Reading map : Structure of the market Measurement problems. It may simply reflect the profitability of the industry

Similar documents
Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Recall the conditions for a perfectly competitive market. Firms are price takers in both input and output markets.

ANSWERS To next 16 Multiple Choice Questions below B B B B A E B E C C C E C C D B

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

ECO 100Y L0101 INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS. Midterm Test #2

Introduction. Monopoly 05/10/2017

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

Perfect Competition Model: where does it apply in PICs

1 Maximizing profits when marginal costs are increasing

CMA Part 2 Financial Decision Making

2 Maximizing pro ts when marginal costs are increasing

Problem Set #2. Intermediate Macroeconomics 101 Due 20/8/12

ECONOMICS 103. Topic 7: Producer Theory - costs and competition revisited

Paul Krugman and Robin Wells. Microeconomics. Third Edition. Chapter 11 Behind the Supply Curve: Inputs and Costs. Copyright 2013 by Worth Publishers

Economics. Firms in Competitive Markets 11/29/2013. Introduction: A Scenario. The Big Picture. Competitive Market Experiment

The Big Picture. Introduction: A Scenario. The Revenue of a Competitive Firm. Firms in Competitive Markets

ECON 102 Boyle Final Exam New Material Practice Exam Solutions

Induction Course Microeconomics

12/2/2009. Market Structures. pure (perfect) competition monopoly monopolistic competition. oligopoly. Characteristics of Pure Competition

2c Tax Incidence : General Equilibrium

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Microeconomics, Questions 1-2

Corporate Finance, Module 3: Common Stock Valuation. Illustrative Test Questions and Practice Problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.

Come and join us at WebLyceum

Welcome to Day 8. Principles of Microeconomics

1. Which of the following statements is an implication of the semi-strong form of the. Prices slowly adjust over time to incorporate past information.

Lesson-36. Profit Maximization and A Perfectly Competitive Firm

OUTLINE September 20, Revisit: Burden of a Tax. Firms Supply Decisions 9/19/2017 1:27 PM. Burden & quantity effect Depend on Price-Elasticity

Simple Notes on the ISLM Model (The Mundell-Fleming Model)

AS/ECON AF Answers to Assignment 1 October Q1. Find the equation of the production possibility curve in the following 2 good, 2 input

Corporate Finance, Module 21: Option Valuation. Practice Problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 7, 2005

Derivation of zero-beta CAPM: Efficient portfolios

Portfolio Management Philip Morris has issued bonds that pay coupons annually with the following characteristics:

Note on Cost of Capital

Slide Set 6: Market Equilibrium & Perfect Competition

ANTITRUST ECONOMICS 2013

A Perfectly Competitive Market. A perfectly competitive market is one in which economic forces operate unimpeded.

Models of Asset Pricing

Lecture 9: Supply in a Competitive Market

Introduction to economic growth (2)

Equalities. Equalities

9 D/S of/for Labor. 9.1 Demand for Labor. Microeconomics I - Lecture #9, April 14, 2009

Economics Introduction: A Scenario. The Revenue of a Competitive Firm. Characteristics of Perfect Competition

Lecture # 14 Profit Maximization

Model Question Paper Economics - I (MSF1A3)

MONEY DEMAND, THE EQUILIBRIUM INTEREST RATE, AND MONETARY POLICY. Chapter 23

Risk and Return and Portfolio Theory

Testing the predictions of the Solow model:

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

II. Determinants of Asset Demand. Figure 1

CHAPTER 15 INVESTMENT, TIME, AND CAPITAL MARKETS

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

CHAPTER 2 REVENUE OF THE FIRM

Theory. 2.1 One Country Background

If a model were to predict that prices and money are inversely related, that prediction would be evidence against that model.

G.C.E. (A.L.) Support Seminar- 2016

If it is important to you, you will find a way If not, you will find an excuse. Frank Banks

Final Term Papers. Fall 2009 (Session 03) ECO401. (Group is not responsible for any solved content) Subscribe to VU SMS Alert Service

November 2001 Course 2 Interest Theory, Economics and Finance. Society of Actuaries/Casualty Actuarial Society

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 9 THE COSTS OF PRODUCTION

Economics 101 Section 5

SOLUTIONS TO TEXT PROBLEMS:

1 The Solow Growth Model

Unit 3: Costs of Production and Perfect Competition

Dr. Barry Haworth University of Louisville Department of Economics Economics 201. Midterm #2

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 2 with Solutions

CHAPTER 3 National Income: Where It Comes From and Where It Goes

BOND ANALYTICS. Aditya Vyas IDFC Ltd.

Characterization of the Optimum

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

We will make several assumptions about these preferences:

Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization

1. What is the vertical intercept of the demand curve above? a. 120 b. 5 c. 24 d. 60 e. 1/5

ECO401 Quiz # 5 February 15, 2010 Total questions: 15

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 10, Question 1

Investment 3.1 INTRODUCTION. Fixed investment

PROBLEM SET 7 ANSWERS: Answers to Exercises in Jean Tirole s Theory of Industrial Organization

Chapter-17. Theory of Production

The Open Economy. (c) Copyright 1998 by Douglas H. Joines 1

Chapter 7. Costs. An economist is a person who, when invited to give a talk at a banquet, tells the audience there s no such thing as a free lunch.

Noncooperative Market Games in Normal Form

Economics 335 Problem Set 6 Spring 1998

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015

Version 1 READ THESE INSTRUCTIONS CAREFULLY. DO NOT BEGIN WORKING UNTIL THE PROCTOR TELLS YOU TO DO SO

SUPPLY AND DEMAND CHAPTER 2

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

Costs and Profit Maximization Under Competition

False_ The average revenue of a firm can be increasing in the firm s output.

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

ECONOMICS. Time Allowed: 3 hours Maximum Marks: 100

is a concept that relates the responsiveness (or sensitivity) of one variable to a change in another variable. Elasticity of A with respect to B = %

The mathematical definitions are given on screen.

CPR-no: 14th January 2013 Managerial Economics Mid-term

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

First page. edition Gwartney Stroup Sobel Macpherson

Lecture # 6 Elasticity/Taxes

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

Transcription:

Reading map : The structure-conduct-performance paradigm is discussed in Chapter 8 of the Carlton & Perloff text book. We have followed the chapter somewhat closely in this case, and covered pages 244-259 during Lecture 2. However, your understanding of the mathematical details of the material on pages 247-249 and 254 is not essential for your understanding of the SCP theory. The discussion about the empirical validity of the proposed relationship between market structure and firm performance can be found on pages 259-267 of the Carlton & Perloff text book. The discussion about (Sutton s) modern approach to structure-conduct-performance is on pages 268-274 of the book. But you need to understand only the basic conceptual aspects of this modern approach; focus on the issues discussed in class. Structure of the market Measurement problems It may simply reflect the profitability of the industry It is difficult to measure the size of the economic market Domestic vs. international Related products (tea and coffee) Buyer concentration US market for electronic consumer products The hypothesis central to the SCP paradigm is that market structure causes performance. The problem, however, is that causality may well exist in the other direction; if a market is profitable, it will attract more firms, and hence its structure will change. It is also not easy to determine the size of the economic market. For example, suppose that there are only 4 firms selling tea in the UK. As such, this suggests that the market is highly concentrated. SCP would then tell us that the profitability of these tea firms should therefore be high. However, the firms might face steep competition from imports. They may also face competition from producers of other warm beverages such as coffee that are (roughly speaking) substitutes for tea. A simple measure of market concentration may not account for these complexities. Firm performance (when measured in terms of profitability) depends not only on the market structure but also on the bargaining power of the buyers. For example, since the US is the largest market for consumer electronics, US consumers often pay prices for electronic goods that are higher than the prices paid by their counterparts in Europe and the rest of the world. Firms charge lower prices in the US to retain control over their share of the largest market for their products.

Structure of the market Determinants Scale (and scope) economies Cost advantages Product differentiation Capital requirements Unionization Institutions Incumbency: can incumbents influence regulation? Democracy: is it necessarily good for market entry? Performance - measurement Returns to asset (or equity) Profit per dollar of investment Price-cost margin Tobin s q Ratio of market value of company to replacement cost of company Problem: how efficient are capital markets? If there are economies of scale, such that the average cost of production decreases with output, smaller firms will find it difficult to compete with larger firms, and eventually only large firms will be left in the market. That will increase market concentration. If some firms have cost advantage over others, the firms with higher cost will leave the market, and that too will increase market concentration. It is difficult, if not impossible, for firms to avoid competition if the product they sell is homogeneous. But if product differentiation is possible then firms will retain market power and there will be a deviation from a competitive market structure. If capital requirements are high, only a few firms might be able to enter and operate in a market. In that case, once again, market concentration will be high. If labourers are unionized, every firm will have to pay wages that are determined through centralized wage bargaining. But some firms may not be able to pay the (usually high) wages that unionized workers get paid, and this will reduce the number of firms in the market, and hence increase market concentration. If incumbents have more power relative to firms that can potentially enter (a situation that is sometimes described as undemocratic), the former might be able to lobby the government to create entry barriers, such that new firms find it difficult to enter. This is known to have happened in the context of international trade, where domestic firms lobbied to limit import competition. In such cases, market concentration can be high. Here, the measure that requires some explanation is Tobin s q. Suppose that a firm owns machines etc worth 100, such that if you want to replicate the same plant you would need 100. You sell 100 shares of that firm to investors. Logically, each share should be valued at 1. Suppose, however, each share is valued at 2, such that the market value of the firm is 200. In that case, Tobin s q for this firm is 200/ 100 = 2. This would happen only if investors believe that the firm s expected future performance is going to be very good, such that 100 is not a true reflection of the value of the firm. If we make the (somewhat strong assumption) that

Rates of return and economic profit - I Economic profit = Revenue (Labour cost + Material cost + Capital cost) Capital cost annual rental fees Capital cost is a flow and not the cost of the stock of capital Capital assets should be valued at replacement cost for the rate of return to be an accurate indicator of whether new capital should be invested or whether the firm should be shut down Rates of return and economic profit - II To be noted: A rental rate must provide an owner of capital with a particular rate of return after accounting for depreciation markets have all relevant information such that 200 accurately reflects the future value of the firm, then we can use Tobin s q as a measure of a firm s (expected future) performance. It is often used in the academic literature, much less so in other contexts. Recapitulate that when we say that a firm earns zero profit in a competitive market (in the long run) or positive profit in a monopolistic market, we talk about economic profit. On the other hand, when we measure rates of return, we talk about accounting profit. We have to reconcile the two. The formula for computing economic profit is on the PPT slide on the left. The first thing to note is that the cost of capital is a flow that equals the rental rate of capital times the stock of capital. A simple example will clear up the distinction between stock and flow. If you save have 100 in savings in a bank, and you get 1 per month in interest earnings, then 1 is a flow and the 100 is a stock. The next question that one has to answer is whether capital should be measured in terms of book value or in terms of replacement cost. For example, consider again the firm which would cost 100 to replicate. When the firm was set up, however, it may have cost 80 to set it up because the machines etc were cheaper at that time. Is the value of this firm s capital stock 80 (the book value) or 100 (the replacement cost)? We generally consider the latter to be more relevant, i.e., our measure of a firm s capital stock should be its replacement cost. This slide refers to the algebra on page 248 of the Carlton & Perloff text book. What you should take away from this discussion is how one estimates the earned rate of return, given information on a firm s revenue, labour cost, material cost, replacement cost of capital and the depreciation rate. Algebra: = R labour cost material cost (r + )p K K Setting = 0 in a competitive market, r = (R labour cost material cost p K K)/ p K K (1) Consider two industries, in each of which the actual observed rate of return is 5% higher than the

Rates of return and price Suppose that actual rate of return is 5% higher than the normal rate of return In order for rate of return to be normal, revenue must decline by 5% of value of capital Given the labour cost and the materials cost, the implication of this for the required change in price depends on the industry s capital intensity A high rate of return on capital does not necessarily imply that a firm is overcharging its customers significantly Rates of return problems Economic vs. accounting definitions of capital Rental fee of all assets vs. book value of assets Replacement cost vs. historical cost normal return that firms earn in a perfectly competitive market. Clearly, if there is competition, the revenue of firms in both these markets should decline to restore the normal rate of return. Such a decline in the revenue of firms would require a fall in the price of charged by the firm that is sufficient to more than offset the increase in the sale of the product (a firm can sell more at a lower price if the demand curve facing it is downward sloping). The extent to which the price should fall will depend on the elasticity of demand. (IF YOU DON T UNDERSTAND THIS, ASK ME DURING MY OFFICE HOURS, AND I WILL EXPLAIN.) The implication is that large differences in rates of returns across industries may actually result from relatively small differences in the price-cost margin. This slide summarizes the discussion in the section entitled Pitfalls in calculating rates of return, on pages 249-252 of the Carlton & Perloff text book. This section is not difficult to understand. If you need clarification, seek clarification during the next tutorial. Measurement of depreciation Straight line formula Valuing advertisement and R&D Impact of future profitability Adjustment for inflation Discussion adjusting for risk Capital asset pricing model (CAPM) Expected return E(R i ) = R f + [E(R m ) R f ] where E(R i ) expected rate of return on asset i R f risk-free rate of return E(R m ) expected rate of return on the market portfolio beta of the asset, a measure of risk While the problems mentioned in the previous slide are pure measurement problems, this one is, in part, a conceptual problem. Suppose that you find that returns on assets (or investments) in a market is fairly high. Does it necessarily mean that the market is uncompetitive and that market concentration is high? What if the production process, or some other activity of the firms, is risky, such that the higher rate of return is simply a reflection of the higher risk? In that case, once again, it would be difficult to test the validity of the SCP paradigm. This slide summarizes a model called the CAPM which essentially says that returns from an asset should be commensurate with its risk. That is why investors get a return of 3.3% per annum when they lend to the German government for 10 years, and a return of 12.71% when they lend to the Brazilian government for the same period (Source: Bloomberg).

Price-cost margin Lerner index = (P MC)/P It can be demonstrated that (P MC)/P = - 1/ε (2) Check In a perfectly competitive market, ε = infinity In a perfectly competitive market, P = MC Price-cost margin (contd.) Using AVC instead of (difficult to measure) MC Implicit assumption: long-run constant returns to scale This results in a measurement bias: instead of (2), the price-cost margin becomes - 1/ε + (r + )(p K K/PQ) P m P* = P c Measuring price-cost margin E* E m E c If market is competitive, price will remain P c, else it will be P m Use this principle to estimate mark ups and price-cost margin: (P MC)/P = - / where is a measure of market power and is a measure of elasticity of demand MC c In the literature on the SCP paradigm, we generally use the price-cost margin (or Lerner index) as the measure of performance. In highlighted equation in the slide on the left, is the price elasticity of demand, i.e., the responsiveness of quantity demanded to a change in price. How do we verify that the equation is correct? In a competitive market, P = MC, i.e., Lerner index equals zero. In a competitive market, the price elasticity of demand is infinite, i.e., if a seller increases the price of its product even a little bit, it will lose all its customers. (Remember that the product is homogeneous in a competitive market such that it is easy to switch sellers.) If is infinity, then once again the Lerner index (this time, 1 divided by infinity) is zero. So, we get the same outcome for competitive markets using both sides of the highlighted equation. This slide discusses something that has relevance for the discussion on econometrically estimating the relationship between structure and performance. Since we cannot generally compute marginal cost from financial statements, we often use the average variable cost instead of the marginal cost in the Lerner index. This changes our measure of the Lerner index from 1/ to (1/ ) PLUS something. For the moment, just note this change. We shall discuss this later. This is Figure 8.3 of the Carlton & Perloff text book, and the explanation provided for this figure in the book is reasonably good. This figure has also been discussed in the voice embedded PPT file. MC m MR 1 MR2 Q* Q m Q c D 1 D 2 Q

Empirical evidence Market structure and price-cost margin - I Model: (P AVC)/P = 0.16 + 0.10 C4 + 0.08 (p K K/PQ) (0.01) (0.02) (0.02) Implication: Suppose C4 = 0.50 and (p K K/PQ) = 0.40 Price-cost margin = 0.24, i.e., P = 1.3AVC (P is 30% higher than average variable cost If C4 increases to 100% (or 1), then P = 1.4AVC Overall, the impact of concentration ratio on price-cost margin is unstable and ambiguous Empirical evidence Market structure and price-cost margin - II Model: PCM = - 22.3 + 0.183 S 0.022 C4 + others where S = market share of the firm An estimated positive correlation between PCM and C4 at the industry level may be incorrect, and does not reflect any causal relationship between the two variables Here we discuss the empirical evidence about the relationship between price-cost margin and 4-firm concentration ratio (C4). Note that since we use AVC instead of marginal cost to compute price-cost margin, we have to add p K K/PQ to the regression equation. The coefficient of C4 in the regression equation is 0.10, which is positive. This suggests a positive relationship between price-cost margin and C4, which is predicted by the structure-conduct performance paradigm. Note, however, that the impact of a change in market concentration on price-cost margin is not large. Suppose that C4 = 0.50, i.e., the largest 4 firms account for 40% of the sales in the market, and suppose that p K K/PQ = 0.40. In that case, from the regression equation, we get P = 1.3 AVC, i.e., price is 30% higher than the average variable cost. If now C4 is increased to 1.00, other things remaining the same, P = 1.4 AVC, i.e., price is 40% higher than average variable cost. In other words, a doubling of has a relatively small impact on price-cost margin. Hence, even if the predicted relationship between market concentration and price-cost margin is statistically significant, it may not be significant from an economic standpoint. Here the argument is that a firm s price-cost margin is less dependent on market concentration (C4) and more on its own market power, as captured by its market share (S). The regression equation suggests that this is indeed the case. The impact of market share on price-cost margin is 0.18, which is positive. The impact of C4 on the price-cost margin, on the other hand, is -0.022, which is negative, contrary to the prediction of the structure-conductperformance paradigm. Also, numerically the impact of market share (S) on price-cost margin is much greater than the impact of C4. This brings into question the validity of the structure-conductperformance paradigm.

Sutton Sunk costs are exogenous If firms can form cartels, profit margins are high, so new entrants are attracted and market concentration falls If a market is highly contestable, profit margins are low, so new firms do not enter and market concentration remains high Sunk costs are endogenous An increase in market size will increase average quality but will not reduce market concentration Conduct taking a step back Conduct involves making strategic decision aimed at reducing competitive pressures Strategic decisions are taken by firms management Why do firms take many bad strategic decisions? E.g., mergers and acquisitions Agency conflict If sunk costs are exogenous, we can think of two scenarios that are at odds with the prediction of the structure-conduct-performance paradigm regarding the (positive) relationship between market concentration and price-cost (or profit) margin. Consider next the situation where sunk costs are endogenous. As the market size increases, incumbent firms can incur sunk costs by investing in product quality. This investment results in better quality products, on average, without a reduction in market concentration. This is the case of the supermarket industry that is discussed in the following slide. To the extent that we are worried about consumer benefits and price-cost margin is only one way to approach this issue this suggests that there can be increase in these benefits on account of competition, even though the market concentration itself remains unchanged. The structure-conduct-performance paradigm does not discuss conduct. There is an assumption that competitive pressures influence behavior of firms. However, strategic decisions are taken on behalf of firms by their managers, and economists argue that the interests of managers are not always consistent with that of profit maximization. This divergence in interests of managers and firms (and their owners) is known as agency conflict. A simple example is that of mergers and acquisitions. These involve strategic decisions made by managers, and are expected to augment a firm s profitability. But in most cases mergers and acquisitions fail to add to a firm s value.