A lower bound on seller revenue in single buyer monopoly auctions

Similar documents
Lower Bounds on Revenue of Approximately Optimal Auctions

Approximate Revenue Maximization with Multiple Items

Single-Parameter Mechanisms

CS364B: Frontiers in Mechanism Design Lecture #18: Multi-Parameter Revenue-Maximization

The efficiency of fair division

American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market

Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012

CS364A: Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture #14: Robust Price-of-Anarchy Bounds in Smooth Games

Day 3. Myerson: What s Optimal

Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand

CS364A: Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture #3: Myerson s Lemma

Time Resolution of the St. Petersburg Paradox: A Rebuttal

Correlation-Robust Mechanism Design

FURTHER ASPECTS OF GAMBLING WITH THE KELLY CRITERION. We consider two aspects of gambling with the Kelly criterion. First, we show that for

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w

Mechanism Design and Auctions

Richardson Extrapolation Techniques for the Pricing of American-style Options

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

The Value of Information in Central-Place Foraging. Research Report

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF FINITE

Revenue Maximization with a Single Sample (Proofs Omitted to Save Space)

Competing Mechanisms with Limited Commitment

Optimal Platform Design

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Auction Theory Lecture Note, David McAdams, Fall Bilateral Trade

April 29, X ( ) for all. Using to denote a true type and areport,let

Local vs Non-local Forward Equations for Option Pricing

Monte Carlo Simulation in Financial Valuation

An Improved Saddlepoint Approximation Based on the Negative Binomial Distribution for the General Birth Process

Math 489/Math 889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Dunbar, Fall 2007

The Conservative Expected Value: A New Measure with Motivation from Stock Trading via Feedback

Mossin s Theorem for Upper-Limit Insurance Policies

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

Equilibrium Price Dispersion with Sequential Search

Deriving the Black-Scholes Equation and Basic Mathematical Finance

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model

The value of foresight

Characterization of the Optimum

Andreas Wagener University of Vienna. Abstract

SAMPLE STANDARD DEVIATION(s) CHART UNDER THE ASSUMPTION OF MODERATENESS AND ITS PERFORMANCE ANALYSIS

Single Price Mechanisms for Revenue Maximization in Unlimited Supply Combinatorial Auctions

Much of what appears here comes from ideas presented in the book:

Slides for Risk Management

A Preference Foundation for Fehr and Schmidt s Model. of Inequity Aversion 1

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012

A SIMPLE DERIVATION OF AND IMPROVEMENTS TO JAMSHIDIAN S AND ROGERS UPPER BOUND METHODS FOR BERMUDAN OPTIONS

Liquidity and Risk Management

Week 2 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Hypothesis Testing and Confidence Intervals

Module 10:Application of stochastic processes in areas like finance Lecture 36:Black-Scholes Model. Stochastic Differential Equation.

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Distortion operator of uncertainty claim pricing using weibull distortion operator

Optimal Mixed Spectrum Auction

Option Pricing Formula for Fuzzy Financial Market

Lecture 2. Vladimir Asriyan and John Mondragon. September 14, UC Berkeley

On the Distribution and Its Properties of the Sum of a Normal and a Doubly Truncated Normal

Lecture 7: Bayesian approach to MAB - Gittins index

Problem 1: Random variables, common distributions and the monopoly price

Optimal Allocation of Policy Limits and Deductibles

Probabilistic Analysis of the Economic Impact of Earthquake Prediction Systems

Single Price Mechanisms for Revenue Maximization in Unlimited Supply Combinatorial Auctions

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM

Sequential Coalition Formation for Uncertain Environments

Dynamic and Stochastic Knapsack-Type Models for Foreclosed Housing Acquisition and Redevelopment

The Complexity of Simple and Optimal Deterministic Mechanisms for an Additive Buyer. Xi Chen, George Matikas, Dimitris Paparas, Mihalis Yannakakis

Optimal Auctions. Game Theory Course: Jackson, Leyton-Brown & Shoham

The Stigler-Luckock model with market makers

Expected utility inequalities: theory and applications

November 2006 LSE-CDAM

Copula-Based Pairs Trading Strategy

Price Discrimination As Portfolio Diversification. Abstract

Stability in geometric & functional inequalities

Infinite Horizon Optimal Policy for an Inventory System with Two Types of Products sharing Common Hardware Platforms

GENERATION OF STANDARD NORMAL RANDOM NUMBERS. Naveen Kumar Boiroju and M. Krishna Reddy

Directed Search and the Futility of Cheap Talk

Lecture 3: Information in Sequential Screening

Mechanisms for House Allocation with Existing Tenants under Dichotomous Preferences

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

BICRITERIA OPTIMIZATION IN THE NEWSVENDOR PROBLEM WITH EXPONENTIALLY DISTRIBUTED DEMAND 1

IEOR 3106: Introduction to OR: Stochastic Models. Fall 2013, Professor Whitt. Class Lecture Notes: Tuesday, September 10.

Recap First-Price Revenue Equivalence Optimal Auctions. Auction Theory II. Lecture 19. Auction Theory II Lecture 19, Slide 1

Revenue Maximization in a Bayesian Double Auction Market

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

Estimation of Value at Risk and ruin probability for diffusion processes with jumps

A Skewed Truncated Cauchy Uniform Distribution and Its Moments

STATISTICS and PROBABILITY

CDS Pricing Formula in the Fuzzy Credit Risk Market

Near-Optimal Multi-Unit Auctions with Ordered Bidders

Probability. An intro for calculus students P= Figure 1: A normal integral

An Approximation Algorithm for Capacity Allocation over a Single Flight Leg with Fare-Locking

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers. Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel)

Constrained Sequential Resource Allocation and Guessing Games

Information Acquisition under Persuasive Precedent versus Binding Precedent (Preliminary and Incomplete)

Some Computational Aspects of Martingale Processes in ruling the Arbitrage from Binomial asset Pricing Model

Price Setting with Interdependent Values

arxiv: v1 [cs.gt] 12 Aug 2008

Information Processing and Limited Liability

Transcription:

A lower bound on seller revenue in single buyer monopoly auctions Omer Tamuz October 7, 213 Abstract We consider a monopoly seller who optimally auctions a single object to a single potential buyer, with a known distribution of valuations. We show that a tight lower bound on the seller s expected revenue is 1/e times the geometric expectation of the buyer s valuation, and that this bound is uniquely achieved for the equal revenue distribution. We show also that when the valuation s expectation and geometric expectation are close, then the seller s expected revenue is close to the expected valuation. 1 Introduction Consider a monopoly seller, selling a single object to a single potential buyer. We assume that the buyer has a valuation for the object which is unknown to the seller, and that the seller s uncertainty is quantified by a probability distribution, from which it believes the buyer picks its valuation. Assuming that the seller wishes to maximize its expected revenue, Myerson [1] shows that the optimal incentive compatible mechanism involves a simple one-time offer: the seller optimally) chooses a price and offers the buyer to buy the object for this price; the assumption is that the buyer accepts the offer if its valuation exceeds this price. Myerson s seminal paper has become a classical result in auction theory, with numerous follow-up studies. A survey of this literature is beyond the scope of this paper see, e.g., [2, 3]). The expected seller revenue is an important, simple intrinsic characteristic of the valuation distribution. A natural question is its relation with various other properties of the distribution. For example, can seller revenue be bounded given such characterizations of the valuation as its expectation, entropy, etc.? An immediate upper bound on seller revenue is the buyer s expected valuation. In fact, the seller can extract the buyer s expected valuation only if the seller knows the buyer s valuation exactly - i.e., the distribution over valuations is a point mass. Lower bounds on seller revenue are important in the study of approximations to Myerson auctions see., e.g., Hartline and Roughgarden [4], Daskalakis and Pierrakos [5]). A general lower bound on the seller s revenue is known when the distribution of the buyer s valuation has a monotone hazard rate; in this case, the seller s expected revenue is at least 1/e times the expected valuation see Hartline, Mirrokni and Sundararajan [6], as well as Dhangwatnotai, Roughgarden and Yan [7]). This bound does not hold in general: as an extreme example, the equal revenue distribution discussed below has infinite expectation but finite seller revenue. The family of monotone hazard rate distributions does not include many important distributions such the Pareto distribution or other power law distributions, or in fact any distribution that doesn t have a very thin tail, vanishing at least exponentially. The above mentioned lower bound for monotone hazard rate distributions Weizmann Institute, Rehovot 761, Israel 1

does not apply to these distributions, and indeed it seems that the literature lacks any similar, general lower bounds on seller revenue. The geometric expectation of a positive random variable X is G [X] = expe [log X]) see, e.g., [8]). We show that a general lower bound on the seller s expected revenue is 1/e times the geometric expectation of the valuation. Equivalently, the natural) logarithm of the expected seller revenue is greater than or equal to the expectation of the logarithm of the valuation, minus one. This bound holds for any distribution of positive valuations. Notably, the regularity condition, which often appears in the context of Myerson auctions, is not required here. This result is a new and perhaps unexpected connection between two natural properties of distributions: the geometric expectation and expected seller revenue. We show that this bound is tight in the following sense: for a fixed value of the geometric mean, there is a unique cumulative distribution function CDF) of the buyer s valuation for which the bound is achieved; this distribution is the equal revenue distribution, with CDF of the form F v) = 1 c/v for v c. This distribution is special in the context of single buyer Myerson auctions, as it is the only one where seller revenue is identical for all prices. The ratio between expected valuation and expected seller revenue is a natural measure of the uncertainty of the valuation distribution. Also, the discrepancy between the geometric expectation and the arithmetic) expectation of a positive random variable is a well known measure of its dispersion. Hence, when the ratio between the expectations is close to one, one would expect the amount of uncertainty to be low and therefore seller revenue to be close to the expected valuation. We show that this is indeed the case: when the buyer s valuation has finite expectation, and the geometric expectation is within a factor of 1 δ of the expectation, then seller revenue is within a factor of 1 2 4/3 δ 1/3 of the expected valuation. Similarly, it is easy to show that when the variance of the valuation approaches zero then seller revenue also approaches the expected valuation. 2 Definitions and results We consider a seller who wishes to sell a single object to a single potential buyer. The buyer has a valuation V for the object which is picked from a distribution with CDF F, i.e. F v) = P [V v]. We assume that V is positive, so that P [V ] = or F ) =. We otherwise make no assumptions on the distribution of V ; it may be atomic or non-atomic, have or not have an expectation, etc. The seller offers the object to the buyer for a fixed price p. The buyer accepts the offer if p < V, in which case the seller s revenue is p. Otherwise, i.e., if p V, then the seller s revenue is. Thus, the seller s expected revenue for price p, which we denote by U p [V ], is given by We define U p [V ] = pp [p < V ] = p1 F p)). 1) U [V ] = sup p U p [V ] = sup p1 F p)). 2) p When this supremum is achieved for some price p then U [V ] is the seller s maximal expected revenue, achieved in the optimal Myerson auction with price p. We define the geometric expectation see, e.g., [8]) of a positive real random variable X by G [X] = exp E [log X]). Note that G [X] E [X] by Jensen s inequality, and that equality is achieved only for point mass distributions, i.e., when the buyer s valuation is some fixed number. Note that likewise U [V ] E [V ], again with equality only for point mass distributions. 2

The equal revenue distribution with parameter c has the following CDF: { p c Φ c p) = 1 c p p > c. 3) It is called equal revenue because if V c has CDF Φ c then U p [V c ] = U [V c ] for all p c. Our main result is the following theorem. Theorem 2.1. Let V be a positive random variable. Then U [V ] 1 eg [V ], with equality if and only if V has the equal revenue CDF Φ c with c = U [V ]. Proof. Let V be a positive random variable with CDF F. By Eq. 2 we have that log U [V ] log p + log1 F p)) 4) for all p. We now take the expectation of both sides with respect to p F : log U [V ] df p) log p df p) + log1 F p))df p). 5) Since U [V ] is a constant then the l.h.s. equals log U [V ]. The first addend on the r.h.s. is simply E [log V ]. The second is E [log1 F V ))]; note that F V ) is distributed uniformly on [, 1], and that therefore Hence Eq. 5 becomes: E [log1 F V ))] = 1 log1 x)dx = 1. log U [V ] E [log V ] 1, and U [V ] 1 e expe [log V ]) = 1 e G [V ]. To see that U [V ] = 1 eg [V ] only for the equal revenue distribution with parameter U [V ], note that we have equality in Eq. 4 for all p in the support of F if and only if F = Φ c for some c, and that therefore we have equality in Eq. 5 if and only if F = Φ c for some c. Finally, a simple calculation yields that c = U [V ]. Note that this proof in fact demonstrates a stronger statement, namely that the expected revenue is at least 1 eg [V ] for a seller picking a random price from the distribution of V. Dhangwatnotai, Roughgarden and Yan [7] use similar ideas to show lower bounds on revenue, for valuation distributions with monotone hazard rates. We next show that when the geometric expectation approaches the arithmetic) expectation then the seller revenue also approaches the expectation. Theorem 2.2. Let V be a positive random variable with finite expectation, and let G [V ] = 1 δ)e [V ]. Then U [V ] 1 2 4/3 δ 1/3) E [V ]. 3

Proof. Let V be a positive random variable with finite expectation, and denote 1 δ = G[V ] E[V ]. We normalize V so that E [V ] = 1, and prove the claim by showing that U [V ] 1 2 4/3 δ 1/3. Consider the random variable V 1 log V. Since E [V ] = 1, we have that E [V 1 log V ] = log G [V ] = log1 δ). Since x 1 log x for all x >, then V 1 log V is non-negative. Hence by Markov s inequality P [V 1 log V k log1 δ)] 1 k, or [ P V e 1 V 1 δ) k] 1 k. 6) This inequality is a concentration result, showing that when δ is small then V e 1 V is unlikely to be much less than one. However, for our end we require a concentration result on V rather than on V e 1 V ; that will enable us to show that the seller can sell with high probability for a price close to the arithmetic expectation. To this end, we will use the Lambert W function, which is defined at x as the solution of the equation W x)e W x) = x. We use it to solve the inequality of Eq. 6 and arrive at [ )] P V W 1 δ) k /e 1 k, which is the concentration result we needed: V is unlikely to be small when δ is small. It follows that by setting the price at W 1 δ) k /e ), the seller sells with probability at least 1 1/k, and so ) ) U [V ] W 1 δ) k /e 1 1/k. Now, an upper bound on W is the following [9]: W x) 1 + 2ex + 1), and so U [V ] ) ) 1 21 1 δ) k 1 1/k 1 ) ) 2δk 1 1/k. Setting k = 2δ) 1/3 we get U [V ] 1 2δ) 1/2 2δ) 1/6) 1 2δ) 1/3) 1 22δ) 1/3. 3 Open questions It may very well be possible to show tighter upper bounds for U [V ], using continuous entropy. For example, let V have expectation 1 and entropy at least 1. Then U [V ] is at most 1/e: in fact, it is equal to 1/e since, by maximum entropy arguments, there is only one distribution on R + the exponential with expectation 1) that satisfies both conditions, and for this distribution U [V ] = 1/e. One could hope that it is likewise possible to prove upper bounds on U [V ], given that V has expectation 1 and entropy at least h < 1; intuitively, the entropy constraint should force V to spread rather than concentrate around its expectation, decreasing the seller s expected revenue. 4

4 Acknowledgments We would like to thank Elchanan Mossel for commenting on a preliminary version of this paper. We owe a debt of gratitude to the anonymous reviewer who helped us improve the paper significantly through many helpful suggestions. This research is supported by ISF grant 13/8, and by a Google Europe Fellowship in Social Computing. References [1] R. Myerson, Optimal auction design, Mathematics of operations research 1981) 58 73. [2] V. Krishna, Auction theory, Academic press, 29. [3] P. Klemperer, Auction theory: A guide to the literature, Journal of economic surveys 13 3) 1999) 227 286. [4] J. Hartline, T. Roughgarden, Simple versus optimal mechanisms, in: Proceedings of the 1th ACM conference on Electronic Commerce, ACM, 29, pp. 225 234. [5] C. Daskalakis, G. Pierrakos, Simple, optimal and efficient auctions, in: N. Chen, E. Elkind, E. Koutsoupias Eds.), Internet and Network Economics, Vol. 79 of Lecture Notes in Computer Science, Springer Berlin Heidelberg, 211, pp. 19 121. [6] J. Hartline, V. Mirrokni, M. Sundararajan, Optimal marketing strategies over social networks, in: Proceedings of the 17th international World Wide Web conference, ACM, 28, pp. 189 198. [7] P. Dhangwatnotai, T. Roughgarden, Q. Yan, Revenue maximization with a single sample, in: Proceedings of the 11th ACM conference on Electronic Commerce, ACM, 21, pp. 129 138. [8] M. Paolella, Fundamental probability: A computational approach, John Wiley & Sons, 26. [9] R. Corless, G. Gonnet, D. Hare, D. Jeffrey, D. Knuth, On the Lambert W function, Advances in Computational mathematics 5 1) 1996) 329 359. 5