A MARTINGALE REPRESENTATION FOR THE MAXIMUM OF A LÉVY PROCESS

Similar documents
Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension

Stochastic Integral Representation of One Stochastically Non-smooth Wiener Functional

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model

Minimal Variance Hedging in Large Financial Markets: random fields approach

American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 13 Mar 2014

Sensitivity of American Option Prices with Different Strikes, Maturities and Volatilities

Lecture 1: Lévy processes

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

Chapter 1. Introduction and Preliminaries. 1.1 Motivation. The American put option problem

The Azema Yor embedding in non-singular diusions

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS

Math 6810 (Probability) Fall Lecture notes

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

Barrier Options Pricing in Uncertain Financial Market

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon

American Foreign Exchange Options and some Continuity Estimates of the Optimal Exercise Boundary with respect to Volatility

Non-semimartingales in finance

Term Structure of Credit Spreads of A Firm When Its Underlying Assets are Discontinuous

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

A Continuity Correction under Jump-Diffusion Models with Applications in Finance

Universität Regensburg Mathematik

Introduction to Stochastic Calculus With Applications

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Stochastic calculus Introduction I. Stochastic Finance. C. Azizieh VUB 1/91. C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance

The Azéma-Yor Embedding in Non-Singular Diffusions

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

Estimation of Value at Risk and ruin probability for diffusion processes with jumps

Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs.

Applications of Lévy processes

Martingale Representation and All That

Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach

Martingale Transport, Skorokhod Embedding and Peacocks

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

CONVERGENCE OF OPTION REWARDS FOR MARKOV TYPE PRICE PROCESSES MODULATED BY STOCHASTIC INDICES

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Control Improvement for Jump-Diffusion Processes with Applications to Finance

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

Convergence of Discretized Stochastic (Interest Rate) Processes with Stochastic Drift Term.

EXPLICIT MARTINGALE REPRESENTATIONS FOR BROWNIAN FUNCTIONALS AND APPLICATIONS TO OPTION HEDGING

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Brownian Motion. Richard Lockhart. Simon Fraser University. STAT 870 Summer 2011

CRRAO Advanced Institute of Mathematics, Statistics and Computer Science (AIMSCS) Research Report. B. L. S. Prakasa Rao

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

Weierstrass Institute for Applied Analysis and Stochastics Maximum likelihood estimation for jump diffusions

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

SOME APPLICATIONS OF OCCUPATION TIMES OF BROWNIAN MOTION WITH DRIFT IN MATHEMATICAL FINANCE

Functional Ito calculus. hedging of path-dependent options

American Barrier Option Pricing Formulae for Uncertain Stock Model

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.pr] 23 Nov 2017

Hedging under Arbitrage

Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies

VALUATION OF FLEXIBLE INSURANCE CONTRACTS

Exponential utility maximization under partial information and sufficiency of information

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

Modeling Credit Risk with Partial Information

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.gn] 13 Aug 2018

1 Rare event simulation and importance sampling

Efficient valuation of exotic derivatives in Lévy models

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Logarithmic derivatives of densities for jump processes

Model-independent bounds for Asian options

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

The British Russian Option

Hedging under arbitrage

Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard

In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure

S t d with probability (1 p), where

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 11 10/9/2013. Martingales and stopping times II

Credit Risk using Time Changed Brownian Motions

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

Path Dependent British Options

A Numerical Approach to the Estimation of Search Effort in a Search for a Moving Object

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

Math 489/Math 889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Dunbar, Fall 2007

Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences

Interest rate models in continuous time

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View

Weak Convergence to Stochastic Integrals

Lévy models in finance

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

Transcription:

Communications on Stochastic Analysis Vol. 5, No. 4 (211) 683-688 Serials Publications www.serialspublications.com A MATINGALE EPESENTATION FO THE MAXIMUM OF A LÉVY POCESS BUNO ÉMILLAD AND JEAN-FANÇOIS ENAUD Abstract. By using Malliavin calculus for Lévy processes, we compute an explicit martingale representation for the maximum of a square-integrable Lévy process. 1. Introduction and Preliminary esults The representation of functionals of Brownian motion by stochastic integrals, also known as martingale representation, has been widely studied. The martingale representation theorem states that any square-integrable Brownian functional is equal to a stochastic integral with respect to Brownian motion; it plays an important role in mathematical finance, where it appears naturally in optimal portfolio compositions. Martingale representation theorems are also important in stochastic calculus for Lévy processes. For a survey on martingale representation theorems, see [2]. In the Brownian motion case, the Clark-Ocone formula of Malliavin calculus is a powerful tool to get explicit martingale representations for path-dependent Brownian functionals; for an example of application, see [11]. ecently, due the development of Malliavin calculus for Lévy processes, many Clark-Ocone formulas have appeared for various sub-classes of this family of processes. For more details, the reader is invited to have a look at [3]. In this note, using a Clark-Ocone formula for Lévy processes, we compute an explicit martingale representation of the maximum of a square-integrable Lévy process, therefore providing a generalization of the well-known explicit martingale representation of the maximum for Brownian motion. Let T be a strictly positive real number and let X = (X t ) t [,T] be a (onedimensional) Lévy process defined on a probability space (Ω,F,P), i.e., X is a process with independent and stationary increments, is continuous in probability and starts from almost surely. We assume that X is the càdlàg modification and that the probability space is equipped with the completed filtration (F t ) t [,T] generated by X. We also assume that the σ-field F is equal to F T. This filtration satisfies the usual conditions and, for any fixed time t, F t = F t ; see [1]. eceived 211-7-13; Communicated by Hui-Hsiung Kuo. 2 Mathematics Subject Classification. 6H7, 6G51. Key words and phrases. Martingale representation, Lévy processes, Malliavin calculus, Clark- Ocone formula. 683

684 B. ÉMILLAD AND J.-F. ENAUD When the Lévy process X is square-integrable, it can be expressed as t X t = µt+σw t + zñ(ds,dz), (1.1) where µ is a real number, σ is a strictly positive real number, W is a standard Brownian motion and Ñ is the compensated Poisson random measure associated with the Poisson random measure N of X. The Poisson random measure N is independent of the Brownian motion W. Its compensator measure is denoted by λ ν, where λ is Lebesgue measure on [,T] and ν is the Lévy measure of X, i.e., ν is a σ-finite measure on such that ν({}) = and (1 z 2 )ν(dz) <. Therefore the compensated random measure Ñ is defined by Ñ([,t] A) = N([,t] A) tν(a). In this setup, let P be the predictable σ-field on [,T] Ω and B() the Borel σ-field on. A process ψ(t,z,ω) is said to be Borel predictable if it is (P B())- measurable. For the rest of the paper, we suppose that X is a square-integrable Lévy process with a decomposition as in Equation (1.1). A direct extension of Theorem 9.1 in [3] (see e.g. [12] for more details) yields the following martingale representation theorem for Lévy processes: Theorem1.1. Let F L 2 (Ω,F,P). There exist a unique Borel predictable process ψ L 2 (λ ν P) and a unique predictable process φ L 2 (λ P) such that T T F = E[F]+ φ(t)dw t + ψ(t,z)ñ(dt,dz). (1.2) The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we first recall the martingale representation for the maximum of Brownian motion and then state our main result, that is the martingale representation for the maximum of a general square-integrable Lévy process. Then, in Section 3, after a very short presentation of the relevant results from Malliavin calculus for Lévy processes, we proceed to the proof of the main result. 2. Martingale epresentation for the unning Supremum For s < t T, define M s,t = sup s r t X r and M t = M,t. Our main result is a generalization of the following one: Theorem 2.1. If X = W, i.e. if X is a standard Brownian motion, then 2T T [ ( )] M T = π + Mt W t 2 1 Φ dw t, T t where Φ(x) = P{N(,1) x}. This last representation can be found in [13]. Their proof uses Clark s formula (see [1]), which is essentially a Clark-Ocone formula on the canonical space of Brownian motion. It can also be computed using a completely different method

MATINGALE EPESENTATION 685 based on Itô s formula (see [14]). Let s note that if one extends this by adding a drift to the Brownian motion, the results are similar (see [11]). Our main result consists in providing explicit expressions for φ and ψ appearing in (1.2) for F = M T when X is an arbitrary square-integrable Lévy process. Set F t (y) = P{M t > y}. Theorem 2.2. If X a square-integrable Lévy process, then its running maximum can be written as follows: T T M T = E[M T ]+ φ(t,m t X t )dw t + ψ(t,z,m t X t )Ñ(dt,dz), with φ(t,y) = σ F T t (y) and ψ(t,z,y) = (z y) + +I {z>y} y F T t (x)dx+i {z y} y y z F T t (x)dx. It is easily shown that Theorem 2.2 is an extension of Theorem 2.1; it suffices to notice that when X = W we have Ñ(dt,dz) and ( ( F t (y) = 2 1 Φ y/ )) t. When X is a square-integrable subordinator, e.g. a Gamma subordinator, then trivially M T = X T and F t (y) is the tail of the distribution of X t. For many jumpdiffusion Lévy processes, i.e., when X is the sum of a Brownian motion with drift and a compound Poisson jump structure with finite second moment (e.g. Kou s model [5]), the distribution of M T can be obtained up to the inversion of a Laplace transform. The distribution of the running supremum of more sophisticated Lévy processes have been studied by A. Kuznetsov and his co-authors, see [7, 6]. 3. Proof of Theorem 2.2 Our proof for Theorem 2.2 is based on a Malliavin calculus for square-integrable Lévy processes constructed along the same lines as the standard Brownian Malliavin calculus and the Malliavin calculus for pure-jump square-integrable Lévy processes as developed in [8]. See [3] for the main definitions and results, and for more references. Several proofs are provided in [12]. One can define two directional derivative operators, one in the direction of the Brownian motion and one in the direction of the Poisson random measure: these (directional) derivative operators are respectively given by D (1) : D (1) L 2 ([,T] Ω) and D (2) : D (2) L 2 ([,T] Ω), where D (1) and D (2) stand for their respective domain. We say that F is Malliavin differentiable if F D 1,2 := D (1) D (2). We use the following norm for the Malliavin derivative DF := (D (1) F,D (2) F): DF 2 = D (1) F 2 L 2 (λ P) + D(2) F 2 L 2 (λ ν P). The Malliavin derivative D is continuous: Lemma 3.1. If F belongs to L 2 (Ω), if (F k ) k 1 is a sequence of elements in D 1,2 converging to F in the L 2 (Ω)-norm and if sup k 1 DF k <, then F belongs to D 1,2 and (DF k ) k 1 converges weakly to DF in L 2 (λ P) L 2 (λ ν P).

686 B. ÉMILLAD AND J.-F. ENAUD If F D (1), all the results about the classical Brownian Malliavin derivative, such as the chain rule for Lipschitz functions, can be applied to D (1) F; see Nualart [9] for details. But this is also true for the Poisson random measure Malliavin derivative. For example, if F = g(x t1,...,x tn ) D (2) and (t,z) g ( X t1 +zi [,t1](t),...,x tn +zi [,tn](t) ) g(x t1,...,x tn ) belongs to L 2 (λ ν P), then D (2) t,zf = g ( X t1 +zi [,t1](t),...,x tn +zi [,tn](t) ) g(x t1,...,x tn ). This is the adding-a-mass formula; see [3] and the references therein for more details. Finally, here is the corresponding Clark-Ocone formula: Theorem 3.2. If F belongs to D 1,2, then F = E[F]+ T E [ D (1) t F F t ] dwt + T E [ D (2) t,z F F t]ñ(dt,dz). We are now ready to prove Theorem 2.2. First, since X is a square-integrable martingale with drift, from Doob s maximal inequality we have that M T is a square-integrable random variable. Also, if E[M T ] <, then one can show that (see Shiryaev and Yor [14] and Graversen et al. [4]) E[M T F t ] = M t + M t X t FT t (z)dz. (3.1) Now, let (t k ) k 1 be a dense subset of [,T], let F = M T and, for each n 1, define F n = max{x t1,...,x tn }. Clearly, (F n ) n 1 is an increasing sequence bounded by F. Hence F n converges to F in the L 2 (Ω)-norm when n goes to infinity. We want to prove that each F n is Malliavin differentiable, i.e., that each F n belongs to D 1,2 = D (1) D (2). This follows from the following two facts. First, since (x 1,...,x n ) max{x 1,...,x n } is a Lipschitz function on n and since D (1) operates like the classical Brownian Malliavin derivative on the Brownian part of F n, we have that n n D (1) t F n = σi {t tk }I Ak σi Ak = σ, k=1 where A 1 = {F n = X t1 } and A k = {F n X t1,...,f n X tk 1,F n = X tk } for 2 k n. This implies that sup n 1 D (1) F n 2 L 2 ([,T] Ω) σ2 T. Secondly, since D (2) operates like the Poissonrandommeasure Malliavinderivative on the Poisson part of F n, we have that D (2) t,zf n = max { Xt1 +zi {t<t1},...,x tn +zi {t<tn}} Fn z, where the equality is justified by the following inequality: { max Xt1 +zi {t<t1},...,x tn +zi {t<tn}} Fn 2 L 2 ([,T] Ω) T z 2 ν(dz). k=1

MATINGALE EPESENTATION 687 Indeed, if z, then max { X t1 +zi {t<t1},...,x tn +zi {t<tn}} Fn z, and, if z <, then F n max { } X t1 +zi {t<t1},...,x tn +zi {t<tn} = F n +min { } X t1 + z I {t<t1},..., X tn + z I {t<tn} = min { } F n X t1 + z I {t<t1},...,f n X tn + z I {t<tn} z. This implies that sup n 1 D (2) F n 2 L 2 ([,T] Ω) T z2 ν(dz). Consequently, sup n 1 DF n 2 T(σ 2 + z2 ν(dz)) and we have that F is Malliavin differentiable. By the uniqueness of the limit, this means that taking the limit of D (1) t F n when n goes to infinity yields D (1) t F = σi [,τ] (t), where τ = inf{t [,T]: X t = M T }, with the convention inf = T, i.e. τ is the first time when the Lévy process X (not the Brownian motion W) reaches its supremum on [,T], and Hence D t,zf (2) ( ) = sup Xs +zi {t<s} MT. s T [ ] E D (1) t F F t = σp{m t < M t,t F t } = σp{m T t > a}, where a = M t X t. Since M t,t X t is independent of F t and has the same law as M T t, then using Equation (3.1) we get that [ ] [ ] E D t,zf (2) ( ) F t = E Xs +zi {t<s} MT F t sup s T where a = M t X t. Since [ E (M T t +z a) +] = = E[max{M t,m t,t +z} F t ] E[M T F t ] ] = M t +E [(M t,t +z M t ) + F t E[M T F t ] [ = E (M T t +z a) +] F T t (x)dx, a z a F T t (x)dx, we have that ψ(t,z,a) = F T t (x)dx F T t (x)dx a z a a = I {z a} (z a)+i {z a} F T t (x)dx +I {a>z } a a z F T t (x)dx I {z<} a z a F T t (x)dx. Finally, the martingale representation follows from the Clark-Ocone formula given in Theorem 3.2.

688 B. ÉMILLAD AND J.-F. ENAUD Acknowledgments. Funding in support of this work was provided by the Natural Sciences and Engineering esearch Council of Canada (NSEC), the Fonds québécois de la recherche sur la nature et les technologies (FQNT) and the Institut de finance mathématique de Montréal (IFM2). eferences 1. Clark, J. M. C.: The representation of functionals of Brownian motion by stochastic integrals, Ann. Math. Statist. 41 (197), 1282 1295. 2. Davis, M. H. A.: Martingale representation and all that, in: Advances in control, communication networks, and transportation systems, Systems Control Found. Appl. (25) 57 68, Birkhäuser Boston. 3. Di Nunno, G., Øksendal, B., and Proske, F.: Malliavin Calculus for Lévy Processes with Applications to Finance, Universitext - Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 29. 4. Graversen, S. E., Peskir, G., and Shiryaev, A. N.: Stopping Brownian motion without anticipation as close as possible to its ultimate maximum, Theory Probab. Appl. 45 (21), 125 136. 5. Kou, S. G.: A jump-diffusion model for option pricing, Management Science 48 (22), 186 111. 6. Kuznetsov, A.: Wiener-Hopf factorization and distribution of extrema for a family of Lévy processes, Ann. Appl. Probab. 2 (21), 181 183. 7. Kuznetsov, A., Kyprianou, A. E., and Pardo, J. C.: Meromorphic Lévy processes and their fluctuation identities, Ann. Appl. Probab. (to appear). 8. Løkka, A.: Martingale representation of functionals of Lévy processes, Stochastic Anal. Appl. 22 (24), 867 892. 9. Nualart, D.: The Malliavin Calculus and elated Topics, Springer-Verlag, 1995. 1. Protter, P. E.: Stochastic Integration and Differential Equations, Springer-Verlag, second edition, 24. 11. enaud, J.-F. and émillard, B.: Explicit martingale representations for Brownian functionals and applications to option hedging, Stochastic Anal. Appl., 25 (27), 81 82. 12. enaud, J.-F. and émillard, B.: Malliavin calculus and Clark-Ocone formula for functionals of a square-integrable Lévy process, GEAD Technical report G-29-67 (29). 13. ogers, L. C. G. and Williams, D.: Diffusions, Markov Processes and Martingales, volume 2: Itô calculus, Wiley and Sons, 1987. 14. Shiryaev, A. N. and Yor, M.: On stochastic integral representations of functionals of Brownian motion, Theory Probab. Appl. 48 (24), 34 313. Bruno émillard: Service de l enseignement des méthodes quantitatives de gestion, HEC Montréal, 3 chemin de la Côte-Sainte-Catherine, Montréal (Québec), H3T 2A7, Canada E-mail address: bruno.remillard@hec.ca Jean-François enaud: Département de mathématiques, Université du Québec à Montréal (UQAM), 21 av. Président-Kennedy, Montréal (Québec) H2X 3Y7, Canada E-mail address: renaud.jf@uqam.ca