Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

Similar documents
EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #9 - Monopoly

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

1. If the consumer has income y then the budget constraint is. x + F (q) y. where is a variable taking the values 0 or 1, representing the cases not

2 Maximizing pro ts when marginal costs are increasing

ECON Micro Foundations

Some Notes on Timing in Games

Problem Set 2 Answers

Problem Set 1 Answer Key. I. Short Problems 1. Check whether the following three functions represent the same underlying preferences

EconS Industrial Organization Assignment 6 Homework Solutions

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

Answer: Let y 2 denote rm 2 s output of food and L 2 denote rm 2 s labor input (so

Economic Growth and Development : Exam. Consider the model by Barro (1990). The production function takes the

EconS Constrained Consumer Choice

EconS Games with Incomplete Information II and Auction Theory

Asymmetries, Passive Partial Ownership Holdings, and Product Innovation

1 Consumer Choice. 2 Consumer Preferences. 2.1 Properties of Consumer Preferences. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 4 of the text.

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice

2. Find the equilibrium price and quantity in this market.

Simple e ciency-wage model

Strategic Pre-Commitment

Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Econ Homework 4 - Answers ECONOMIC APPLICATIONS OF CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION. 1. Assume that a rm produces product x using k and l, where

1 Unemployment Insurance

Advertising and entry deterrence: how the size of the market matters

For on-line Publication Only ON-LINE APPENDIX FOR. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market. June 2017

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems III

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

Lecture 7 - Locational equilibrium continued

Opting out of publicly provided services: A majority voting result

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #7 - Competitive Markets

Introduction to Economic Analysis Fall 2009 Problems on Chapter 3: Savings and growth

Optimal Acquisition Strategies in Unknown Territories

Economics 326: Pro t Maximization and Production. Ethan Kaplan

1 Two Period Production Economy

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Second Midterm Examination Answers

Econ 302 Assignment 3 Solution. a 2bQ c = 0, which is the monopolist s optimal quantity; the associated price is. P (Q) = a b

Advanced Microeconomic Theory EC104

Switching Costs, Relationship Marketing and Dynamic Price Competition

Product Di erentiation. We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade.

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime Chang and Velasco JET 2000 and NBER 6469

1 Multiple Choice (30 points)

EconS Substitution E ects

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

Credit Card Competition and Naive Hyperbolic Consumers

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2011 Examination. 2010/2011 Syllabus ONLY

Universidad Carlos III de Madrid May Microeconomics Grade

False_ The average revenue of a firm can be increasing in the firm s output.

Technical Appendix to Long-Term Contracts under the Threat of Supplier Default

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Characterization of the Optimum

1 Supply and Demand. 1.1 Demand. Price. Quantity. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 2 of the text.

Dynamic games with incomplete information

UCLA Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Exam Micro-Economic Theory

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model

Auction Theory - An Introduction

EconS Cost Functions

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

Search, Welfare and the Hot Potato E ect of In ation

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

Quantity Competition vs. Price Competition under Optimal Subsidy in a Mixed Duopoly. Marcella Scrimitore. EERI Research Paper Series No 15/2012

Microeconomics I - Midterm

Francesco Nava Microeconomic Principles II EC202 Lent Term 2010

EconS Firm Optimization

Jung Hur and Yohanes E. Riyanto

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Econ 805 Homework #3 Answers

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Downstream R&D, raising rival s costs, and input price contracts: a comment on the role of spillovers

EconS Oligopoly - Part 3

The Role of Physical Capital

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Comprehensive Exam

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY MIDTERM EXAM #2 ANSWER KEY

Models of Wage-setting.. January 15, 2010

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

Alternative Central Bank Credit Policies for Liquidity Provision in a Model of Payments

Growth and Welfare Maximization in Models of Public Finance and Endogenous Growth

Problem Set # Public Economics

Liquidity, Asset Price and Banking

Upward Pricing Pressure formulations with logit demand and endogenous partial acquisitions

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Solutions to Problem Set # 2

1 The Solow Growth Model

Pharmaceutical Patenting in Developing Countries and R&D

N-Player Preemption Games

Problem 3 Solutions. l 3 r, 1

Customer Lock-In With Long-Term Contracts

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati.

Exercises on chapter 4

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

Transcription:

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part Sotiris Georganas Royal Holloway University of London January 00 Problem Consider Hotelling s linear city with endogenous prices and exogenous and locations. Suppose, however, that there is only one rm, and that this monopolist is (exogenously) located at the left end point of the interval (y = 0). Assume that the consumers transportation costs are quadratic, (x y), where > 0 is a parameter, x is the location of the consumer, and y is the location of the rm from which she buys. Also, allow for the possibility that some consumers may prefer not to buy at all (which yields zero utility). Solve for the optimal monopoly price in this model assuming zero production costs. Solution Problem We thus have only one rm, located at y = 0. Consumers are assumed to be uniformly distributed over the unit interval. The timing of the game is. The rm chooses a price.. Each consumer chooses whether to buy or not. Since the game is dynamic we will use bacward induction to solve for a subgame perfect equilibrium. In the rst step hence tae the rm s price p as given an consider the problem faced by the consumers. The problem faced by any given consumer is whether or not to buy from the rm. When we solve this problem for all consumers, and for a generic price p, we thus trace out the rms demand function. Since the consumers are identical except for their locations, and moreover, the transportation cost increases in distance from the producer, there will be some consumer (location), denoted x, who is indi erent between buying and not buying. Everyone to the left of x will buy, while everyone to the right of x will not. When solving for x we

have to be a bit care, however, since it may be that we have a corner solution where either all consumers buy (x > ) or no consumers buy. The utility to consumer x from buying the good is U ( ; 0) = x p : In contrast, a consumer with location x gets zero utility if not buying. Hence for the indi erent consumer x we have that x p = 0: Solving for x, we have r x = However, as noted above, we need to be a bit careful since this expression is only valid when the resulting cuto point is in the unit interval. It is thus only valid for prices p. To see this, note that if p, then not even the consumer at that is at the rm s location, i.e. x = 0, will want to buy; hence at such a high price demand is zero. Conversely, if the price is p <, then even the most distant consumer (at x = ) will strictly prefer to buy, implying that demand is equal to one. Since the consumers are uniformly distributed over the unit interval, the demand for the rm s product is thus r D (p ) = x = Having derived this demand function, we can now consider the rm s price setting problem. Since the cost of production is zero, the rm s pro ts are p : p : (p ) = p D (p ) = p r p : The rst order condition satis ed by the optimal price is p p p = 0:

Solving the rst order condition yields p = p p = p, ( p ) = p, p, p = 3 Plugging the optimal price bac into the expression for the pro ts yields that = p = 3 3 (3) p = 3 3 Given that > 0 and > 0 this expression is strictly positive. However, this optimal pro t was derived under the assumption that the indi erent type x was interior, i.e. within the unit interval, and hence only valid if p : Clearly p < (since it is a fraction of ). This tells us that the rm is, trivially, better o setting a price that induces some consumers to buy, i.e. p would not be optimal. However, we also need to consider the possibility that it might be optimal to set a price that is low enough that all consumers buy. What are the highest possibly pro ts for the rm when all consumers buy? Clearly, this is achieved by setting bp = buy). Pro ts are then (since this is the highest price at which all consumers b = bp = : When does inducing all consumers to buy generate the highest pro ts? It will do so when the unconstrained price p that we derived above is lower than bp, i.e. when p = 3 < = bp or, equivalently, when < 3 : 3

Another way of seeing this it to thin about the price setting problem as a constrained optimization problem, max (p ) p In this formulation, and nowing that the pro t function (p ) is a concave function, checing whether setting the price at the lower bound is optimal involves checing whether the derivative of (p ) with respect to p, when evaluated at p = or negative. If it is positive, then the optimal price is larger than negative, the optimal price is. Recall that the derivative is, is positive, while if it is 0 (p ) = p p p Hence evaluating at p = yields 0 (p = ) = = ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) The derivate of pro ts, evaluated at the lower bound of prices, is thus positive if > 3 and negative at < 3. Hence we conclude that, if > =3 then, at the optimum, the monopolist does not sell to all consumers and sets the optimal price p = (=3), while if =3, it sells to all consumers and sets the optimal price p = : Problem Consider a Hotelling model with two rms: rm is located at y = 0, and rm is located at y =. Consumers are uniformly distributed along the interval [0; ]. Each consumer wishes to buy at most one unit. The utility of a consumer located at x is p x if he buys from rm, p ( x) if he buys from rm, and 0 if he buys from neither rm. i represents the qualities of the products o ered by rm i, while p i is the price set by rm i. is a positive 4

constant. For simplicity, assume that the two rms have zero production costs and that they compete by simultaneously setting prices. (a) Given p and p, compute the location of the consumer who is just indi erent between the two rms (suppose that the maret is covered). Explain the intuition of the expression you got. (b) Given your answer in (a), write the pro t maximization problem of each rm. Solve the problem and derive the best-response function of each rm. Show the two bestresponse functions in a graph that has p on the horizontal axis and p on the vertical axis, assuming = and =. Solve for the equilibrium set of prices given that =. (c) Suppose that rm increases by an amount a > 0 by investing in quality (so that = + a). What is the resulting change in the best response functions of the two rms? Illustrate your answer with a gure and explain the intuition for the resulting changes. Compute the equilibrium prices after the increase in quality by rm. (d) Is the strategic e ect of the increase in bene cial or harmful for rm? Would rm be more inclined or less inclined to invest relative to the case where it does not engage in price competition with rm? Explain your answer. (See CW, p. 53 for a general discussion of strategic e ects.) Solution Problem (a) The location of the indi erent consumer, denoted x, is given by the solution to the following equation, p x = p ( x) or ( x) x = + p p (rearrange) x = + p p (simplify l.h.s) x = p + p (multiplying by -) or, nally solving, x = + p + p 5

This expression is the demand for rm while x is the demand for rm. If rms and o ers pacages that have the same quality and price, then the each rm captures half of the maret. Firm i can capture more than half of the maret by either o ering a lower price or by o ering a higher quality. and (b) De ne the demand function for each rm D (p ; p ; ; ) = x = + p + p D (p ; p ; ; ) = x = + p + p Since production costs are zero, the pro ts for rm i is simply its revenue p i D i. Hence, in a Nash price-setting equilibrium, rm chooses p, given p, so as to maximize p D = p + p + p : The rst order condition for this problem is @D D + p = 0 @p + p + p p = 0 + ( ) + p Hence, solving for the best response p, yields p (p ; ; ) = + ( ) p + p = 0 By a similar calculation, we obtain that the best price-response by rm is p (p ; ; ) = + ( ) + p Inspecting the best-response function p (p ; ; ) ; we see rm s chosen price increases by 0.5 for every increase in p. Hence in terms of a graph that has p and p on the horizontal and vertical axis respectively, the slope of p (p ; ; ) is. By the same argument, the slope of p (p ; ; ) is /. The following graph illustrates the case where = and =. 6

3.5 p.5 0.5 0 0.5.5.5 3 p With = the best response functions simplify to p (p ; ; ) = + p p (p ; ; ) = + p and it is easy to see that the unique price equilibrium is the symmetric outcome p = p = : (c) Suppose that rm increases the quality of its product so that = + a, for some a > 0. The best-response functions are now p (p ; ; ) = + a + p p (p ; ; ) = a + p Hence, relative to the initial situation, the best price-response by rm has increased by a= while that of rm has decreased by a=. The following gure illustrate the case where a = =. 3.5 p.5 0.5 0 0.5.5.5 3 p 7

In intuitive terms, when rm raises than its best-response function shifts outward because it is optimal for rm to raise p for each value of p. This is since rm s product is now of superior quality, so rm can exploit the higher willingness of its customers to pay by charging them higher prices. The best-response function of rm, however, decreases in the sense that now rm would lie to set a lower price p for each value of p. The reason for that is that the increase in has shifted some customers away from rm to rm due to the increase in the quality by rm. Hence, in order to regain some customers, rm will want to drop its price. The new equilibrium entails a lower price by rm. With a = =; the new (asymmetric) price equilibrium is the pair (p ; p ) the solve the two-equation system p = + a + p p = a + p Using the rst equation to substitute for p in the second yields the following equation in p p = a + + a + p Simplifying (collecting constants) and solving yields p = rst equation then yields p = + a + a = + a 3 3 a=3. Plugging this into the Hence with the quality gap = a, the new equilibrium prices are (p ; p ) = + a 3 ; a 3 (which obviously generalize the case where a = 0). (d) Recall from CW the notion of a strategic e ect. Consider two rms and and a two-stage situation; in the rst stage rm can mae an investment a, and in the second stage the two rms compete e.g. in prices (or alternatively in quantities). Pro ts for rm can generally be written as = (p ; p ; a) : Using that the outcome of the price 8

competition will depend on the level of the investment, i.e. p i = p i (a), the incentives to invest can be written as @ @a + @ @p @p @a + @ @p @p @a The rst term is the direct e ect in the current example the increase in quality by rm attracts customers and hence directly increase pro ts. The second term involves the expression @ =@p which is the impact on pro ts of a marginal change in the price; the condition for a (second-stage) Nash price-setting equilibrium ensures that this term is zero. The third term is the strategic e ect. Firm recognizes that this will have an e ect on its own prices and taes this into account when maing the investment decision. In this case rm recognizes that investing in quality generates a negative strategic e ect since rm becomes more aggressive in its price-setting which hurts rm. In other words, while rm enjoys a higher quality and hence a higher willingness of its consumers to pay for its product, it also nds itself competing against a more aggressive rival who cuts its price in order to lure customers away from rm. This harm then must be taen into account when considering the quality increasing investment. 9