nition of p, we see that p () r P r P = r B () = r 1 e (44) which is an increasing and concave function of. Equation (37), p (r; ) = r (t) + q p (), implies that a bond s expected rate of return increases (decreases) with its time until maturity if the market price of risk, q, is positive (negative). Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 25/ 36

Characteristics of Bond Prices cont d A bond s continuously compounded yield, Y (r (t) ; ), equals Y (r (t) ; ) = = where Y 1 r + q r 1 ln [P (r (t) ; )] 1 B () ln [A ()] + r (t) (45) = Y 1 + [r (t) Y 1 ] B () 1 2 r 2. 2 + 2 r B () 2 4 Note that lim!1 Y (r (t) ; ) = Y 1. Hence, the yield curve, which is the graph of Y (r (t) ; ) as a function of, equals r (t) at = 0 and asymptotes to Y 1 for large. Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 26/ 36

Bond Yield Slopes When r (t) Y 1 = r + q r 4 2 monotonically increasing. 2 r When Y 1 < r (t) < Y 4 2 1 + 2 r curve has a humped shape. 2 r 2 2 3 2 r 4 2, the yield curve is = r + q r, the yield A monotonically downward sloping, or inverted, yield curve occurs when r + q r r (t). Since the yield curve is normally upward sloping, this suggests that r < r + q r 3 2 r, or q > 3r 4 2 4, i.e., a positive market price of bond risk. Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 27/ 36

Option Pricing with Random Interest Rates We now value contingent claims ( rst example) assuming stochastic interest rates (second example) to derive the Merton (1973b) option pricing model (third example). De ne the price of a risk-free bond that pays $X at as P (t; ) X, so the option s value is c (S (t) ; P (t; ) ; t). From Vasicek (1977), this bond s process is dp (t; ) = p (t; ) P (t; ) dt + p () P (t; ) dz p (46) where from equation (31) de ne dz p dz r and assume a bond-stock correlation of dz p dz = dt. Applying Itô s lemma: @c @c dc = S + @S @P pp + @c @t + 1 @ 2 c 2 @S 2 2 S 2 + 1 @ 2 c 2 @P 2 2 pp 2 + @2 c @S@P psp dt + @c @c S dz + @S @P pp dz p (47) Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 28/ 36

Option Pricing with Random Interest Rates cont d = c cdt + @c @c S dz + @S @P pp dz p where c c is de ned as the bracketed terms in (47). Our hedge portfolio is a unit short position in the option, a purchase of w s (t) units of the underlying stock, and a purchase of w p (t) units of the -maturity bond. A zero-net-investment restriction implies c (t) w s (t) S (t) w p (t) P (t; ) = 0 (48) The hedge portfolio s return can then be written as dh (t) = dc(t) + w s (t) ds (t) + w p (t) dp (t; ) (49) Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 29/ 36

Hedge Portfolio with Random Interest Rates = c c + w s (t) S + w p (t) p P dt @c + @S S + w s (t) S dz @c + @P pp + w p (t) p P dz p = w s (t) ( c ) S + w p (t) p c P dt @c + w s (t) Sdz @S + w p (t) @c @P p P dz p Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 30/ 36

Hedge Portfolio with Random Interest Rates cont d If w s (t) and w p (t) are chosen to make the portfolio s return riskless, then from (49) they must equal: w s (t) = @c @S (50) w p (t) = @c (51) @P But from the zero-net-investment condition (48), this can only be possible if it happens to be the case that c = w s (t) S + w p (t) P = S @c @S + P @c @P (52) Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 31/ 36

Hedge Portfolio Dynamics By Euler s theorem, condition (52) holds if the option price is a homogeneous of degree 1 function of S and P. That is, c (ks (t) ; kp (t; ) ; t) = kc (S (t) ; P (t; ) ; t). If so, then no-arbitrage implies dh(t) = 0: w s (t) ( c ) S + w p (t) p c P = 0 (53) or @c @S ( c ) S + @c @P p c P = 0 (54) which, using (52), can be rewritten as @c @c S + @S @P pp c c = 0 (55) Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 32/ 36

Hedge Portfolio Dynamics cont d Substituting for c c from (47), we obtain @c @t 1 @ 2 c 2 @S 2 2 S 2 1 @ 2 c 2 @P 2 2 pp 2 which, since T 1 2 t, can also be written as @ 2 c @S 2 2 S 2 + @2 c @P 2 2 pp 2 + 2 @2 c @S@P psp @ 2 c @S@P psp = 0 (56) The boundary conditions are c (S (T ) ; P (T ; 0) ; T ) = c (S (T ) ; 1; T ) = max [S (T ) X ; 0] where P (t = T ; = 0) = 1. The Merton (1973) solution is @c @ = 0 (57) Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 33/ 36

Merton PDE Solution where where c (S (t) ; P (t; ) ; ) = S(t) N(h 1 ) P (t; ) XN(h 2 ) (58) v 2 = h 1 = ln h 2 = h 1 v Z 0 S(t) P(t;)X 2 + p (y) 2 v + 1 2 v 2 (59) 2 p (y) dy (60) This is the Black-Scholes equation with v 2 replacing 2. v 2 S(t) is the total variance of P(t;)X from date t to date T, an interval of periods. Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 34/ 36

Merton PDE Solution cont d If the bond s volatility is assumed to be that of the Vasicek model, p (y) = r (1 e y ), then (60) is R v 2 = 2 + 2 r 2 1 2e y + e 2y 2 r 1 e y dy 0 = 2 + 2 r 3 + 1 e 2 2 2 1 e 2 r 2 1 e (61) Finally, note that the solution is homogeneous of degree 1 in S (t) and P (t; ), which veri es condition (52). Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 35/ 36

Summary When an underlying asset follows a di usion and trade is can occur continuously, a portfolio can be created that fully hedges the risk of a contingent claim. In the absence of arbitrage, this hedge portfolio s return must equal the riskless rate, which implies an equilibrium partial di erential equation for the contingent claim s value. This Black-Scholes-Merton hedging argument can derive values of options and determine a term structure of default-free interest rates. Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation 36/ 36