Volume 30, Issue 4. A decomposition of the home-market effect

Similar documents
The Dixit-Stiglitz-Krugman Trade Model: A Geometric Note

The Effects of Regional Free Trade Agreements on Industrial Structure: An Extension of Krugman s Economic Geography Model (1991)

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

International Trade Lecture 5: Increasing Returns to Scale and Monopolistic Competition

Discussion Papers In Economics And Business

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography

Trade Liberalization and Labor Unions

Economic Geography, Monopolistic Competition and Trade

Monopolistic competition: the Dixit-Stiglitz-Spence model

Economics 689 Texas A&M University

Growth with Time Zone Differences

Infrastructure and Urban Primacy: A Theoretical Model. Jinghui Lim 1. Economics Urban Economics Professor Charles Becker December 15, 2005

Product Di erentiation. We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade.

International Trade: Lecture 3

Kwok Tong Soo Lancaster University. Abstract

Fiscal Policy in a Small Open Economy with Endogenous Labor Supply * 1

Generalized Taylor Rule and Determinacy of Growth Equilibrium. Abstract

Impact of Tariff under Hecksher-Ohlin Comparative Advantage Setting and Firm Heterogeneity

International Trade Lecture 14: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (I) Melitz (2003)

Social Common Capital and Sustainable Development. H. Uzawa. Social Common Capital Research, Tokyo, Japan. (IPD Climate Change Manchester Meeting)

International Trade Gravity Model

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Perhaps the most striking aspect of the current

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth

Advanced Macro and Money (WS09/10) Problem Set 4

Foundational Preliminaries: Answers to Within-Chapter-Exercises

Revisiting Cournot and Bertrand in the presence of income effects

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

International Economics B 9. Monopolistic competition and international trade: Firm Heterogeneity

Export Taxes under Bertrand Duopoly. Abstract

Lecture 3: New Trade Theory

Some Simple Analytics of the Taxation of Banks as Corporations

Firms in International Trade. Lecture 2: The Melitz Model

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

It Takes a Village - Network Effect of Child-rearing

1 Roy model: Chiswick (1978) and Borjas (1987)

Savings, Investment and the Real Interest Rate in an Endogenous Growth Model

Local public good, regional integration and fiscal competition : an economic geography model

A Note on the Solow Growth Model with a CES Production Function and Declining Population

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS

Public Investment, Life Expectancy and Income Growth

Monopolistic competition models

Chapter 10 THE PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM COMPETITIVE MODEL. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Trade Protection and the Location of Production

Optimal Taxation Policy in the Presence of Comprehensive Reference Externalities. Constantin Gurdgiev

Midterm Exam International Trade Economics 6903, Fall 2008 Donald Davis

Keynesian Theory (IS-LM Model): how GDP and interest rates are determined in Short Run with Sticky Prices.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND THE KEYNESIAN CROSS. N. Gregory Mankiw. Working Paper No. 2386

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

Chapter 4. Determination of Income and Employment 4.1 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND ITS COMPONENTS

Online Appendix A to chapter 16

GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS

FDI and endogenous market shares with multiproduct multinational firms

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017]

Taxation, Infrastructure, and Endogenous Trade Costs in New Economic Geography

Characterization of the Optimum

CENTRE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH WORKING PAPER SERIES

GROWING LOCATIONS: INDUSTRY LOCATION IN A MODEL OF ENDOGENOUS GROWTH * Graduate Institute of International Studies, Geneva

1) Real and Nominal exchange rates are highly positively correlated. 2) Real and nominal exchange rates are well approximated by a random walk.

Lecture 12: New Economic Geography

NOT FOR PUBLICATION. Theory Appendix for The China Syndrome. Small Open Economy Model

Partial Equilibrium Model: An Example. ARTNet Capacity Building Workshop for Trade Research Phnom Penh, Cambodia 2-6 June 2008

1 The Goodwin (1967) Model

Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules

Andreas Wagener University of Vienna. Abstract

Discussion Papers. Andreas Haufler and Michael Pflüger. International Commodity Taxation under Monopolistic Competition

Lecture 3: International trade under imperfect competition

Government Spending on Infrastructure in an Endogenous Growth Model with Finite Horizons

UNIT 1 THEORY OF COSUMER BEHAVIOUR: BASIC THEMES

A Thesis. Presented to the Faculty of the Graduate School. of Cornell University. in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of

X. Henry Wang Bill Yang. Abstract

Elasticity of Substitution, Capital Inflow and Government Size

Volume 31, Issue 3. Taylor rules and the effects of debt-financed fiscal policy in a monetary growth model

Multiproduct-Firm Oligopoly: An Aggregative Games Approach

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

Simple Notes on the ISLM Model (The Mundell-Fleming Model)

Lesson-36. Profit Maximization and A Perfectly Competitive Firm

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

The Role of the Most Favored Nation Principle of the GATT/WTO in the New Trade Model

Competition and Growth in an Endogenous Growth Model with Expanding Product Variety without Scale Effects

AGGREGATE DEMAND, AGGREGATE SUPPLY, AND INFLATION. Chapter 25

The Solow Growth Model. Martin Ellison, Hilary Term 2017

3 Department of Mathematics, Imo State University, P. M. B 2000, Owerri, Nigeria.

Internationalization of Production: FDI and. FDI-Outsourcing

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

TAMPERE ECONOMIC WORKING PAPERS NET SERIES

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

Macro II. John Hassler. Spring John Hassler () New Keynesian Model:1 04/17 1 / 10

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INTERNATIONAL WELFARE AND EMPLOYMENT LINKAGES ARISING FROM MINIMUM WAGES. Hartmut Egger Peter Egger James R.

Relative Endowments and the Volume of Trade

Trade Liberalization and Productivity Growth

A Note on Competitive Investment under Uncertainty. Robert S. Pindyck. MIT-CEPR WP August 1991

Computable Name Author General Equilibrium (CGE) Modeling

Trade effects based on general equilibrium

The Effect of Globalization in a Semi Endogenous Growth Model with Firm Heterogeneity, Endogenous International Spillover, and Trade

MORAL HAZARD AND BACKGROUND RISK IN COMPETITIVE INSURANCE MARKETS: THE DISCRETE EFFORT CASE. James A. Ligon * University of Alabama.

Volume 29, Issue 4. A Nominal Theory of the Nominal Rate of Interest and the Price Level: Some Empirical Evidence

Nonlinear Tax Structures and Endogenous Growth

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Switching Costs and the foreign Firm s Entry

Transcription:

Volume 30, Issue 4 A decomposition of the home-market effect Toru Kikuchi Kobe University Ngo van Long McGill University Abstract Although the home-market effect has become one of the most important concepts in both trade theory and the new economic geography, it lacks a compelling graphical representation. The purpose of this note is to offer such a representation. We will decompose the home-market effect into two steps: a short-run response to population shift, creating entry-stimulating excess profits (in the short run) for firms of the country that experiences a population gain, and a further round of entries into the monopolistic sector of the expanding country induced by exits in the foreign industry. We would like to thank an anonymous referee and an associate editor for helpful comments. Citation: Toru Kikuchi and Ngo van Long, (2010) ''A decomposition of the home-market effect'', Economics Bulletin, Vol. 30 no.4 pp. 2759-2768. Submitted: May 06 2010. Published: October 26, 2010.

1 Introduction The monopolistic competition model, characterized by increasing returns and differentiated products, is a major workhorse of the New Trade Theory. Originally conceived by Joan Robinson and Edward Chamberlain in the 1930 s, it became highly useful after the mathematical formulation by Dixit and Stiglitz (1977). In their seminal contributions, Krugman (1980) and Helpman and Krugman (1985, ch. 10.4) demonstrate that under monopolistic competition, country size determines the net trade flows in differentiated products when trade is subject to trade costs. The key idea is what is called the home-market effect: if two countries differ only in size, in the presence of trade costs, the larger country will end up with a more-than-proportional share of the production of differentiated products. 1 The home-market effect has become one of the most important concepts in both trade theory and the new economic geography. 2 Still, it lacks a compelling graphical representation. The purpose of this note is to offer such a representation. We will decompose the home-market effect into two steps: a short-run response to population shift, creating entry-stimulating excess profits (in the short run) for firms of the country that experiences a population gain, and a further round of entries into the monopolistically competitive sector of the expanding country induced by exits in the foreign country. We will emphasize that the second round of entries constitutes the main source of the home-market effect. Our experience indicates that this graphical approach helps the reader to gain, almost effortlessly, a clear 1 In a review of the scientific contribution of Paul Krugman, Neary (2009, p. 233) argues that this was to prove perhaps the most innovative of his contributions. 2 See, for example, Brakman, Garretsen, and van Marrewijk (2009, ch. 1), Combes, Mayer and Thisse (2008, ch. 4), and Feenstra (2004, ch. 5). Applications of economic geography to open-economy macroeconomics include Alesina and Barro (2002). 1

understanding of the home-market effect. The next section presents the basic model. The nature of the trading equilibrium is considered in Section 3, followed by concluding remarks in Section 4. 2 The Model Suppose that there are two countries: Home and Foreign. Home (resp. Foreign) is endowed with L (L ) units of labor, which is the only primary factor of production. The countries have identical technologies. Each country produces two consumption goods, Good X (differentiated products) and Good Y (homogeneous goods). Good Y is sold in a perfectly competitive market, while Good X is sold in a monopolistically competitive market. Good Y is produced under constant returns using only labor; units are chosen such that one unit of labor produces one unit of output. Wage rates are normalized to unity. International trade of Good X incurs iceberg transport costs, meaning that for every τ units of Good X shipped from abroad, only one unit arrives. This raises the price to consumers of an imported variety from p to τp, where p is the mill price and τ > 1 is the transport cost factor. In each country, agents have the following utility function: u = X µ Y 1 µ, 0 < µ < 1, (1) where Y is the consumption of Good Y and X is an aggregator of the consumption of the differentiated products, [ n X = c ρ n ] 1/ρ i + (c i ) ρ, 0 < ρ < 1. (2) i=1 i=1 2

Consumption of each variety is given by c i and σ 1/(1 ρ) > 1 is the elasticity of substitution between every pair of Good X varieties. The price index for Good X (which is dual to the aggregator X) is represented by [ n P X = p ρ/(ρ 1) n ] (ρ 1)/ρ i + (τp i ) ρ/(ρ 1) i=1 i=1 Home consumers demand for a Home product is (3) c = p σ (P X ) σ 1 µl. (4) Similarly, the derived demand (i.e. including units lost by iceberg transport costs) for a Foreign product from Home consumers is c = τ(τp ) σ (P X ) σ 1 µl. (5) The production of a differentiated product involves a constant marginal cost β and α units of labor as a fixed cost. With the total number of products available to consumers being very large, each producer sets its price by applying a constant markup factor on marginal cost p = p = σβ σ 1. (6) Free entry ensures that profit is zero in the long-run, hence the long-run equilibrium output of each variety, x, is a constant, independent of the level of trade costs: x = α (σ 1). (7) β Before moving to the trade equilibrium, it is important to note the entryexit process. If in the short-run, the demand for a differentiated product exceeds the long-run equilibrium output x, there are positive profits, which creates an incentive for new firms to enter the industry. Conversely, if the short-run demand is smaller than x, some firms will exit. This entry-exit process plays an important role in determining the degree of the home-market effect. 3

3 Trade Equilibrium Turning to the trade equilibrium with positive trade costs, the product market equilibrium requires that supply equal demand for each Home product: x = c + c C (8) By substituting (4) for c, the Foreign counterpart of (5) for c, into equation (8) and denoting φ τ 1 σ < 1 we obtain the following aggregate demand for a Home product (C) and its Foreign counterpart (C ): C = µ ( L p n + φn + L ), (9) n + (n /φ) C = µ ( ) L p (n/φ) + n + L. (10) φn + n Figure 1 depicts the relationship between the number of varieties in each country, n and n, and the level of demand for each variety, C and C. Aggregate demands are depicted as the curve CC in panel (a) (i.e., the space n, C), and curve C C in panel (b) (i.e. the space n, C ), respectively. The long-run equilibrium output level x is represented as the intersection of the horizontal line ZZ with the vertical axis. The initial equilibria are depicted by points E and E. Along the curve CC (resp. C C ), we treat n (resp. n) as an exogenous variable. [ C n = µ L p (n + φn ) 2 + φ 2 L ] (φn + n ) 2 < 0, (11) C = µφ [ L n p (n + φn ) 2 + L ] (φn + n ) 2 < 0. (12) Equation (11) implies that the curve CC is decreasing in n, while (12) indicates that the curve CC is shifted downward when there is an increase in n. 4

Now suppose that an exogenous labor movement from Foreign to Home occurs: in Home, the labor force becomes L+ L, while in Foreign, the labor force becomes L L. We can decompose the movement toward the new equilibrium into two steps. Step 1: Firstly, suppose that in the short run, the number of varieties in each country is fixed: The increase in L, combined with the decrease in L, shifts the curve CC is upward (dotted C C ) because φn < n /φ, while the curve C C is shifted downward (dotted C C ). The new shortrun equilibrium is obtained as point E (resp E ). Thus each Home (resp. Foreign) firm experiences an increase (resp. decrease) in demand relative to its long-run output level x. Since the price stays put at βσ/(σ 1) while average fixed cost falls in Home, profit rises for each home firm. Similarly, profit falls for each foreign firm. These changes trigger the entry of new firms in Home, while exits begin to occur in Foreign, which are shown as arrows in each panel. (If exits did not occur in Foreign, the new equilibrium number of Home firm would be indicated by the intersection of the dotted C C curve and the line ZZ.) It is important to note that this curve shifting does not exhibit the home-market effect: since the initial shift of CC is proportional to the increase in L, it only increases n proportionally. Step 2: The above entry-exit process gives rise to a second round of curve shifting, and thus a second round of entries and exits. C C is shifted further up by a reduction in n (to C C ), while C C is shifted further down by an increase in n (to C C ). Thus the new long-run equilibrium is obtained as the point E (for Home) and E (for Foreign). It is important to note that the second round constitutes the main source of the home-market effect. Expenditure shifting between countries triggers an entry-exit process in each country, which reinforces the first entry-exit process. 5

Proposition 1 (Krugman): If two countries differ only in terms of size, the larger country will end up with a more-than-proportional share of world output of differentiated products. Finally, we can point to the home-market magnification. Freer trade magnifies the degree of relocation that comes from a given shift of population. 3 In other words, industry becomes more footloose, not less footloose, as trade gets freer. 4 Concluding Remarks We have decomposed the home market effect into two steps: a short-run response to population shift, creating entry-stimulating excess profits (in the short run) for firms of the country that experiences a population gain, and a further round of entries into the monopolistic sector of the expanding country induced by exits in the foreign industry. Our diagrammatic representation illustrates the process in an intuitive way. 4 A similar diagrammatic approach can be used to show how freer trade magnifies the home-market effect. 3 This is because freeing up trade makes the impact of n on C makes bigger. Thus, the same change in L would result in a higher degree of relocation [Baldwin et al. (2003)]. In the case of free trade (i.e., φ = 1), however, this home-market magnification vanishes. We would like to thank an anonymous referee for pointing this out. 4 Davis (1998) has shown that the home market effect can be reversed if there is a transport costs for the homogeneous good that is larger than for the differentiated goods. Since our diagrammatic representation concentrates on the case of no transportation costs for the homogeneous goods (i.e., factor price equalization between countries), it is difficult to show Davis case by using this approach. 6

References [1] Alesina, Alberto. and Robert J. Barro (2002) Currency Unions, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117 (2), pp 409-436. [2] Baldwin, Richard, Rikard Forslid, Philippe Martin, Gianmarco Ottaviano, and Frederic Robert-Nicoud (2003) Economic Geography and Public Policy, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. [3] Brakman, Steven, Harry Garretsen, and Charles van Marrewijk (2009) The New Introduction to Geographical Economics, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. [4] Combes, Pierre-Philippe, Thierry Mayer, and Jacques-Francois Thisse (2008) Economic Geography: The Integration of Regions and Nations, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. [5] Davis, Donald (1998) The Home Market, Trade and Industrial Structure, American Economic Review, Vol. 88, pp. 1264 1276. [6] Dixit, Avinash K., and Joseph Stiglitz (1977) Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity, American Economic Review, Vol. 67, pp. 297 308. [7] Feenstra, Robert C. (2004) Advanced International Trade: Theory and Evidence, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. [8] Helpman, Elhanan and Paul Krugman (1985) Market Structure and Foreign Trade, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. [9] Krugman, Paul (1980) Scale Economies, Product Differentiation, and the Pattern of Trade, American Economic Review, Vol. 70, pp. 950 959. 7

[10] Neary, J. Peter (2009) Putting the New into New Trade Theory: Paul Krugman s Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol. 111, pp. 217 250. 8

Figure 1 (b) C* C* C* C C C C E (a) Z E* E* E* E E Z C n* C* C* C* C C n