Trading Company and Indirect Exports

Similar documents
Trading Company and Indirect Exports

FDI Spillovers and Intellectual Property Rights

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

Firm Productivity and Exports in the Wholesale Sector: Evidence from Japan

Endogenous FDI Spillovers: Do You Want to Keep Your Recipe to Yourself?

FDI with Reverse Imports and Hollowing Out

Lecture 6 Dynamic games with imperfect information

Long run equilibria in an asymmetric oligopoly

Trade Liberalization and Labor Unions

HW Consider the following game:

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9

Noncooperative Oligopoly

Pass-Through Pricing on Production Chains

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Second Midterm Examination Answers

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Maximin and minimax strategies in asymmetric duopoly: Cournot and Bertrand

Price discrimination in asymmetric Cournot oligopoly

Endogenous Transaction Cost, Specialization, and Strategic Alliance

A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition. Markus Reisinger & Monika Schnitzer University of Munich University of Munich

ANSWERS FINAL 342 VERSION 1

Volume 29, Issue 1. Second-mover advantage under strategic subsidy policy in a third market model

Simon Fraser University Department of Economics. Econ342: International Trade. Final Examination. Instructor: N. Schmitt

Pure Strategies and Undeclared Labour in Unionized Oligopoly

Volume 29, Issue 2. Equilibrium Location and Economic Welfare in Delivered Pricing Oligopoly

Strategic Trade Policy under Isoelastic Demand and Asymmetric Production Costs

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Relative Performance and Stability of Collusive Behavior

In Class Exercises. Problem 1

Export subsidies, countervailing duties, and welfare

Regional restriction, strategic commitment, and welfare

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I

Location, Productivity, and Trade

Profit Share and Partner Choice in International Joint Ventures

Follower Payoffs in Symmetric Duopoly Games

Switching Costs and the foreign Firm s Entry

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Profitable Mergers. in Cournot and Stackelberg Markets:

Endogenous choice of decision variables

Resource Allocation and Decision Analysis (ECON 8010) Spring 2014 Foundations of Decision Analysis

research paper series

Econ 711 Homework 1 Solutions

Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies?

Public Schemes for Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets

Analysis of a highly migratory fish stocks fishery: a game theoretic approach

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński

TEACHING STICKY PRICES TO UNDERGRADUATES

Simon Fraser University Department of Economics. Econ342: International Trade. Final Examination. Instructor: N. Schmitt

Perfect competition and intra-industry trade

What Industry Should We Privatize?: Mixed Oligopoly and Externality

VERTICAL RELATIONS AND DOWNSTREAM MARKET POWER by. Ioannis Pinopoulos 1. May, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract

Equilibrium Audit Strategies Against Tax Treaty Shopping

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Econ 8602, Fall 2017 Homework 2

An Economic Analysis of the Special Milk Classes Scheme of Canada and the Agricultural Subsidy

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 26, Lecture 28. Oligopoly

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

Endogenous Price Leadership and Technological Differences

Game Theory Fall 2003

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications Final Exam Ronaldo Carpio Jan. 13, 2015

Strategic Choice of Channel Structure in an Oligopoly

Quota bonuses in a principle-agent setting

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Outsourcing under Incomplete Information

Mixed Motives of Simultaneous-move Games in a Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

MORAL HAZARD AND BACKGROUND RISK IN COMPETITIVE INSURANCE MARKETS: THE DISCRETE EFFORT CASE. James A. Ligon * University of Alabama.

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. August 2010

SHORTER PAPERS. Tariffs versus Quotas under Market Price Uncertainty. Hung-Yi Chen and Hong Hwang. 1 Introduction

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES EXPORT-PLATFORM FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT. Karolina Ekholm Rikard Forslid James R. Markusen

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

Privatization and government preference. Abstract

Export performance requirements under international duopoly*

is the best response of firm 1 to the quantity chosen by firm 2. Firm 2 s problem: Max Π 2 = q 2 (a b(q 1 + q 2 )) cq 2

Symmetric Game. In animal behaviour a typical realization involves two parents balancing their individual investment in the common

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Econ 601 Prof. James Peck Extra Practice Problems Answers (for final)

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

Optimal Trade Policies for Exporting Countries under the Stackelberg Type of Competition between Firms

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Strategic Production Game 1

Chapter 2 Equilibrium and Efficiency

Econ 101A Final exam Th 15 December. Do not turn the page until instructed to.

How to Supply Safer Food: A Strategic Trade Policy Point of View

The Timing of Endogenous Wage Setting under Bertrand Competition in a Unionized Mixed Duopoly

Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment

Foreign direct investment and export under imperfectly competitive host-country input market

Microeconomics III. Oligopoly prefacetogametheory (Mar 11, 2012) School of Economics The Interdisciplinary Center (IDC), Herzliya

Transcription:

Trading Company and Indirect Exports Kiyoshi atsubara August 0 Abstract This article develops an oligopoly model of trade intermediation. In the model, two manufacturing firms that want to export their products cannot do so by themselves at the beginning, because of lack of distribution network or other necessary facilities for exporting. It is assumed that they have two choices: () paying a fixed cost to be able to conduct exporting by themselves (direct exports), or () paying a commission fee to a trading company to use its trade intermediation (indirect exports). After choosing their ways of exports, they compete in quantity in the foreign market. This article shows the following. (i) In the benchmark case (symmetric manufacturers with zero production costs), depending on the fixed costs and the commission fee, the choices of the two firms may be threefold: (Case ) both choose indirect exports, (Case : asymmetric choices) one chooses indirect while the other chooses direct exports (the two firms are identical though), or (Case ) both choose direct exports. However, the trading company always prefer Case and set its commission fee to let the two manufacturers choose indirect exports. (ii) In the asymmetric production-cost case (firm s marginal cost is zero while firm s is positive), Case in the benchmark case bifurcates. That is, indirect exports by firm or firm and direct exports by firm or firm. In the previous literature, the case when the both manufacturing firms choose indirect exports, which is likely in the model, is not. JEL Classification: F Keywords: trade intermediation, fixed costs of direct exports, commission fee for indirect exports College of Commerce, Nihon University. ailing Address: 5-- Kinuta, Setagaya, Tokyo 57-8570 Japan. Phone and Fax: +8--7-6868. E-mail: matsubara.kiyoshi@nihon-u.ac.jp

Introduction Wholesalers have an important role in international trade. For instance, manufacturing firms trying to enter foreign markets do not have necessary facilities such as distribution network or knowledge about the foreign markets at the beginning. By utilizing trade-intermediation services provided by wholesalers, such manufacturers may save possible fixed costs of foreign entry. To my knowledge, the previous theoretical studies of trade intermediation have built variants of the heterogeneous-firm trade model a la elitz (00) with a trade-intermediation industry in which wholesalers are homogeneous and that is free entry (AFN, Khandelwal, and Wei 0, Akerman 0, for instance). These studies show that manufacturers with intermediate productivity levels use trade intermediation, while those with high productivity levels do not. However, Some studies show that shows that wholesalers are heterogeneous and concentrated in Japan, US, and some EU countries (see Rauch 6 and Tanaka 0 about Japan). Therefore, considering some strategic interaction between manufacturers and wholesaler(s) may help us understand more about the role of wholesalers in international trade, which is the motivation for this study. This article develops an oligopoly model of trade intermediation. In the model, two manufacturing firms that want to export their products cannot do so by themselves at the beginning, because of lack of distribution network or other necessary facilities for exporting. It is assumed that they have two choices: () paying a fixed cost to be able to conduct exporting by themselves (direct exports), or () paying a commission fee to a trading company to use its trade intermediation (indirect exports). After choosing their ways of exports, they compete in quantity in the foreign market. This article shows the following. (i) In the benchmark case (symmetric manufacturers with zero production costs), depending on the fixed costs and the commission fee, the choices of the two firms may be threefold: (Case ) both choose indirect exports, (Case : asymmetric choices) one chooses indirect while the other chooses direct exports (the two firms are identical though), or (Case ) both choose direct exports. However, the trading company always prefer Case and set its commission fee to let the two manufacturers choose indirect exports. (ii) In the asymmetric production-cost case (firm s marginal cost is zero while firm s is positive), Case in the benchmark case bifurcates. That is, indirect exports by firm or firm and direct exports by firm or firm. In the previous literature, the case when the both manufacturing firms choose indirect exports, which is likely in the model, is not. This paper is arranged as follows. In section two, the basic setup of the model and the benchmark case are described. In section three, heterogeneity among the manufacturing firms are introduced. Section four summarizes the results and show remaining issues this paper should discuss.

odel In this section, the basic setup of the model is described. Suppose that two manufacturing firms, and, exist in a country and both of them plan to enter the market of a foreign country. For the manufacturers, two ways of entry are available. One way is direct exports, i.e. paying fixed costs of exports, f, and then exporting their products by themselves. The other way is indirect exports, i.e. utilizing an exporting service provided by a trading company, T. If either firms or choose indirect exports, they have to pay per-unit commission fee, c T to the trading company, but they can save the fixed costs of exports, necessary with direct exports. Decisions of the two manufacturers and trading company are described by the following three-stage game: in stage one, the trading company determines the level of c T. In stage two, firms and choose one of the two ways of exports. In stage three, firms and compete in quantity in the foreign market, which has no incumbent firms. First, as a benchmark, a case of symmetric manufacturing firms is discussed. Then, the model is extended to the asymmetric case.. Benchmark: Symmetric anufacturers Suppose that the inverse demand function of the foreign market is p(x, x ) = (x + x ) where p is the price and x i is the quantity produced by firm i (i =, ). For simplicity, either production or shipping costs are assumed to be zero. Firm i s profits in each of the two exporting modes are as follows: πi IX = {p(x, x ) c T }x i, πi DX = p(x, x )x i f, i =,. where IX (DX) denotes (in)direct exports respectively. About the profits of the trading company, three cases might occur. Cases and are symmetric about two firms s choices of exporting mode, while Case is asymmetric. π T = c T (x + x ) if firms and choose IX (Case ), c T x i if firms i chooses IX and if firm j chooses DX (i j) (Case ), 0 if firms and choose DX (Case ). The model is solved by backward induction... Stage Three: anufacturers s Decision In Case, when both firms and choose indirect exports, their optimal quantity and profits are: x IX i = x IX = c T, i =,. () ( ) πi IX = (x IX ) ct =. ()

In Case, when both firms and choose direct exports, their optimal quantity and profits are: x DX i = x DX =, i =, () π DX i = (x DX ) f = f. () Because of non-negative profits, f is assumed. In Case, when firm chooses indirect exports and firm chooses direct exports respectively, their optimal quantity and profits are: x IX = c T π IX = (x IX ) = x DX = + c T π DX = (x DX ) =, (5) ( ) ct, (6), (7) ( ) + ct f. (8) Table is the payoff matrix of the subgame by the two manufacturers. In each of the four boxes of the matrix, the first number is the profits of firm, and the second number is the those of firm. The northwest box is Case, when both firms choose indirect exports. while the southeast box is Case, when both firms choose direct exports. The northeast and southwest boxes are Case, when one firm chooses indirect exports and the other chooses direct exports. Which case is the equilibrium depends on the fixed costs of direct exports, f, and the commission fee charged by the trading company, c T. On the plane of (f, c T ), Figure shows which case occurs with a given pair of these two variables. If c T f, Case is the equilibrium of the subgame. This inequality implies that firm i prefers indirect exports if firm j s strategy is indirect exports. In order for Case to be the equilibrium of the subgame, another condition under which firm i prefers indirect exports if firm j s strategy is direct exports is needed. It is c T < f. However, as Figure implies, if the first inequality holds, the second one also holds. In Figure, the straight line is a tangent line for the curve at the origin. If c T > f, Case is the equilibrium of the subgame. As Figure shows, Case is likely to occur when f is small and c T is large at the same time, which is another polar case besides Case (large f and small c T ). Finally, if f < c T f, Case is the equilibrium of the subgame. Case is between Cases and, as Figure shows... Stages Two and One: Trading Company s Decision The trading company determines the level of its commission fee based on the subgame of the two manufacturing firms discussed above. First, in Case, the profits

( ) of the trading company is c ct T. The level of commission fee maximizing these profits is. However, the trading company cannot choose this value. The border of Case is the straight line c T = f. Also, f is assumed. These two things implies that the maximum value of c T that the trading company can choose is. With c T =, the profits of the trading company is. ore generally, 8 with c T = f, the profits of the trading company in Case are πt Case = f ( f ) = f 7(f ). 8 Note that πt Case increases as f increases for 0 f. How about other two cases? Obviously, the trading company does not choose any level of the commission fee satisfying c T > f, because in Case, its ( ) profits are zero. In Case, its profits are c ct T, whose maximum is with c T =. Whether the trading company can charge this level of the commission fee depends on f. For a given level of f, the maximum level of c T that the trading company can charge is f, which is the upper limit of Case region in Figure. It is shown that if f, then f. Therefore, with Case, the trading company s profits are as follows: πt Case = if f f f if 0 f 6 < To show which case, Cases or, the trading company should choose, the profits of the two cases are compared. Two steps are taken. First, suppose that for 0 f <, the profits in Case are larger than those in Case. If this inequality holds, then the following inequality also holds. f > f. Note that both sides are decreasing functions of f. and they are equal to when f = 0. When f = 6, the left hand side is equal to while the right hand side 6 is equal to, so the former is larger than the latter. By taking derivatives of the both sides with respect to f, it is shown that for any 0 f <, the left hand side is larger than the right hand side, because the absolute value of the derivative of the right hand side is always larger than that of the left hand side. Therefore, the above inequality holds. Next, if f, the profit in Case is. The profits in Case is equal to when f = <. Because the profits in Case is an increasing function of f, if f, they are always larger than. Thus, πt Case > πt Case for any 0 f. Therefore, the trading company always chooses c T = f and Case is realized. The benchmark case shows that the trading company sets the level of commission fee by considering the level of the fixed costs of direct exports for the manufacturing firms as described above. By doing so, the trading company can

let the two manufacturers choose indirect exports for any level of f. However, in the benchmark case, the manufacturers are homogeneous. Therefore, the effect of heterogeneity among manufacturing firms in terms of production costs is not examined, which is the focus in the next section. Asymmetric anufacturing Firms Now, asymmetric production costs are introduced. Suppose that firm can produce its products by no costs while firm pays a constant marginal cost of c. Since the main focus of this section is the effect of marginal-cost heterogeneity among manufacturers, the fixed costs of direct exports f are assumed to be the same between firms and. With this production-cost asymmetry, the following four cases are analyzed: Case : both manufacturing firms choose indirect exports. Case : Firm (zero C) chooses indirect exports while firm (positive C) chooses direct exports. Case : Firm chooses direct exports while firm chooses indirect exports. Case : both manufacturing firms choose direct exports. Note that Cases and together correspond to Case in the benchmark case. Because of the marginal-cost difference, Cases and have different quantity produced by each of the two manufacturers and thus different profits. As in the benchmark case, optimal quantities produced by the two manufacturing firms and resulting profits are examined first. Then, trading company s decision is Analise.. Profits of anufacturers in the Four Cases Profits of the two manufacturing firms in each of the four cases are as follows: Case Case π Case = π Case = ( ) + c c T, ( ) c c T. π Case = π Case = ( ) + c c T, ( ) c + c T f. 5

Case Case π Case = π Case = ( ) + c + c T f, ( ) c c T. π Case = π Case = ( ) + c f, ( ) c f. It is assumed that f ( c ) to make the outputs and profits of both firms in cases to nonnegative. Also, c < is assumed, because this inequality is needed for the profits of firm in cases of and to be positive. Before examining manufacturers s behavior further, let us make sure which case is the best for the trading company. The profits of the trading company in the four cases are as follows: c T (x + x ) in case, c π T = T x in case, c T x in case, 0 in case. Note that the profits of the trading company in Case are different than those in Case. In Case, firm pays the commission fee of indirect exports to the trading company, while in Case, firm does it. As mentioned before, the quantities produced by firms and are different because of different levels of marginal costs... Equilibrium of the Stage-Three Subgame Table is the payoff matrix of the subgame by the two manufacturers. The northwest box is Case, when both firms choose indirect exports. while the southeast box is Case, when both firms choose direct exports. The northeast box is Case, when firm chooses indirect exports and chooses direct exports. Finally, the southwest box is Case, when firm chooses direct exports and firm chooses indirect exports. Which case is the equilibrium depends on the fixed costs of direct exports, f, and the commission fee charged by the trading company, c T. Besides these two variables, the marginal cost of firm, c also plays an important role, as Figure shows. On the plane of (f, c T ), Figure shows which case occurs with a given pair of these two variables. Note that the dotted straight line, the dotted curve, and the dotted vertical line were all solid in Figure. Therefore, by introducing the marginal-cost asymmetry, both the straight line and curve bifurcate, and the vertical line is shifted leftward. In the result, the regions of Case and Case 6

(Case in the symmetric production-cost case) get smaller. About asymmetric cases, Cases and, whether the whole region is expanded is not obvious due to the leftward shift of the vertical line. However, for 0 f ( ) c, the region of asymmetric cases is expanded (between two lines c T = f and (+c ) c T = ( c ) ( c ) f ). The region of Case, when firm chooses direct exports and firm chooses indirect exports, is the whole region of the asymmetric cases. On the other hand, the region of Case, when firm chooses indirect exports and firm chooses direct exports, is between other two lines, c T = f ( c ) and c T = (+c ) (+c ) f, which implies that Case is less likely than Case... Stages Two and One: Trading Company s Decision As in the symmetric production-cost case, the trading company determines the level of its commission fee based on the subgame of the two manufacturing ( firms discussed above. First, in Case, the profits of the trading company is c c c T T. ) The level of commission fee maximizing these profits is c. However, the trading company cannot choose this value. The border of Case is the straight line c T = f. Also, f (+c ) ( ) c is assumed. These two things imply that the maximum value of c T that the trading company can choose is ( c ), which is (+c ) lower than c. ore generally, with c T = f (+c, the profits of the trading ) ( ) f company in Case are (+c ) c f (+c ) = (6 c )f (+c 7f ) 8(+c. ) How about other two cases? Obviously, the trading company does not choose any level of the commission fee satisfying c T > ( c ) ( c ) f, because ( ) in Case, its profits are zero. In Case, its profits are c +c c T T, whose maximum is (+c ) with c T = +c. Whether the trading company can charge this level of the commission fee depends on f. For a given level of f, the maximum level of c T that the trading company can charge is (+c ) (+c ) f, which is the upper limit of Case region in Figure. It is shown that if f, 8 then ( f. Therefore, with Case, the trading company s profits are as follows: πt Case = if (+c ) f ( ) c (+c ) f } if 0 f 6 < (+c ) (+c ) f (+c ){(+c ) Note that in order for (+c ) < ( ) c, c must be equal to or smaller than 6. Otherwise, the first line of the profits in Case disappears and only the second line is left (now it is for 0 f ( ) c. Also, For the profits in Case, a similar formula can be used by replacing + c with c. 7

As in the symmetric production-cost case, the profits in Cases,, and should be compared to show which case is the best for the trading company, and how the best choice is affected by the level of c. However, the formulae of the profits of these three cases are so complicated that deriving some results analytically is not sure at this point. Conclusion This article develops an oligopoly model of trade intermediation and shows the following. (i) In the benchmark case (symmetric manufacturers with zero production costs), depending on the fixed costs and the commission fee, the choices of the two firms may be threefold: (Case ) both choose indirect exports, (Case : asymmetric choices) one chooses indirect while the other chooses direct exports (the two firms are identical though), or (Case ) both choose direct exports. However, the trading company always prefer Case and set its commission fee to let the two manufacturers choose indirect exports. (ii) In the asymmetric production-cost case (firm s marginal cost is zero while firm s is positive), Case in the benchmark case bifurcates. That is, indirect exports by firm or firm and direct exports by firm or firm. In the previous literature, the case when the both manufacturing firms choose indirect exports, which is likely in the model, is not. However, many issues are not solved yet. First of all, in the asymmetric production-cost case, the decision of the trading company is not clear. Whether asymmetric exporting-mode choices (Cases and ) may be equilibria should be resolved. Second, by exchanging stages and /, checking the robustness may be possible. Finally, welfare analysis is necessary to draw policy implications. References [] Ahn, JaeBin, Amit K. Khandelwal, and Shang-Jin Wei, The Role of Intermediaries in Facilitating Trade. Journal of International Economics, 8() (ay 0): 7-85. [] Akerman, Anders, Wholesalers and Economies of Scope in International Trade. Research Papers in Economics, Department of Economics, Stockholm University 00:. available at http://people.su.se/ ank/. [] elitz,., The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity, Econometrica, 7(6) (00), 65-75. [] Rauch, James E., Trade and Search: Social Capital, Sogo Shosha, and Spillovers. NBER Working Paper 568 (June 6). [5] Tanaka, Ayumu, Firm Productivity and Exports in the Wholesale Sector: Evidence from Japan. RIETI Discussion Paper Series -E-007 (February 0). 8

Firms Firm Exporting mode IX DX Firm IX c T, c T c T, c T f DX c T f, c T f, f Table : Payoff matrix in stage (quantity competition between firms and ). ct c T Case Case c T f Case 0 f Figure : Fixed costs of direct exports, commission fee, and manufacturers s optimal choices.

Firms Firm Firm Exporting mode IX DX IX c c T, c c T c c T f, c c T DX c c T, c c T f c f, c f Table : Payoff matrix in stage with different marginal costs of production. ct c T c T c T Case Case Case c T c T f c T 0 Case f Figure : Fixed costs of direct exports, commission fee, and manufacturers s optimal choices under asymmetric marginal costs of production. 0