Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly

Similar documents
Mixed Motives of Simultaneous-move Games in a Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

Relative Performance and Stability of Collusive Behavior

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

Privatization and government preference. Abstract

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

Maximin and minimax strategies in asymmetric duopoly: Cournot and Bertrand

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Market Structure and Privatization Policy under International Competition

Alternative Strategies of a Public Enterprise in Oligopoly Revisited: An Extension of Stackelberg Competition

Volume 29, Issue 2. Equilibrium Location and Economic Welfare in Delivered Pricing Oligopoly

Research Article Welfare Comparison of Leader-Follower Models in a Mixed Duopoly

Volume 29, Issue 1. Second-mover advantage under strategic subsidy policy in a third market model

Mixed Oligopoly, Partial Privatization and Subsidization. Abstract

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly

Mixed Duopoly with Price Competition

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Welfare and Profit Comparison between Quantity and Price Competition in Stackelberg Mixed Duopolies

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

Microeconomics III. Oligopoly prefacetogametheory (Mar 11, 2012) School of Economics The Interdisciplinary Center (IDC), Herzliya

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2012

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND TRADE POLICY

What Industry Should We Privatize?: Mixed Oligopoly and Externality

Patent Licensing in a Leadership Structure

Analysis of a highly migratory fish stocks fishery: a game theoretic approach

Wage-Rise Contract and Entry Deterrence: Bertrand and Cournot

On supply function competition in a mixed oligopoly

Quantity Competition vs. Price Competition under Optimal Subsidy in a Mixed Duopoly. Marcella Scrimitore. EERI Research Paper Series No 15/2012

Efficiency, Privatization, and Political Participation

Optimal Trade Policies for Exporting Countries under the Stackelberg Type of Competition between Firms

Oligopoly (contd.) Chapter 27

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I

Pure Strategies and Undeclared Labour in Unionized Oligopoly

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

MKTG 555: Marketing Models

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik ( December 29, 2008

Price discrimination in asymmetric Cournot oligopoly

Long run equilibria in an asymmetric oligopoly

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati.

The Timing of Endogenous Wage Setting under Bertrand Competition in a Unionized Mixed Duopoly

Does Timing of Decisions in a Mixed Duopoly Matter?

VERTICAL RELATIONS AND DOWNSTREAM MARKET POWER by. Ioannis Pinopoulos 1. May, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract

Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies?

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit

HW Consider the following game:

The Nightmare of the Leader: The Impact of Deregulation on an Oligopoly Insurance Market

Outsourcing under Incomplete Information

Advertisement Competition in a Differentiated Mixed Duopoly: Bertrand vs. Cournot

Price versus Quantity in a Mixed Duopoly under Uncertainty

Solution Problem Set 2

Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma

Noncooperative Oligopoly

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals.

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory EC104

Chapter 11: Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers

A monopoly is an industry consisting a single. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two. An oligopoly is an industry consisting of a few

Regional restriction, strategic commitment, and welfare

All Equilibrium Revenues in Buy Price Auctions

Cournot-Bertrand competition in a unionized mixed duopoly

SOLVING COURNOT, STACKELBERG AND COLLUSION GAMES USING R

X. Henry Wang Bill Yang. Abstract

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

Microeconomics I - Seminar #9, April 17, Suggested Solution

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001

Shigeo MUTO (Tokyo Institute of Technology, Japan)

Endogenous choice of decision variables

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation

Relocation and Public Ownership of Firms

International Economics B 6. Applications of international oligopoly models

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications Final Exam Ronaldo Carpio Jan. 13, 2015

Follower Payoffs in Symmetric Duopoly Games

Endogenous Leadership with and without Policy Intervention: International Trade when Producer and Seller Differ

STRATEGIC VERTICAL CONTRACTING WITH ENDOGENOUS NUMBER OF DOWNSTREAM DIVISIONS

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

Profit Share and Partner Choice in International Joint Ventures

ENDOGENOUS TIMING IN A MIXED DUOPOLY: WEIGHTED WELFARE AND PRICE COMPETITION

FDI with Reverse Imports and Hollowing Out

Business Strategy in Oligopoly Markets

CEREC, Facultés universitaires Saint Louis. Abstract

A folk theorem for one-shot Bertrand games

Export Taxes under Bertrand Duopoly. Abstract

Organizational Structure and the Choice of Price vs. Quantity in a Mixed Duopoly

Urban unemployment, privatization policy, and a differentiated mixed oligopoly

HE+ Economics Nash Equilibrium

FDI Spillovers and Intellectual Property Rights

Ex-ante versus ex-post privatization policies with foreign penetration in free-entry mixed markets

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Second Midterm Examination Answers

Cournot-Bertrand Comparison in a Mixed Oligopoly

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally.

Transcription:

Working Paper Series No. 09007(Econ) China Economics and Management Academy China Institute for Advanced Study Central University of Finance and Economics Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly by Yuanzhu Lu

The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly Yuanzhu Lu China Economics and Management Academy, Central University of Finance and Economics Abstract This paper investigates whether the relative-profit-maximization objective of private firms affects endogenous timing in a mixed oligopoly in the linear demand case. Assuming firms have constant marginal costs and symmetric private firms are more efficient than the public firm, I find that such an objective does not affect endogenous timing at all compared with the absolute-profit-maximization case. When the equilibrium involves the public firm acting as a leader, social welfare increases compared with the level in the absolute-profit-maximization case. When the equilibrium involves the public firm acting as a follower, social welfare remains unchanged. Keywords: Mixed oligopoly; Endogenous timing; Stackelberg; Relative profits JEL Classification: L3, D43, H4 I am grateful to two anonymous referees, Subhashini Muthukrishnan, and participants at the fourth APEA (Asia-Pacific Economic Association) conference for their helpful comments on earlier versions of this paper. All errors remain mine. Yuanzhu Lu: China Economics and Management Academy, Central University of Finance and Economics, No 39 South College Road, CHINA, 0008; Tel: (860)688397, Fax: (860)688376, Email: yuanzhulu@cufe.edu.cn.

. Introduction Mixed oligopolies are common in many countries. The oil industry, heavy manufacturing, telecommunications and tourism industry are very good examples of mixed oligopolies. There have been a lot of studies on mixed oligopolies including partial privatization, capacity choice, endogenous timing and so on. One strand of literature on mixed oligopoly (especially mixed duopoly) has focused on endogenous timing, since alternate order of moves often produces significantly different results and thus leads to different welfare levels. These papers adopt Hamilton and Slutsky (990) s extended game with observable delay. For example, Pal (998) analyzed endogenous order of moves in quantity choice in a mixed oligopoly consisting of a single public firm and n domestic private firms. Matsumura (003) considered endogenous roles of firms in a mixed duopoly market where a state-owned public firm and a foreign private firm compete. Lu (006) investigated endogenous timing in a mixed oligopoly with one public firm, n domestic private firms and m foreign private firms. All these papers find that in equilibrium a public firm never moves simultaneously with domestic private firms. Most of the papers on mixed oligopoly make standard assumptions about a firm s objective. They assume that a private firm is an absolute-profit maximizer while a public firm is a social welfare maximizer. However, according to managerial theory of the firm, it has long been proposed that private firms in reality do not act to maximize absolute See De Fraja and Delbono (990) and Nett (993) for general reviews of the mixed oligopoly models. For recent literature on mixed oligopoly (duopoly), see Sun, Zhang and Li (005), Lu and Poddar (006), Cantos-Sánchez and Moner-Colonques (006), Matsushima and Matsumura (006), Kato and Tomaru (007), etc. Jacques (004) and Lu (007) slightly correct Proposition 4. of Pal (998).

payoffs. 3 In this paper I assume that the public firm s objective is to maximize social welfare which is defined as the sum of consumer surplus and the firm s absolute profits, while a private firm s objective is to maximize relative profit which is defined as the difference between the firm s absolute profit and the average absolute profit of all the firms. Why do I consider relative profit as a private firm s objective? Agent theory suggests that there are benefits associated with evaluating agents on the basis of their relative performances when the agent s performances are affected by a common shock term. The use of relative performance evaluation has been empirically supported by Gibbons and Murphy (990) who test the presence of relative performance evaluation for CEOs using data on 608 chief executive officers (CEOs) from 049 corporations from 974 to 986. Their results strongly support the hypothesis that relative performance evaluation is used in compensation and retention decisions affecting CEOs. In recent years, maximizing relative profit instead of absolute profit has aroused the interest of economists from different fields. From an evolutionary perspective, Schaffer (989) demonstrates with a Darwinian model of economic natural selection, that if firms have market power, profit-maximizers are not necessarily the best survivors. According to Schaffer (989), a unilateral deviation from Cournot equilibrium decreases the profit of the deviator, but decreases the other firm s profit even more. In other words, on the condition of being better than other competitors, firms that deviate from Cournot equilibrium achieve higher payoffs than the payoffs they receive under Cournot equilibrium. In Vega-Redondo (997), it is further argued that, under a general 3 Kaneda and Mastui (003) provided analytical review of the literature.

equilibrium framework, if firms maximize relative profit, a Walrasian equilibrium can be induced. On the other hand, Lundgren (996) shows that by making managerial compensation depend on relative profits rather than absolute profits, the incentives for oligopoly collusion can be eliminated. Kockesen, et al. (000) have shown that under some conditions a firm which strives to maximize relative profit will outperform a firm which maximizes absolute profit. Bolton and Ockenfels (000) and Fehr and Schmidt (999, 006) conducted an analysis considering an individual utility function that brings about a feeling of compassion towards an individual with a relatively lower material payoff and simultaneously brings about envy of other individuals with a higher material payoff. Morgan, et al. (003) studied auctions where bidders have independent private values but attach a disutility to the surplus of rivals. The purpose of this study is to find answers to the following questions: Does the relative-profit-maximization objective of private firms affect endogenous timing in a mixed oligopoly? Does social welfare increase compared to the absolute-profit-maximization case? Using a constant marginal cost function, I find that the objective does not affect endogenous timing at all. The equilibrium configuration is exactly the same as that characterized in Pal (998), Jacques (00) and Lu (007). When the equilibrium involves the public firm acting as a leader, social welfare increases compared with the level in the absolute-profit-maximization case. When the equilibrium involves the public firm acting as a follower, social welfare remains unchanged. The organization of the paper is as follows. In Section, I describe the model. 3

Section 3 presents three fixed timing games. The SPNEs in the observable delay game are presented in Section 4. Section 5 closes the paper.. The Model A mixed oligopoly market is considered with one public firm, called firm 0, and N private firms, all producing a single homogeneous good. The market price is determined by the inverse demand function p= a Q, where p is market price, Q q q N = 0 + j= j is total output and i q denotes the output of firm i ( = 0,,..., N ). Assume that a is sufficiently large. All private firms marginal costs are constant and identical, normalized to 0. The public firm is assumed to be less efficient than private firms and has a constant marginal cost c> 0. 4 Fixed costs are assumed to be zero for all firms. Each private firm i ( = 0,,..., N ) is a relative-profit-maximizer, and firm 0 is a public firm maximizing social welfare which is defined as the sum of consumer surplus and all firms profits. So a private firm i s objective function is π = π = ( a Q) q (( a Q) Q cq0), () + N+ N r i i π j i N j= 0 and the public firm s objective function is W = p( x) dx cq = aq Q cq Q 0 0. () 0 I consider the observable delay game of Hamilton and Slutsky (990) in the context 4 If the public firm is more or equally efficient than the private firms, it would produce a quantity such that the market price equals its marginal cost, resulting in a public monopoly. 4

of a quantity setting mixed oligopoly where the firms choose the timing for choosing their quantities. There are M periods for quantity choice and each firm cannot produce in more than one period. Specifically, I consider a two-stage game. In stage one, firms announce in which period they will choose their quantities and are committed to this choice. In stage two, after the announcement, firms choose their quantities knowing when the other firms will make their quantity choice and the market then clears after each firm has produced its output. My objective is to solve for the subgame perfect Nash equilibria (SPNE) of this extended quantity setting mixed oligopoly game. 3. Fixed Timing Games I investigate one Cournot and two Stackelberg models of fixed timing. The two Stackelberg models are called public follower model and public leader model. The equilibria of the observable delay game are determined in the next section. Without loss of generality, I assume that there are only two periods for quantity choice in this section. 3. Cournot Model In this model, all firms produce output simultaneously. The first-order condition for a private firm i s relative-profit-maximization problem is qi+ a Q ( a Q) = 0, i=,..., N, N+ (3) which implies that the reaction function of firm i is a N Ri q j = qi = q j. j i N j i (4) And the first-order condition for a public firm s social welfare maximization problem is 5

which implies that the reaction function of firm 0 is a Q= c, (5) N N R0 q j = q0 = a c q j. j= j= (6) The above equation says that the public firm will produce output until the market price is equal to its marginal cost. So in both the Cournot model and the public follower model, the market price is equal to c ; thus the public firm earns zero profit and a private firm r i s relative profit is then π π ( Nπ ) / ( N ) π / ( N ) cq / ( N ) = + = + = +, taking into i i i i i account that the symmetric private firms produce the same quantity level in the symmetric equilibrium. Solving for the equilibrium output of the Cournot model yields ( ) ( ) a N + c C C a+ N c q0 =, qi =, i=,..., N, N+ N+ (7) where the superscript C denotes the equilibrium outcome of the Cournot game. Each firm s payoff is then r ( π i ) C + ( ) ( N+ ) a N c = c, i=,..., N, (8) ( ) a N + c C W = ( a c ) c. N+ (9) 3. Public Follower Model In this model, all private firms produce simultaneously in period and the public firm produces in period. As pointed out before, the public firm will produce until 6

p = c in period. In period, private firms produce output taking into account the public firm s reaction function (6). Clearly, private firms will produce as much as possible subject to q0 0. Thus, F F a c q0 = 0, qi =, i=,..., N, (0) N r ( π i ) F ( c) ( ), i,..., N +, c a = = N N () F W = ( a c ), () where the superscript F denotes the equilibrium outcome of the public follower game. So social welfare in the public follower model is higher than in the Cournot model: W F C > W. This is because the market price is the same in both models and the less efficient public firm produces nothing in the public follower model while it produces a positive amount in the Cournot model. Therefore, the public firm and all private firms producing simultaneously in period cannot be sustained as an equilibrium. 3.3 Public Leader Model In this model, the public firm produces in period and all private firms produce simultaneously in period. In period, each private firm i s reaction function is given by (4). It is straightforward to obtain each private firm i s quantity in period as a function of q 0 : q i = ( ) 0 Na N q N +. (3) In period, the public firm produces output taking into account each private firm i s reaction function (3). Its objective function can then be written as 7

W = ( ( ) ) ( ( ) ) a N a N q0 N a N q 0 cq0. N + + + + + + It is straightforward to obtain ( N ) ( N )( N + ) L a N + L a 0 i q = c, q = + c, i=,..., N, N+ N+ N+ N+ r ( π i ) L c = a+ ( N+ ) ( ) ( N )( N + ) N+ c, (4) (5) + L N ac W = a + c, N+ N+ (6) where the superscript L denotes the equilibrium outcome of the public leader game. Clearly, the social welfare in this model is never lower than in the Cournot model C since the public firm can always choose its quantity equal to q 0. Since it chooses a L C different amount q0 q0 when N, L W must be higher than C W : W L C > W. L C However, when N =, q0 = q0 = a / c and thus W L N, C = W. Therefore, when the public firm and all private firms producing simultaneously in period cannot be sustained as an equilibrium. It is also clear that W F L > W since in the public follower model, the price is equal to the public firm s marginal cost and the less efficient public firm produces nothing, which maximizes social welfare. 4. Equilibria in the Observable Delay Game I now determine the equilibrium in the observable delay game. Proposition 8

summarizes the results of welfare comparisons among the three models of fixed timing. Proposition : When N, F L C W > W > W ; when N =, F L C W > W = W. This result tells us that the public firm acting as a follower of all private firms is socially optimal. To maximize social welfare, the public firm should make credible commitment on the role of a follower. As pointed out before, () the public firm and all private firms producing simultaneously in period cannot be sustained as an equilibrium, and () when N, the public firm and all private firms producing simultaneously in period cannot be sustained as an equilibrium. To determine whether the public firm and the private firm ( N = ) producing simultaneously in period can be sustained as an equilibrium, I will check whether the private firm has an incentive to be a leader. Note that the private firm s relative profit as a leader is never lower than the level as a simultaneous-mover. Moreover, since the private firm chooses a different amount q F i q ( a c a / ), the C i private firm s relative profit as a leader must be strictly higher. Thus, Proposition : The public firm and all private firms producing simultaneously cannot be sustained as an equilibrium. This proposition holds true regardless of the number of possible periods for quantity choice ( M ). Next I will consider the public follower and public leader candidate equilibria. I first conisder the case when M =. Consider the public follower candidate equilibrium. Clearly, the public firm has no incentive to deviate. Does a private firm, say firm, have an incentive to deviate to produce in period? Suppose it deviated. Then in period, the public firm s reaction function (6) and firm s reaction function (4) imply q ( ) N a c N 0 N+ j= = q and j 9

( ( ) ) q = a+ N c. Since the public firm will produce until p= c, each private firm N+ i=,..., N chooses to produce as large as possible such that q 0 = 0. Firm s relative profit is then ( ) r c a c N cq N+ N+ π = = c, which is lower than ( ) ( ) c a c N N + since a is sufficiently large. Therefore, firm has no incentive to deviate. Similarly, it can also be shown that a subgroup of private firms has no incentive to deviate. Suppose firms,,, m ( m N ) deviate to produce in period. Then in period i ( ( ) ) q = a+ N c, i=,..., m. The market price is still c, and q 0 = 0, thus each N+ private firm i s ( i=,..., m ) relative profit is = ( i=,..., m ). So the public r N π i N+ c follower candidate equilibrium is an equilibrium indeed. Consider the public leader candidate equilibrium. Clearly, the public firm has no incentive to deviate. Does a private firm, say firm, have an incentive to produce in period? Suppose it deviated. Then in period, each private firm i=,..., N will produce ( )( ) q Na N q0+ q i N N + =. In period, the social welfare and firm s relative profit can be written as ( N N) a+ ( N+ )( q0+ q) ( N N) a+ ( N+ )( q0+ q) W = a cq 0, N N+ N N+ π = a ( N N) a+ ( N+ )( q0+ q) r N N+ q ( N N) a+ ( N+ )( q0+ q) ( N N) a+ ( N+ )( q0+ q) a cq N+ N N+ N N+ It is straightforward to obtain 0. 0

q 0 a N q a N r a c N c N N N N N, c N N N N N, N N N N N N N 3 c. Comparing firm s relative profit when deviating and the relative profit when producing in period yields a ( N ) ( N ) = ( )( + )( + ) c N N N N N N + 3 + + c a+ ( N+ ) c ( N ) ( N )( N + ) N+ 5 4 3 N 3N + 4N 5N + N, ( N+ ) which is negative when N and positive when N >. So when N, a private firm has no incentive to deviate from the public leader candidate equilibrium. It can also be shown that the two private firms (when N = ) have no incentive to deviate as a group. 3 c Therefore the candidate equilibrium is an equilibrium indeed. Proposition 3: Suppose there are only two possible periods for quantity choice ( M = ). If N >, there is a unique SPNE: public follower. At this equilibrium, the market price equals the marginal cost of the public firm and the public firm produces nothing. If N, then there is a second SPNE: public leader. When there are more than two possible periods for quantity choice ( M > ), the public firm has an incentive to be a follower. So any public leader equilibrium must involve all private firms producing in the last period. However, if there are at least two c

private firms, a private firm has an incentive to produce before the other private firms. 5 So the public leader equilibrium arises if and only if N = ; moreover, the public leader equilibrium must involve the public firm producing in the first period since otherwise the private firm has an incentive to produce as a leader. As for the public follower equilibrium, again since each private firm has an incentive to produce before the other private firms, such an equilibrium must involve all private firms producing in the first period if N and the public firm producing in a subsequent period while if N =, it involves the private firm producing in any period except the last one and the public firm producing in a subsequent period. Proposition 4: Suppose there are more than two possible periods for quantity choice ( M > ). If N, there is a unique SPNE, in which all private firms produce in the fist period and the public firm produces in a subsequent period. If N =, then there are two types of equilibria: public follower equilibrium in which the private firm produces in any period except the last one and the public firm produces in a subsequent period, and public leader equilibrium in which the public firm produces in the first period and the private firm produces in the last period. 4. Comparison between the Relative-Profit-Maximization Case and the Absolute-Profit-Maximization Case Now I compare the endogenous order of moves between the relative-profit-maximization case and the absolute-profit-maximization case. Pal (998), 5 According to our analysis above, this is clear when N. When N, it is straightforward to show that a private firm has an incentive to be a leader of the other private firm (still a follower of the public firm).

Jacques (004) and Lu (007) investigate the absolute-profit-maximization case. It is clear that the endogenous order of moves in these two cases is exactly the same. This is the main result of this paper. Proposition 5: In the linear demand and constant marginal cost case, endogenous timing in a mixed oligopoly is the same regardless of the relative-profit-maximization or absolute-profit-maximization objective of private firms. The social welfare level when the order of moves is endogenized can also be compared between the two cases. It is clear that in the public follower equilibrium, the social welfare level is exactly the same since in each case the total amount of the quantity is a c and the public firm produces nothing. In the public leader equilibrium, when + private firms are relative-profit maximizers, ( N ) W = a + c ; when private L N ac + N+ firms are absolute-profit maximizers, it is straightforward to obtain ( ) L W a N c ac = + +. Since a is sufficiently large, the social welfare level is higher in the relative-profit-maximization case. To understand why, note that when the public firm acts as a leader, the first-order condition for a private firm i s absolute-profit maximization problem is qi+ a Q= which implies that the reaction function of firm i is 0, a Ri q j = qi = q j. j i j i Comparing this function with (4) tells us that a private firm will produce more output in the relative-payoff-maximization case. Taking this into account, a public firm as a leader produces less. Moreover, the total quantity is higher than in the 3

absolute-payoff-maximization case. Proposition 6: In the public follower equilibrium, private firms relative-profit-maximization objective has no effect on social welfare; however, in the public leader equilibrium, social welfare increases when the private firms are relative-profit maximizers. 5. Concluding Remarks In this paper I investigate the effect of private firms relative-payoff-maximization objective on endogenous timing in a mixed oligopoly in the linear demand and constant marginal cost case. I find that endogenous timing in a mixed oligopoly is the same regardless of the relative-profit-maximization or absolute-profit-maximization objective of private firms. I also find that in the public follower equilibrium, private firms relative-profit-maximization objective has no effect on social welfare; however, in the public leader equilibrium, social welfare increases when the private firms are relative-profit maximizers. This suggests that, it is socially desirable that private firms focus on relative profits instead of absolute profits. I believe that the main results of this paper will continue to hold for more general demand and cost functions. First, note that generally (except in very special cases) a private firm has an incentive to produce more output in the relative-profit-maximization case. When a general (inverse) concave and downward sloping demand function p( Q ) and cost function C0( q 0) for the public and convex cost function C( q ) for the private 4

firm are used, 6,7 a private firm i s relative profit is N N r π i = π i π j = p( Q) qi C( qi) p( Q) Q C0( q0) C( q j), N+ j= 0 N+ j= and the first order condition can be written as p Q qi p Q p Q q j C qi N ( ) + ( ) ( ) = ( ) It is then clear that once q 0, 8 a relative-profit-maximizing private firm i j i j > produces more than an absolute-profit-maximizing private firm. Second, given this fact, it can be expected that generally all firms producing simultaneously cannot be sustained as an equilibrium outcome. Suppose they produce in the first period. The public firm has an incentive to deviate to be a follower so that private firms produce more. Suppose they produce in a subsequent period. Either the public firm or a private firm has an incentive j i. to deviate to be a leader. Third, it can also be expected that when N is sufficiently large, the public leader configuration cannot be sustained as an equilibrium outcome since a private firm has an incentive to produce before other private firms. So private firms relative-payoff-maximization objective has not much, if any, effect on endogenous order of moves in a mixed oligopoly. Generally, social welfare increases in the relative-profit-maximization case compared with the absolute-profit-maximization case since private firms have incentives 6 The inverse demand function p( Q) satisfies p < 0, p 0and cost function C( q) satisfies C 0. 7 For the sake of simplicity, the symmetry of the private firms is again imposed. The public firm is again assumed to be less efficient to avoid a public monopoly, i.e., C ( q) C ( q) 0 >. j i q j > 8 As long as the public firm is not a follower or there are at least two private firms, 0. 5

to produce more output in the relative-profit-maximization case, as pointed out before. References Bolton, G. E. and A. Ockenfels (000). ERC: A Theory of Equity, Reciprocity, and Competition. American Economic Review, 90, pp. 66-93. Cantos-Sánchez, P. and R., Moner-Colonques (006). Mixed Oligopoly, Product Differentiation and Competition for Public Transport Services. The Manchester School, 74, pp. 94-33. De Fraja, G. and F. Delbono (990). Game Theoretic Models of Mixed Oligopoly, Journal of Economic Surveys, 4, -7. Fehr, E. and K. M. Schmidt. (006). Economics of Fairness, Reciprocity and Altruism: Experimental Evidence and New Theories, in S. Kolm, and J. M. Ythier (eds), in Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism, and Reciprocity, Vol., Chapter 8, pp. 65-694. North-Holland: Amsterdam. Fehr, E. and K. M. Schmidt (999). A Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 4, pp. 87-868. Gibbons, R. and K. J. Murphy (990). Relative Performance Evaluation for Chief Executive Officers. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 43, pp. 30S-5S. Hamilton, J. and S. Slutsky (990). Endogenous Timing in Duopoly Games: Stackelberg or Cournot Equilibria. Games and Economic Behavior,, pp. 9-46. Jacques, A. (004). Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly: A Forgotten Equilibrium. Economics Letters, 83, pp. 47-48. Kaneda, M. and A. Mastui (003). Do Profit Maximizers Maximize Profit? Divergence of 6

Objective and Result in Oligopoly. mimeo, University of Tokyo, available at http://www.e.u-tokyo.ac.jp/~amatsui/profit50.pdf. Kato, K. and Y. Tomaru (007). Mixed Oligopoly, Privatization, Subsidization, and the Order of Firms Moves: Several Types of Objectives. Economics Letters, 96, pp. 87-9. Kockesen, L., Ok, E. A. and R. Sethi (000). The StrategicAdvantage of Negatively Interdependent Preferences. Journal of Economic Theory, 9, pp. 74-99. Lu, Y. (006). Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly with Foreign Private Competitors: the Linear Demand Case. Journal of Economics, 88, pp. 49-68. Lu, Y. (007). Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly: Another Forgotten Equilibrium. Economics Letters, 94, pp. 6-7. Lu, Y. and S. Poddar (006). The Choice of Capacity in Mixed Duopoly under Demand Uncertainty. The Manchester School, 74, pp. 66-7. Lundgren, C. (996). Using Relative Profit Incentives to Prevent Collusion. Review of Industrial Organization,, pp. 533-550. Matsushima, N. and T. Matsumura (006). Mixed Oligopoly, Foreign Firms, and Location Choice. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 36, pp. 753-77. Matsumura, T. (003). Stackelberg Mixed Duopoly with a Foreign Competitor. Bulletin of Economic Research, 55, pp. 75-87. Morgan, J., Steiglitz, K. and G. Reis (003). The Spite Motive and Equilibrium Behavior in Auctions. Contributions to Economic Analysis & Policy, (), Article 5. Nett, L. (993). Mixed Oligopoly with Homogenous Goods, Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics 64, 367 394. Pal, D. (998). Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly. Economics Letters, 6, pp. 7

8-85. Schaffer, M. E. (989). Are Profit Maximisers the Best Survivors? Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization,, pp. 9-45. Sun, Q., Zhang, A. and J. Li (005). A Study of Optimal State Shares in Mixed Oligopoly: Implications for SOE Reform and Foreign Competition. China Economic Review, 6, pp. -7. Vega-Redondo, F. (997). The Evolution of Walrasian Behavior. Econometrica, 65, pp. 375-384. 8