Teaching business cycles with the IS-TR model

Similar documents
Objectives AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

Part2 Multiple Choice Practice Qs

6. The Aggregate Demand and Supply Model

VII. Short-Run Economic Fluctuations

Economics 102 Discussion Handout Week 14 Spring Aggregate Supply and Demand: Summary

TAMPERE ECONOMIC WORKING PAPERS NET SERIES

Answers to Questions: Chapter 8

Macroeconomic Theory and Policy (2nd Edition)

Macroeconomics. Based on the textbook by Karlin and Soskice: Macroeconomics: Institutions, Instability, and the Financial System

7 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND* Chapter. Key Concepts

Lecturer: Dr. Priscilla Twumasi Baffour, Department of Economics Contact Information:

Economics 102 Discussion Handout Week 14 Spring Aggregate Supply and Demand: Summary

III. 9. IS LM: the basic framework to understand macro policy continued Text, ch 11

Archimedean Upper Conservatory Economics, November 2016 Quiz, Unit VI, Stabilization Policies

Archimedean Upper Conservatory Economics, October 2016

Keynesian Theory (IS-LM Model): how GDP and interest rates are determined in Short Run with Sticky Prices.

Lecture 22. Aggregate demand and aggregate supply

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Test Review. Question 1. Answer 1. Question 2. Answer 2. Question 3. Econ 719 Test Review Test 1 Chapters 1,2,8,3,4,7,9. Nominal GDP.

At the height of the financial crisis in December 2008, the Federal Open Market

Chapter 9 Chapter 10

Macroeconomics I International Group Course

Keynesian Matters Source:

The Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Model

AP Macroeconomics. Scoring Guidelines

Macro CH 29 sample questions

Expansions (periods of. positive economic growth)

ECON 209 FINAL EXAM COURSE PACK FALL 2017

SHORT-RUN FLUCTUATIONS. David Romer. University of California, Berkeley. First version: August 1999 This revision: January 2018

ECON Intermediate Macroeconomics (Professor Gordon) Second Midterm Examination: Fall 2015 Answer sheet

CHAPTER 23 OUTPUT AND PRICES IN THE SHORT RUN

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

ECO 209Y L0101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #2

Econ 102 Final Exam Name ID Section Number

Disclaimer: This resource package is for studying purposes only EDUCATION

3. OPEN ECONOMY MACROECONOMICS

Introduction The Story of Macroeconomics. September 2011

A. What is the value of the tax increase multiplier if the MPC is.80? B. Consumption changes by 400 and disposable income by 100. What is the MPC?

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

What Determines Aggregate Demand?

AGGREGATE SUPPLY, AGGREGATE DEMAND, AND INFLATION: PUTTING IT ALL TOGETHER Macroeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Chapter 10 3/19/2018. AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND (Part 1) Objectives. Aggregate Supply

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 11. Classical and Keynesian Macro Analyses

From Solow to Romer: Teaching Endogenous Technological Change in Undergraduate Economics

Macroeconomics Review Course LECTURE NOTES

University of Toronto July 21, 2010 ECO 209Y L0101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #2

Chapter 23. Aggregate Supply and Aggregate Demand in the Short Run. In this chapter you will learn to. The Demand Side of the Economy

This is IS-LM, chapter 21 from the book Finance, Banking, and Money (index.html) (v. 1.1).

The text was adapted by The Saylor Foundation under the CC BY-NC-SA without attribution as requested by the works original creator or licensee

Macro Models: an APP for Macroeconomic Models. User Manual 1.0

Lecture 12: Economic Fluctuations. Rob Godby University of Wyoming

Equilibrium in AD-AS Model Problem Set

LECTURE 18. AS/AD in demand-deficient Ireland: Unemployment and Deflation

Sticky Wages and Prices: Aggregate Expenditure and the Multiplier. 5Topic

TEACHING OPEN-ECONOMY MACROECONOMICS WITH IMPLICIT AGGREGATE SUPPLY ON A SINGLE DIAGRAM *

ECON 212: ELEMENTS OF ECONOMICS II Univ. Of Ghana, Legon Lecture 8: Aggregate Demand Aggregate Supply Dr. Priscilla T. Baffour

5. An increase in government spending is represented as a:

Cost Shocks in the AD/ AS Model

ECON Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory

Real Business Cycle Model

9. CHAPTER: Aggregate Demand I

Teaching Macroeconomics after the Crisis: What have we learnt? Peter Bofinger Universität Würzburg

Practice Test 1: Multiple Choice

Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment

A decrease in the price level makes consumers feel more wealthy, which in turn encourages them to spend more.

Working Paper Series Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware

Objectives THE BUSINESS CYCLE CHAPTER

Textbook Media Press. CH 27 Taylor: Principles of Economics 3e 1

14.02 Quiz #2 SOLUTION. Spring Time Allowed: 90 minutes

3 Macroeconomics LESSON 8

This is IS-LM, chapter 21 from the book Finance, Banking, and Money (index.html) (v. 2.0).

Aggregate Demand I, II March 22-31

Practice Test 2: Multiple Choice

Royal School of Administration. Macroeconomics

Money and the Economy CHAPTER

FETP/MPP8/Macroeconomics/Riedel. General Equilibrium in the Short Run II The IS-LM model

10 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND* Chapt er. Key Concepts. Aggregate Supply1

What is Macroeconomics?

Principles of Macroeconomics Prof. Yamin Ahmad ECON 202 Spring 2007

Economics 1012A: Introduction to Macroeconomics FALL 2007 Dr. R. E. Mueller Third Midterm Examination November 15, 2007

Chapter 13: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Analysis

Business Fluctuations. Notes 07. Aggregate. Supply. Aggregate. Demand. Aggregate. Demand Shifts. Aggregate. Supply Shifts.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Macroeconomics I Exam Revision. Part A: Week Four Economic Growth Based on Week Three Lectures [Also refer to Chapter 20]

ECO 2013: Macroeconomics Valencia Community College

Model Question Paper Economics - II (MSF1A4)

Macroeconomic Analysis Econ 6022


Macroeconomics, Spring 2007, Final Exam, several versions, Early May

China, the Dollar Peg and U.S. Monetary Policy

Problem Set #5 Due in hard copy at beginning of lecture on Monday, April 8, 2013

Please choose the most correct answer. You can choose only ONE answer for every question.

Chapter 11 1/19/2018. Basic Keynesian Model Expenditure and Tax Multipliers

ECON 3010 Intermediate Macroeconomics Final Exam

Review: Markets of Goods and Money

Introduction to Economic Fluctuations. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

EC202 Macroeconomics

Expectations Theory and the Economy CHAPTER

Monetary Macroeconomics Lecture 3. Mark Hayes

Transcription:

MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Teaching business cycles with the IS-TR model Juha Tervala University of Helsinki 30 September 2014 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/58992/ MPRA Paper No. 58992, posted 1 October 2014 14:22 UTC

ömmföäflsäafaäsflassflassflas fffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffff Discussion Papers Teaching business cycles with the IS-TR model Juha Tervala University of Helsinki and HECER Discussion Paper No. 382 August 2014 ISSN 1795-0562 HECER Helsinki Center of Economic Research, P.O. Box 17 (Arkadiankatu 7), FI-00014 University of Helsinki, FINLAND, Tel +358-9-191-28780, Fax +358-9-191-28781, E-mail info-hecer@helsinki.fi, Internet www.hecer.fi

HECER Discussion Paper No. 382 Teaching business cycles with the IS-TR model Abstract Business cycles are an essential part of macroeconomics. However, the study of macroeconomics often ignores the observed business cycles. During and after the global financial crisis, several economists have emphasized that macroeconomics courses will have to be changed. This paper presents a real world application of the IS-TR model, which helps to explain and teach business cycles. The simple Keynesian model clearly explains output fluctuations and the conduct of monetary policy. The main reason for strong business cycles in the euro area has been shocks in the goods market. The European Central Bank has changed its main interest rate mainly as a reaction to changes in the output gap. JEL Classification: A20, E40, E52 Keywords: business cycles, IS-TR model, macroeconomics, teaching of economics Juha Tervala Department of Political and Economic Studies University of Helsinki P.O. Box 17 (Arkadiankatu 7) FI-00014 University of Helsinki FINLAND e-mail: juha.tervala@helsinki.fi

1. Introduction Business cycles are an essential part of macroeconomics. The IS-LM model and its successor, the IS- TR model, are classical tools of macroeconomics teaching. However, the study of macroeconomics often ignores the observed business cycles. During and after the global financial crisis, several economists have emphasized that macroeconomics courses will have to be changed. Blinder (2010, 385), for instance, argues that the global financial crisis should force everyone who teaches macroeconomics [ ] to reconsider their curriculums. Shiller (2010) argues that students have felt that the lectures on macroeconomics bear little relation to the economic crisis. Also students have expressed a desire to change the way economics is taught. The International Student Initiative for Pluralism in Economics (2014), for example, argues that [t]he real world should be brought back into the classroom. Friedman (2010) argues that a key lesson of the financial crisis that that we live in a monetary economy and therefore aggregate demand and policies that affect aggregate demand are determinants of real economic outcomes. There is demand for an applied model that helps explain the recently observed business cycles. This paper introduces an application of the textbook IS-TR model of Burda and Wyplosz (2013), which helps to explain and teach business cycles and the conduct of monetary policy. The paper s focus is on the euro area, but the Keynesian model also effectively explains monetary policy and fluctuations in output in the United States and Great Britain. The paper s primary target is macroeconomics teachers interested in teaching business cycles using a recent and interesting example. 1 1 This paper complements Chapter 10 of Macroeconomics: A European Text by Burda and Wyplosz (2013). Figures and Excel files used in this presentation can be found at http://blogs.helsinki.fi/jtervala/teachingbusiness-cycles-with-the-is-tr-model/. The Excel files can be very useful in analysing the case for the United States, for example, in various exercises. This paper is based on Tervala (2014).

2. A version of the IS-TR model This section introduces one version of the IS-TR model. The IS curve represents the combinations of the nominal interest rate (i) and output (Y), which are consistent with equilibrium of the goods market. Business cycle models typically (including the model of Burda and Wyplosz (2013)) assume that prices are sticky, and therefore inflation is zero. However, I assume that inflation matches the inflation target of the European Central Bank (ECB). Therefore, the real interest rate is the nominal interest rate minus the inflation target, and fluctuations in the nominal interest rate directly change the real interest rate. Aggregate demand depends on private consumption (C), investment (I), public demand (G) and net exports (PCA, for the primary current account). Therefore, the IS curve can be written as follows: = + + +. The Taylor rule (TR) has replaced the LM curve in modern business cycle models. The Taylor rule describes how the central bank should set the interest rate, depending on the target interest rate, inflation and output gap. The output gap is the deviation of output from its natural or potential level. As mentioned earlier, inflation is assumed to match the inflation target of the ECB. Therefore, the Taylor rule can be written as = +, where is the target interest rate of the central bank, and b is a parameter governing the central bank s response to the output gap, denoted by. The Taylor rule represents the combinations of output and interest rate that characterize the central bank s monetary policy. The TR curve moves only if monetary policy is changed. The central bank responds to fluctuations in the output gap. For example, a negative output gap implies that the central bank lowers the interest rate below the

target rate. Changes in the target rate move the TR curve. For example, an expansionary (contractionary) monetary policy shock moves the TR curve downward (upward). Equilibrium in the short term is the combination of the interest rate and output that satisfies the IS equation and the Taylor rule. The IS-TR model can be used to analyse the macroeconomic effects of shocks. Good market shocks shift the IS curve, whereas monetary policy shocks shift the TR curve. Traditional business cycle models analyse changes in the level of output. However, economic growth is a pervasive phenomenon. Therefore, I analyse a version of the IS-TR model that focuses on the output gap, not the level of output. In this version of the model, the IS curve remains at the original position, assuming aggregate demand growths at the same rate as the potential output. If aggregate demand growths faster (slower) than potential output, then IS curve shifts rightward (leftward). Figure 1 shows the IS-TR model in a case where the output gap is zero and the interest rate matches the target rate of the central bank. Figure 1. IS-TR model

3. Business cycles in the euro area The next step is to analyse business cycles in the euro area between 2000 and 2013. As mentioned earlier, inflation is assumed to remain constant, which does not match reality. Figure 2 shows inflation in the euro area. As the figure shows, inflation remained close to the ECB s inflation target of 2% for the most part, with an average inflation rate (2.1%). Therefore, the assumption of constant inflation does not cause any issues. Figure 2. Inflation in the euro area 2000 2013. Source: OECD (2014). Figure 3. IS-TR model and business cycles in 2000 2003. Source: OECD (2014).

In Figure 3, the horizontal axis shows the OECD s estimates of the output gap and the vertical axis shows the short-term interest rate (three-month money market rate). The money market rate is used instead of the ECB s main refinancing rate. This is because the ECB s main interest rate and expectations about it are reflected in the three-month money market rate. The short-term interest rate of several countries is also easily available on the OECD s website. The data of the United States and Great Britain, for example, can be used in various exercises. In Figure 3, the TR(ECB) curve reflects the ECB s monetary policy rule in the periods of 2000 2003 and 2008 2013. Figure 3 shows that the ECB s target rate was 2.7%, and it reacted consistently to changes in the output gap. So Therefore, the slope of the TR(ECB) curve is realistic (0.8). Figure 4. Economic growth in the euro area. Source: OECD (2014). The slope of the IS curves in the figure is -1. Increase in output in the model is due to monetary policy shocks, when movement takes place along the IS curve. Therefore, the slope of the IS curve is set to match the effectiveness of monetary policy. A typical estimate calculates the effect of one percentage change in the interest rate on output to somewhat less than 1%. For example, Christano et al. (1999) estimate that a positive shock to the monetary policy rule of 75 basis point decreases output roughly by 0.3% to 0.4%. On the other hand, Bluedorn and Bowdler (2011) estimate that a

one percentage point change in the interest rate changes output by 1.3% to 2.1%. These studies show that one percentage point shock to the interest rate changes output both by less than 1% and by more than 1%. Therefore, the assumption that one percentage point change in the interest rate changes the output gap by 1% can be considered a realistic estimate. The starting point in Figure 3 is the year 2000. The IS(00) depicts the IS curve in 2000. As mentioned earlier, TR(ECB) shows the ECB s normal monetary policy rule. The intersection of the IS(00) and TR(ECB) curve shows the combination of the interest rate and the output gap in which the money and goods markets are in equilibrium. Strong economic growth in the late 1990s and in 2000 meant that in 2000, the interest rate was 4.4% and the output gap 2%. In 2001, economic growth was 2% and the increase in aggregate demand was roughly equal to that of potential output. Therefore, the IS curve remained at the same position and the equilibrium was roughly the same as in 2000. Figure 5. The main interest rate of the ECB. Source: ECB (2014). In 2002 and 2003, economic growth was slower than usual, as Figure 4 shows. The increase in aggregate demand was slow, which means that the IS curve shifted leftward. In Figure 3, IS(02) depicts the IS curve in 2002. The IS curve also shifted leftward in 2003. The IS-TR model implies that the central bank reacts to this by lowering the interest rate, and the output gap approaches zero.

Figure 5 shows the main interest rate of the ECB. As shown earlier in Figure 3, slow economic growth and leftward movement of the IS curve in 2002 and 2003 meant that the ECB lowered its main interest rate several times. This seems to have been a reaction to the change in the output gap caused by a decrease in demand. Therefore, the fall in the interest rate was a movement along the TR curve in 2002 and 2003. In 2003, the interest rate was 2.4% and the output gap was negative. Figure 6. IS-TR model and business cycles in 2003 2007. Source: OECD (2014). The IS(03-05) curve in Figure 6 shows the IS curve for the period 2003 2005. As shown earlier in Figure 5, the ECB lowered the interest rate in 2003 to the 2% level, where it was kept for some time. In 2004, it seems that the ECB caused an expansionary monetary policy shock that shifted the TR curve downward. The ECB seems to have pursued expansionary monetary policy between 2004 and 2007. In Figure 6, the TR(04-07) shows the ECB s TR curve for 2004 2007. In 2004, the economy moved along the IS curve to new equilibrium. The interest rate lowered and the output gap turned positive. In 2005, economic growth in the euro area was normal (2%) and the IS curve remained roughly at the same place. Therefore, the money market interest rate was slight above 2% and the output gap was slightly above zero, just as in 2004. Economic growth was much faster than normal in 2006 2007, as aggregate demand increased rapidly for several reasons. First, a consumption boom took place in several euro area countries.

Second, public consumption increased strongly in some euro area countries. Third, global boom increased the euro area s exports. All these events increased aggregate demand in the euro area. The IS curve shifted rightward in 2006, and it moved rightward again in 2007. According to the IS-TR model, a strong increase in demand causes a large change in the output gap. The ECB responded to an economic boom by increasing the interest rate several times in 2006 2007, as shown in Figure 5. However, I should emphasise that the ECB kept the TR curve at a lower than normal level. In 2007, the euro area economy was at a situation in which the output gap was high (3.5%), the ECB s main interest rate was 4% and the money market interest was slightly above 4%. Figure 7. IS-TR model and business cycles in 2007 2009. Source: OECD (2014). In 2008, two important events took place. First, the global expansion came to an end and aggregate demand fell. This caused a leftward shift in the IS curve. Second, the ECB ended the period of loose monetary policy. This is reflected in a movement of the TR curve in 2008 back to its original position. The ECB even increased its main interest rate in 2008, despite a worsening economic situation. 2 According to the IS-TR model, a shift in the IS curve leftward and a shift in the TR curve upward mean an increase in the interest rate and a fall in the output gap. The data support this view, as highlighted in Figure 7. 2 It is worth noting also that inflation was high in 2008. This may in part explain the ECB s monetary policy.

The economic crisis hit the euro area economy in full swing in 2009. Households reduced consumption. Negative animal spirits decreased investment. The banking crisis reduced consumption and investment. The global economy crisis decreased the euro area s exports. These events together caused a strong reduction in demand. The IS curve moved to the level IS(09). According to the model and data, output fell substantially, despite the ECB reducing the interest rate swiftly and strongly. The reduction in the interest rate was consistent with the ECB s monetary policy rule. In 2009, the euro area output fell to 4%, the output gap turned negative and the interest rate was slightly above 1%. Figure 8. IS-TR model and business cycles in 2007 2009. Source: OECD (2014). In 2010 and 2011 the euro area economy recovered. The IS curve shifted rightward, both in 2010 and 2011. Therefore, output increased and the ECB even increased the interest rate in 2011. In 2012, the euro area adopted the fiscal consolidation agenda. A fall in public consumption reduced aggregate demand, and the IS curve shifted leftward in 2012 and 2013 (not shown in figures). This induced a fall in output. The ECB reacted to this by lowering the interest rate, which is consistent with the ECB s normal monetary policy rule. In 2013, the euro area was headed toward a situation where the output gap was roughly -3% and the interest rate was at the zero lower bound.

4. Conclusions This paper is an attempt to bring the real world into macroeconomics lectures. The paper introduces a version of the IS-TR model, which helps teach the observed business cycles in an interesting way. The simple Keynesian model clearly explains output fluctuations and the conduct of monetary policy. Analysis indicated that shocks in the goods markets have been the driving force of business cycles in the euro area. The ECB has increased and decreased its main interest rate mainly as a response to changes in the output gap. Most of the time, the ECB s monetary policy has been consistent with the Taylor rule. However, the ECB implemented expansionary monetary policy in 2004 2007. This was a contributing factor to the overheating of the economy in 2006 2007. However, analysis indicates that the overheating, and the long economic crisis of 2009 2013, were mainly caused by shocks in the goods markets.

References Blinder, A. 2010. Teaching Macro Principles after the Financial Crisis, Journal of Economic Education 40 (4): 385 390. Bluedorn, J.C. and Bowdler, C. 2011. The open economy consequences of U.S. monetary policy, Journal of International Money and Finance 30 (2): 309 36. Burda, M. and Wyplosz, C. 2013. Macroeconomics: A European Text, 6 th edition, Oxford, Oxford University Press. Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M. and Evans, C. 1999. Monetary policy shocks: What have we learned and to what end? in Handbook of Macroeconomics 1A, ed. Taylor, J. and Woodford, M, Amsterdam, Elsevier Science. ECB 2014. Statistics. https://www.ecb.europa.eu/stats/html/index.en.html (accessed May 12, 2014). Friedman, B. M. 2010. Reconstructing Economics in Light of the 2007? Financial Crisis. Journal of Economic Education 40 (4), 391 397. International Student Initiative for Pluralism in Economics 2014. An international student call for pluralism in economics. http://www.isipe.net/open-letter/ (accessed May 15, 2014). OECD 2014. Economic Outlook Annex Tables, http://www.oecd.org/economy/outlook/economicoutlookannextables.htm (accessed May 13, 2014). Shiller, R. 2010. How Should the Financial Crisis Change How We Teach Economics?. Journal of Economic Education 40 (4), 403 409. Tervala, J. 2014. Euroalueen suhdannevaihteluiden opettaminen. Kansantaloudellinen aikakauskirja (Finnish Economic Journal) 110 (2), 202 210.