DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik (http://www.sumonbhaumik.net) December 29, 2008

Similar documents
Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

Microeconomics I - Seminar #9, April 17, Suggested Solution

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

A monopoly is an industry consisting a single. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two. An oligopoly is an industry consisting of a few

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2008

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Chapter 10: Price Competition Learning Objectives Suggested Lecture Outline: Lecture 1: Lecture 2: Suggestions for the Instructor:

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly

MICROECONOMICS II. Author: Gergely K hegyi. Supervised by Gergely K hegyi. February 2011

Solution Problem Set 2

MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001

MS&E HW #1 Solutions

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory EC104

Lecture Note 3. Oligopoly

Wage-Rise Contract and Entry Deterrence: Bertrand and Cournot

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND TRADE POLICY

Business Strategy in Oligopoly Markets

p =9 (x1 + x2). c1 =3(1 z),

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

PRISONER S DILEMMA. Example from P-R p. 455; also 476-7, Price-setting (Bertrand) duopoly Demand functions

Oligopoly (contd.) Chapter 27

LECTURE NOTES ON GAME THEORY. Player 2 Cooperate Defect Cooperate (10,10) (-1,11) Defect (11,-1) (0,0)

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Microeconomics, Questions 1-2

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model

Chapter 11: Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers

INTRODUCTORY ECONOMICS

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

By the end of this course, and having completed the Essential readings and activities, you should:

AS/ECON 2350 S2 N Answers to Mid term Exam July time : 1 hour. Do all 4 questions. All count equally.

pq A q A = (6.01q A.01q C )q A q A = 6q A.01q 2 A.01q C q A q A.

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 26, Lecture 28. Oligopoly

MKTG 555: Marketing Models

Endogenous Leadership with and without Policy Intervention: International Trade when Producer and Seller Differ

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

Problem 3,a. ds 1 (s 2 ) ds 2 < 0. = (1+t)

Question 1: (20 points)

I. Introduction and definitions

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly

Economics 212 Microeconomic Theory Final Exam. April 24, Faculty of Arts and Sciences Queen s University

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

Mixed Oligopoly, Partial Privatization and Subsidization. Abstract

Final Exam - Solutions

Energy markets. Damien Ernst University of Liège

SOLVING COURNOT, STACKELBERG AND COLLUSION GAMES USING R

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Microeconomics III. Oligopoly prefacetogametheory (Mar 11, 2012) School of Economics The Interdisciplinary Center (IDC), Herzliya

Microeconomics, IB and IBP. Regular EXAM, December 2011 Open book, 4 hours

Econ 101A Final exam Th 15 December. Do not turn the page until instructed to.

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 2 Consumer Behaviour 2.1 THE CONSUMER S BUDGET

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati.

Exercise Chapter 10

Volume 29, Issue 1. Second-mover advantage under strategic subsidy policy in a third market model

Chapter 11 Online Appendix:

Oligopoly Games and Voting Games. Cournot s Model of Quantity Competition:

Solutions to Homework 3

Chapter 7 Pricing with Market Power SOLUTIONS TO EXERCISES

Strategic Production Game 1

Problem Set 7 - Answers. Topics in Trade Policy

Table 10.1: Elimination and equilibrium. 1. Is there a dominant strategy for either of the two agents?

On Repeated Myopic Use of the Inverse Elasticity Pricing Rule

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

Antoine Augustine Cournot was a French mathematician who, in 1838, wrote a book entitled Researches

Name: Midterm #1 EconS 425 (February 20 th, 2015)

The Kleit Oligopoly Game: A Classroom Game for Chapter 14 1

EconS Oligopoly - Part 3

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

II. Determinants of Asset Demand. Figure 1

Economics 171: Final Exam

FIRST PUBLIC EXAMINATION

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies?

ECON 311 Winter Quarter, 2010 NAME: KEY Prof. Hamilton

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9

Analysis of a highly migratory fish stocks fishery: a game theoretic approach

Module 2 THEORETICAL TOOLS & APPLICATION. Lectures (3-7) Topics

Price discrimination in asymmetric Cournot oligopoly

2- Demand and Engel Curves derive from consumer optimal choice problem: = PL

Relative Performance and Stability of Collusive Behavior

Export Taxes under Bertrand Duopoly. Abstract

Mohammad Hossein Manshaei 1394

(b) per capita consumption grows at the rate of 2%.

GS/ECON 5010 section B Answers to Assignment 3 November 2012

Price Theory of Two-Sided Markets

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Graduate School of Management and Economics

Some Notes on Timing in Games

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Horizontal Mergers. Chapter 11: Horizontal Mergers 1

UNIT 1 THEORY OF COSUMER BEHAVIOUR: BASIC THEMES

Chapter 4 Topics. Behavior of the representative consumer Behavior of the representative firm Pearson Education, Inc.

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2012

Transcription:

DUOPOLY MODELS Dr. Sumon Bhaumik (http://www.sumonbhaumik.net) December 29, 2008 Contents 1. Collusion in Duopoly 2. Cournot Competition 3. Cournot Competition when One Firm is Subsidized 4. Stackelberg Duopoly 5. Hotelling Competition The handout closely follows the relevant sections of Microeconomic Theory by James Henderson and Richard Quandt. It also uses part of the model used in a paper published by Harold Hotelling in Economic Journal in 1929. 1

1 Collusion in Duopoly Let us suppose that a market has the following inverse demand function: P = 100 0.5(q 1 + q 2 ) (1) There are two firms in this market. They have the following cost curves: C 1 = 5q 1 (2) C 2 = 0.5q2 2 (3) If the two firms can collude, they will maximize the joint profit by acting as a de facto monopolist. The joint profit function is given by Π = [100 0.5(q 1 + q 2 )](q 1 + q 2 ) 5q 1 0.5q2 2 (4) = 100(q 1 + q 2 ) 0.5(q 1 + q 2 ) 2 5q 1 0.5q2 2 (5) = 100(q 1 + q 2 ) 0.5(q1 2 + 2q 1 q 2 + q2) 2 5q 1 0.5q2 2 (6) The two firms choose q1 and q2, i.e., the values of q 1 and q 2 that maximize the joint profit. The two first order conditions are given by Π q 1 = 100 q 1 q 2 5 = 0 (7) Π q 2 = 100 q 1 q 2 q 2 = 0 (8) Solving the two first order conditions simultaneously, we should get q1 = 90 and q2 = 5. Now that we know the value of (q 1 + q 2 ), we should get P = 52.5. Finally, given the optimum quantities and the price, we should be able to compute the profits earned by the two companies in this market with collusion: Π 1 = 4275 and Π 2 = 250. 2 Cournot Competition Suppose now that the firms cannot collude and are involved in Cournot competition. In that case, they will not jointly maximize profit; each form will individually maximize its own profit and choose the corresponding optimal level of output. The profit functions of the two firms are given by 2

Π 1 = [100 0.5(q 1 + q 2 )]q 1 5q 1 (9) Π 2 = [100 0.5(q 1 + q 2 )]q 2 0.5q 2 2 (10) The first order conditions for profit maximization are dπ 1 dq 1 = 100 q 1 0.5q 2 5 = 0 (11) dπ 2 dq 2 = 100 0.5q 1 q 2 q 2 = 0 (12) Equation (11) is the reaction function for Firm 1, while equation (12) is the reaction function for Firm 2. We know that in a market with Cournot competition involving two firms, the equilibrium is attained at the point where the two reaction functions intersect. Hence, we solve equations (11) and (12) simultaneously, and get q 1 = 80 and q 2 = 30. Given the optimum quantities, we can compute the price in equilibrium: P = 45. Finally, given the quantities and the price in equilibrium, we can compute the profits of the two firms: Π 1 = 3200 and Π 2 = 900. Note the following: The total amount produced under Cournot competition (110) is higher than the total amount produced when the two firms collude (95). Not surprisingly, the price is lower under Cournot competition (45) than in a market with collusion (52.5). In the market with Cournot competition, more is produced in the firm with the convex cost curve (30) than in the market with collusion (5), while less is produced in the firm with the linear cost curve. Not surprisingly, the total profit earned by the two firms is lower in a market with Cournot competition (4100) than in a market with collusion (4525). 3 Cournot Competition when One Firm is Subsidized Next, suppose that we still have Cournot competition in the market, but Firm 1 is subsidized by the government. The extent of subsidy is s per unit of output produced by the firm. Firm 2 is not subsidized. In that case, Firm 1 s cost function becomes C 1 = 5q 1 sq 1 = (5 s)q 1. Hence, Firm 1 s profit function becomes 3

Π 1 = [100 0.5(q 1 + q 2 )]q 1 (5 s)q 1 (13) The new reaction function of Firm 1, therefore, is given by dπ 1 dq 1 = 100 q 1 0.5q 2 5 + s = 0 (14) The profit function of Firm 2 is unchanged and hence its reaction function does not change either. The Cournot equilibrium is obtained by simultaneously solving equations (12) and (14), and it gives us q1 = 560+8s and q 7 2 = 105 s. You can see that subsidy to 3.5 Firm 1 increases Firm 1 s output and decreases Firm 2 s output. 4 Stackelberg Duopoly Let us now move back to a duopoly market where neither firm receives a subsidy. But now Firm 1 acts as the leader and Firm 2 as the follower. This is the Stackelberg paradigm. In this paradigm, Firm 1, the leader, knows how Firm 2 will react to its output decision, i.e., Firm 1 knows Firm 2 s reaction function. We know that equation (12) gives us Firm 2 s reaction function. Simplifying it, we get q 2 = 50 0.25q 1. In the Stackelberg paradigm, Firm 1 s profit function, therefore, is given by Π 1 = [100 0.5(q 1 + q 2 )]q 1 5q 1 (15) = 100q 1 0.5q 2 1 0.5q 1 q 2 5q 1 (16) = 100q 1 0.5q 2 1 0.5q 1 (50 q 1 ) 5q 1 (17) = 70q 1 0.375q 2 1 (18) Firm 1 s first order condition for profit maximization, therefore, is dπ 1 dq 1 = 70 0.75q 1 = 0 (19) We, therefore, get q 1 = 93.33 and, substituting this value of q 1 in the reaction function of Firm 2, we get q 2 = 50 0.25q 2 = 26.67. Given these values of output, we can once again compute the price and the profits of the two firms in equilibrium. The profit of Firm 1 (the leader) is 3266.67, higher than the firm s profit in a market with simple Cournot competition. Correspondingly, the profit of Firm 2 (the follower) is 711.11, lower than the firm s profit in a market with simple Cournot competition. 4

5 Hotelling Model 1 Let there be two retail outlets, 1 and 2, that are located along a road that is l kilometers long. At each point along this road, there is a consumer who can choose to go to either outlet 1 or outlet 2, but they have to bear the cost of travel along this road. The cost is c per unit of length. Each retail outlet sets a price that maximizes its profits; outlet 1 charges price p 1 while outlet 2 charges price p 2. The diagramatic representation of this arrangement is as follows: a 1 x y 2 b It is easy to see that consumers who live in zone a are too far away from outlet 2 and it will always be cheaper for them to go to outlet 1. Similarly, for consumers who live in zone b, it is always cheaper to go to outlet 2. In other words, outlet 1 has monopoly over consumers in zone a while outlet 2 has monopoly over consumers in zone b. For those consumers who live between outlets 1 and 2, the total cost of purchasing the product from outlet 1 has to be compared with the total cost of purchasing the product from outlet 2. There would necessarily be one consumer who would be indifferent between the two outlets. She would be located at the point marked by, that is at a distance x from outlet 1 and at a distance y from outlet 2. In other words, the following two conditions should hold: l = a + x + b + y (20) p 1 + cx = p 2 + cy (21) We can solve equations (20) and (21) simultaneously to obtain x = 1 ( l a b + p ) 2 p 1 2 c y = 1 ( l a b + p ) 1 p 2 2 c (22) (23) An increase in p 1 reduces the value of x and increases the value of y, i.e., if outlet 1 increases its price then fewer people who live between the two outlets find it cheaper to go to outlet 1, while more people find it cheaper to go to outlet 2. An increase in p 2 has the opposite effect. 1 Harold Hotelling (1929). Stability in competition. Economic Journal, Vol. 39, No. 153, pp. 41-57. 5

Let us assume for the sake of simplicity that the cost of each retail outlet is zero. Given than there is one consumer per unit of the road, it is easily seen that the demand experienced by the two outlets are q 1 = (a + x) and q 2 = (b + y). In the absence of cost, the profit functions of the outlets are Π 1 = p 1 q 1 = p 1 (a + x) (24) Π 2 = p 2 q 2 = p 2 (b + y) (25) Substituting the values of x and y from equations (22) and (23) into equations (24) and (25), respectively, we get Π 1 = 1 2 (l + a b)p 1 p2 1 2c + p 1p 2 2c Π 2 = 1 2 (l a + b)p 2 p2 2 2c + p 1p 2 2c (26) (27) The first order conditions of profit maximization of the two outlets are given by dπ 1 dp 1 = 1 2 (l + a b) p 1 2c + p 2 2c = 0 (28) dπ 2 dp 2 = 1 2 (l a + b) + p 1 2c p 2 2c = 0 (29) We can simultaneously solve equations (28) and (29) to obtain ( p 1 = c l + a b ) 3 ( p 2 = c l a b ) 3 (30) (31) outlets Given the optimum prices, we can compute the optimal values of profits of the two Π 1 = c ( l + a b ) 2 2 3 (32) Π 2 = c ( l + b a ) 2 2 3 (33) 6

It can be seen that p 1 and Π 1 increase with a while p 2 and Π 2 increase with b, i.e., the price that an outlet can charge and its profit increase with the size of the pool of consumers over which it has monopoly. Hence, it would be rational for each outlet to try to maximize the pool of consumers over which it has monopoly; outlet 1 would move towards outlet 2, and vice versa. In equilibrium, therefore, outlets 1 and 2 would be next to each other somewhere in the middle of the street. 7