TOWARD A CONSUMPTION TAX, AND BEYOND

Similar documents
DO WE NOW COLLECT ANY REVENUE FROM TAXING CAPITAL INCOME? Roger Gordon 1 University of California, San Diego

The Distribution of Federal Taxes, Jeffrey Rohaly

STATE CORPORATE INCOME TAXES GENERALLY

THE INDIVIDUAL ALTERNATIVE MINIMUM TAX: HISTORICAL DATA

Testimony to the President s Tax Reform Panel

Obama s Tax Hikes on High-Income Earners Will Hurt the Poor and Everyone Else

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CHARITABLE BEQUESTS AND TAXES ON INHERITANCES AND ESTATES: AGGREGATE EVIDENCE FROM ACROSS STATES AND TIME

I S S U E B R I E F PUBLIC POLICY INSTITUTE PPI PRESIDENT BUSH S TAX PLAN: IMPACTS ON AGE AND INCOME GROUPS

Government Affairs. The White Papers TAX REFORM.

Taxing Capital Income Once * Leonard E. Burman

Options to Fix the AMT

Options to Limit the Benefit of Tax Expenditures for High-Income Households

ApEc 8341 APPLIED PUBLIC FINANCE Fall 2013

TAX POLICY CENTER BRIEFING BOOK. Background. Q. What are tax expenditures and how are they structured?

Individual Retirement Accounts and 401(k) Plans: Early Withdrawals and Required Distributions

THIS PAPER HAS TWO SECTIONS. THE FIRST

PRELIMINARY ANALYSIS OF THE FAMILY FAIRNESS AND OPPORTUNITY TAX REFORM ACT

Income Taxes and Tax Rates for Sample Families, 2006 Greg Leiserson. December 2006

Five Easy Pieces Scorecard

Long Run Corporate Tax Avoidance, with Scott Dyreng and Ed Maydew, The Accounting Review, vol. 83, January 2008, p

Estimating the Distortionary Costs of Income Taxation in New Zealand

FISCAL FACT No. 516 July, 2016 Director of Federal Projects Key Findings Embargoed

THE DESIGN OF THE INDIVIDUAL ALTERNATIVE

D A T A D I G E S T PUBLIC POLICY INSTITUTE PPI. Extending Preferences for Dividends and Capital Gains: Who Gains the Most?

Senator Kerry s Tax Proposals. Leonard E. Burman and Jeffrey Rohaly 1 Revised July 23, 2004

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TAX EVASION AND CAPITAL GAINS TAXATION. James M. Poterba. Working Paper No. 2119

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES EXCHANGE TRADED FUNDS: A NEW INVESTMENT OPTION FOR TAXABLE INVESTORS. James M. Poterba John B. Shoven

Tax Reform and Charitable Giving

Summary of the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017

Beacon Hill Institute

FASB Looks to. Leslie F. Seidman, FASB Chair. Annual Tax Update Marriage and Taxes Estate Tax Portability Tax Preferences for Education

State Value Added Taxes. Laura Kalambokidis Future State Business Tax Reforms Conference Chicago, IL September 17, 2007

Suppose they took the AM out of the AMT?

An Analysis of the 2004 House Tax Cuts. Leonard E. Burman 1 The Urban Institute and The Tax Policy Center. June 2004

ENTITY CHOICE AND EFFECTIVE TAX RATES

Hoover Classics : Flat Tax hcflat ch6 Mp_201 rev0 page 201. Notes and References

tax notes Volume 147, Number 7 May 18, 2015

In the past decade, there has been a dramatic shift in the

TAX REFORM: IMPACT ON BUSINESSES AND INDIVIDUALS. February 8, 2018 Bruce I. Booken Rose K. Wilson

Six Tax Laws Later How Individuals' Marginal Federal Income Tax Rates Changed Between 1980 and 1995 Leonard E. Burman, William G. Gale, David Weiner

INTRODUCTION: ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF TAX EXPENDITURES

Removing Inflation from the Base is Fair, Pro-Growth Concept

THE TAX CUTS AND JOBS ACT

Increasing the Social Security Payroll Tax Base: Options and Effects on Tax Burdens

TAX EXPENDITURES FOR RETIREMENT PLANS

Revised November 21, 2008

THE STATISTICS OF INCOME (SOI) DIVISION OF THE

xiii Executive Summary

The Shrinking Tax Preference for Pension Savings: An Analysis of Income Tax Changes,

Chapter 11 Investments SOLUTIONS MANUAL. Discussion Questions

The Economic Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

HOW MUCH TO SAVE FOR A SECURE

New Analysis Finds GOP Tax Plan would Give Richest One Percent of CT Residents $125,380 More Per Year on Average than Obama s Approach

Report for Congress. Retirement Savings Accounts: Early Withdrawals and Required Distributions. March 7, 2003

State and Federal Public Finance. Dr. Sally Wallace Chair, Department of Economics Director, Fiscal Research Center

PUTTING FIRMS INTO OPTIMAL TAX THEORY

An Analysis of the Tax Treatment of Capital Losses Summary Several reasons have been advanced for increasing the net capital loss limit against ordina

POLICY BRIEF. Tax legislation enacted in 2001 increased the value of the Child Tax

Executive Summary. Effects of the Federal Tax Law on the State of Maryland Page 1 of 41

continue to average 0.2 percent of GDP from 2018 through 2028, CBO projects.

Assessing the Impact of Tax Reform on Illustrative New Jersey Homeowners

Federal Deductibility of State and Local Taxes

SPECIAL REPORT. The Excess Burden of Taxes and the Economic Cost of High Tax Rates

WebMemo22. The End of Pro-Growth Tax Policy: How the Rangel Tax Bill Could Affect the U.S. Economy. Published by The Heritage Foundation

Feldstein Proposal Increases Federal Revenues but the Devil s in the Details

UPDATED OPTIONS TO REFORM THE DEDUCTION FOR HOME MORTGAGE INTEREST. Amanda Eng Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center May 7, 2014

Trends in Tax Expenditures, Allison Rogers and Eric Toder Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center September 16, 2011

What Has Happened in Other States with High Tax Rates on Million-Dollar Incomes?

Discussion of Fiscal Policy and the Inflation Target

How Public Education Benefits from the Federal Income Tax Deduction for State and Local Taxes and Other Special Tax Provisions

The Child and Dependent Care Credit: Impact of Selected Policy Options

CRS Report for Congress

A Fair Way to Limit Tax Deductions

Desperately Seeking Revenue

Selected Recently Expired Individual Tax Provisions ( Tax Extenders ): In Brief

Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017: What Taxpayers Need to Know Presented by Shabri Moore

Revenue and Incentive Effects of Basis Step-Up at Death: Lessons from the 2010 Voluntary Estate Tax Regime

2017 Fingertip Tax Guide

center for retirement research

THE IMPACT OF AGING BABY BOOMERS ON LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION

H.R. 1 TAX CUT AND JOBS ACT. By: Michelle McCarthy, Esq. and Tyler Murray, Esq.

Towards a More Consistent Distributional Analysis

Commentary on International Taxation: Tax Policy when Corporate Profits are a Return to Labor rather than Capital. Roger H.

CAN EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT EXPLAIN THE RISE IN LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION AT OLDER AGES?

Year-End Tax Moves for Income Tax Rates for 2015

Federal Deductibility of State and Local Taxes

The unprecedented surge in tax receipts beginning in fiscal

Getting Real with Capital Gains Taxes by Adjusting for Inflation

In the United States, most tax incentives for saving are. The Taxation of Retirement Saving: Choosing Between Front Loaded and Back Loaded Options

2018 Tax Brackets. Income Tax Brackets and Rates FISCAL FACT. Amir El-Sibaie. Table 1. Unmarried Individuals, Tax Brackets and Rates, 2018

ROTH CONVERSION STRATEGIES FOR HNW AND AFFLUENT HOUSEHOLDS

WikiLeaks Document Release

Retirement Savings and Tax Expenditure Estimates

Individual Income Tax Rates and Other Key Elements of the Individual Income Tax: 1988 To 2013

CRS Report for Congress

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES RULES AND THE MISMANAGEMENT OF MONETARY FLICY. Martin Feldstein. Working Paper No. 122

A Database on the Passage and Enactment of Recent State Minimum Wage Increases

Tax Incidence Analysis First & Second Omnibus Tax Bills

Obamacare Tax Subsidies: Bigger Deficit, Fewer Taxpayers, Damaged Economy

Summary An issue in the development of the new health care reform plan is the effect on small business. One concern is the effect of a pay or play man

Transcription:

TOWARD A CONSUMPTION TAX, AND BEYOND Roger Gordon Department of Economics University of California, San Diego 9500 Gilman Drive La Jolla, Ca 92093 858-534-4828 858-534-7040 (fax) rogordon@ucsd.edu Laura Kalambokidis Department of Applied Economics University of Minnesota 217f Classroom-Office Building 1994 Buford Avenue St. Paul, MN 55108-6040 612-625-1995 612-625-6245 (fax) lkalambo@apec.umn.edu Jeffrey Rohaly Urban Institute 2100 M Street NW Washington, DC 20037 202-261-5877 202-833-4388 (fax) JRohaly@ui.urban.org Joel Slemrod University of Michigan 701 Tappan Street, Room A2120 Ann Arbor, MI 48109-1234 734-936-3914 734-763-4032 jslemrod@umich.edu Session Title: Taxation, Investment, and Saving Word-Processing Program: Microsoft Word

TOWARD A CONSUMPTION TAX, AND BEYOND Roger Gordon, Laura Kalambokidis, Jeffrey Rohaly, Joel Slemrod* Amid the academic debate about whether a tax based on consumption or income is superior, it has long been recognized that the U.S. federal tax system is in reality a hybrid of an income and consumption tax, with some elements that do not fit naturally into either system. In recent decades tax law changes that altered the nature of the hybrid were generally not discussed as part of a plan to establish either a pure income tax or a pure consumption tax, but as attempts to establish a level playing field or to improve incentives to save. 1 As of 2003, the outline of an explicit plan to move toward a consumption tax is emerging. Under the original Bush administration proposals in 2003, dividends would become tax-exempt if corporate tax had been paid on the earnings supporting the dividends, and a new tax-exempt Lifetime Savings Account, with no restrictions on use, would be created. The proposed expansion of tax-exempt savings accounts was not passed, although it will likely be re-introduced in some form. What did become law were two provisions to expand expensing of qualified property: (1) an increase in the fraction of equipment investment that can be immediately written off from 30 percent (which became law in 2002) to 50 percent, and (2) an increase through 2005 of the limit on the expensing of new depreciable assets by small businesses allowed under IRC Section 179. The 2003 tax law also reduced the rate of tax on dividends and realized capital gains received by an individual shareholder to be no more than 15 percent, compared to a top rate on ordinary income of 35 percent.

The acceleration of depreciation, the reduction of personal tax on dividends, and an expansion of tax-favored savings accounts can be seen as part of a strategy to shift the tax base from income to consumption. 2 If the ultimate destination of this set of tax reforms is a consumption tax base, then the most glaring omission from the discussion to date concerns interest deductibility. The continuation of interest deductibility, in spite of other moves toward a consumption tax base, raises two issues. The first is that interest deductibility plus expensing for businesses, plus exemption of financial returns of individuals produces not a zero tax on capital income, as under a consumption tax, but rather a subsidy. The second is that this tax structure allows a range of tax arbitrage opportunities among individuals and across corporations and individuals. For example, even under pre-2002 tax law, when high-tax-bracket investors borrowed from those in low (or zero) tax brackets they generated an arbitrage gain equal to the difference between the tax rates. Reducing the tax rate on interest income, but not interest deductions, to zero vastly expands this opportunity. These tax arbitrage opportunities reduce tax revenue without necessarily providing a concomitant reduction in the effective tax rate on saving and investment. I. Methodology In this paper we investigate the extent to which the U.S. income tax system of 2004 collects tax on capital income, and the implications of extending tax-preferred savings accounts. We do so by applying a methodology originally proposed in Roger Gordon and Joel Slemrod (1988) and there applied to the U.S. tax system of 1983. The methodology estimates how much tax is collected on capital income by calculating how much tax revenue would change if the tax system were modified to exempt income from capital in present value specifically by adopting 2

what the Meade Committee (1978) called an R-base tax --while leaving the tax rate structure and tax incentives otherwise unchanged. The difference between actual revenue and revenue under this alternative tax system is a measure of how much tax on capital income is collected under current law. There are many tax structures that imply no distortions at the margin to saving and investment decisions. For several reasons discussed in Roger Gordon et al. (2004a), we examine the R-base. Shifting to an R-base tax would involve replacing current deductions for depreciation, amortization, and depletion with immediate expensing for new investment. In addition, it requires eliminating interest, dividend, and capital gains from the tax base and also eliminating all interest deductions. Finally, it is necessary to allow an immediate deduction when goods are added to inventory rather than a deduction when goods are withdrawn from inventory. 3 How this measure relates to an average effective tax rate on saving and investment is discussed at length in Roger Gordon et al. (2004b). Strikingly, Gordon and Slemrod (1988) concluded that in 1983 in the United States the switch to an R-base tax would have cost little or no revenue, suggesting that the tax burden on capital was at that time small or non-existent. The methodology was refined in Gordon et al. (2004a, hereafter GKS) and applied to the U.S. tax system of 1995. 4 The findings for 1995 were less stark: a switch to an R-base tax in 1995 was estimated to cost $108.1 billion in tax revenues. Much had happened between 1983 and 1995, including the passage of the Tax Reform Act of 1986 and a significant drop in nominal interest rates that reduced the tax savings arising from any tax arbitrage through use of debt. II. Results 3

In this paper we apply the GKS methodology to the U.S. economy in 2004 in order to estimate how much tax on capital income is now being collected. Furthermore, we estimate the impact on the tax on capital income of the law changes passed in 2002-3. Finally, we estimate the implications of expanding tax-free accounts, as was proposed but not passed in 2003. Table 1 contains our key results. As a standard for comparison, Columns 1 and 2 present estimates of individual and corporate income tax revenues for 2004, in the absence of and including the main capital income tax changes of 2002-3, respectively. The basic approach is to begin in Column 2 with estimates of 2004 corporate and individual tax revenue. 5 We adjust both corporate and individual tax revenue to reflect the fact that the short-term revenue cost of the expensing provisions passed in 2002 and 2003 will exceed the steady-state revenue cost because future-year revenues will be higher reflecting lower tax depreciation in later years. 6 Next, we obtain estimates of revenue before the capital-incomerelated provisions of the 2002-3 tax laws by adding to the adjusted 2004 law revenue estimates in Column 2 the (adjusted) official estimates of the revenue cost of these provisions in the 2002 and 2003 laws. Thus, the difference between Column 1 and Column 2 is our estimate of the long-run implications of the capital income tax provisions of the 2002-3 tax law changes: a reduction of $49.9 billion in individual income tax revenues, and a reduction of $25.0 billion in corporation income tax revenues.. We then apply the GKS methodology to estimate how much revenue would be collected in 2004 if the United States had an R-base tax. Because of data limitations, we use slightly 4

different procedures for the corporation and individual tax. For the corporation income tax, we had to rely on 2000 data aged to reflect changes in profit, value of inventories, and capital expenditures, but not the tax law changes. We convert 2000 law into the tax collected under an R-base tax with a series of steps that are detailed in Table 2. 7 These steps produce an estimate that moving from 2000 law to an R-base corporation tax would reduce revenues by $55.1 billion; this is reflected in the difference between the first and third columns of the first row of Table 1. To estimate 2004 individual income tax liabilities, we use the Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center Microsimulation Model. 8 Table 3 provides detail on the steps taken to convert actual 2004 tax revenue to the revenue that would be collected under an R-base individual tax. Moving to an R-base would exempt $626.1 billion of interest receipts and other capital income, but also disallow $357.8 billion of interest deductions, for a net drop of $268.2 billion in taxable income. 9 The total reduction in taxable income is $293.3 billion, resulting in a decline of $33.7 billion in tax liability, as reflected in the difference between the second and third columns of the second row of Table 1. The ratio of the change in tax liability to the change in taxable income is just 11.5%, similar to the ratio in 1995, reflecting the fact that the disallowed interest deductions are concentrated among those in the top tax brackets whereas the exempted capital income tends to be received by those in low tax brackets. Table 1 provides the numbers we need to draw conclusions about how much tax on capital income is now collected, and the role of the 2002-3 tax changes in that result. The difference between tax collected and what would be collected under an R-base tax forms the basis of the estimates. Thus, we estimate that the current tax law collects $63.8 billion ($1034.3 - $970.5) on capital income. This compares to $138.7 billion ($1109.2 billion - $970.5 billion) 5

in tax collected on capital income if neither the expensing provisions nor the preferential rate on dividends and capital gains had been enacted. Thus, the 2002-3 provisions affecting capital income reduced the tax on capital income by $74.9 billion. These 2002-3 changes therefore took us very close to collecting no revenue at all from capital income, just $63.8 billion in total. Finally, we estimate the capital income tax revenue implications of significantly expanding tax-free savings accounts, as was proposed in 2003 and is likely to be reconsidered in 2004. We estimate the revenue consequences in two ways. First, we allow married couples filing jointly to exempt from taxable income up to $25,000 ($12,500 for single filers) of currently taxed interest, dividends, and capital gains. This is meant to approximate the long-term consequences of allowing up to $50,000 per year of contributions ($25,000 for single filers), figuring ten years of contributions and a five percent rate of return. Second, we simulate the revenue effects of imposing no individual tax on interest income, dividends, or capital gains. Depending on which simulation procedure we employ, the expanded tax-free savings accounts push the U.S. tax system beyond a consumption tax in the sense that revenue would be lost from taxes on capital income. Comparing the fourth and second columns of Table 1 shows that exempting $25,000 ($12,500) of interest, dividends, and capital gains from taxable income would in the long run reduce individual income tax revenue by $43.3 billion and, as shown in parentheses, completely exempting these items (in both cases retaining interest deductibility) would cost $107.6 billion in individual income tax revenue. 10 The net result is that, depending on how we model the long-run revenue cost of expanded tax-free savings accounts, the total 6

revenue collected from capital income will either be just $20.5 billion ($991.0 - $970.5) or will be minus $43.8 billion ($926.7 $970.5). III. Conclusions As of 2004, the U.S tax system has returned to the situation of the mid-1980 s wherein our income tax system raises little revenue from taxing capital income. If extensive tax-free savings accounts were to be introduced, the system would raise almost no revenue from capital income and possibly subsidize, rather than tax, capital income. The main culprit in this state of affairs is the retention of interest deductibility. Although the revenue from taxing capital income is small, the gains that would result from a clean consumption tax have not been attained, as there remain distortions to both saving and investment decisions, and distortions across capital assets, portfolios, corporate financing, and choice of organizational form under the patchwork of provisions that have been adopted. 7

Table 1 Capital Income Tax Revenue Consequences of Recent and Proposed Tax Reforms (billions of dollars in calendar year 2004) 2004 tax law with 2001 capital income provisions 2004 tax law R-base tax 2004 tax law with expanded savings accounts Corporate income tax 226.5 201.5 171.4 201.5 Personal income tax 882.7 832.8 799.1 789.5 (725.2) Total 1109.2 1034.3 970.5 991.0 (926.7) 8

Table 2 Change in corporate tax base and liability between pre-2002 tax law and an R-base tax, using data aged to 2004, for non-financial C-corps ($billions) Step amounts 1. plus: net interest payments 66.1 2. plus: depletion, amortization and depreciation 682.1 3. less: new capital investment 766.0 4. less: net dividend income 10.6 5. less: net capital and noncapital gains 68.2 6. less: inventory adjustment 60.9 7. equals: net change in taxable income -157.6 8. times: average effective tax rate (before credits) 34.95% 9. equals: net change in tax liability (before credits) -55.1 9

Table 3 Change in individual tax base and liability under an R-base tax calendar year, 2004 ($billions) Step amount 1. Current-law taxable income 4,818.6 2. Less: Schedule B interest income 208.1 3. Less: Other capital income 418.0 4. Plus: Schedule A interest deductions 357.8 5. Net direct change in taxable income -268.2 6. Indirect change in taxable income -25.1 7. Total change in taxable income -293.3 8. R-Base taxable income 4,525.3 9. Implied change in tax liability -33.7 10

References Becker, Johannes and Clemens Fuest. The GKS-Measure of the Effective Tax Rate on Investment: Theory and Empirical Evidence for Germany. Working paper, University of Cologne, November 2003. Gordon, Roger and Joel Slemrod. Do We Collect Any Revenue from Taxing Capital Income? in Lawrence Summers, ed., Tax policy and the economy, Vol. 2. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1988, pp. 89-130. Gordon, Roger et al. Do We Now Collect Any Revenue from Taxing Capital Income? Journal of Public Economics, April 2004a, 88(5), pp. 981-1009. Gordon, Roger et al. A New Summary Measure of the Effective Tax Rate on Investment, in Peter Birch Sorensen, ed., Measuring the tax burden on capital and labour. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, forthcoming 2004b. Kalambokidis, Laura. What is Being Taxed? A Test for the Existence of Excess Profit in the Corporate Income Tax Base. Ph.D. dissertation, University of Michigan, 1992. McLure, Charles E., Jr. "The Tax Reform Act of 1986: Tax Reform's Finest Hour or Death Throes of the Income Tax?" National Tax Journal, September 1988, 41(3), pp. 305-15. 11

Meade Committee Report. The structure and reform of direct taxation. Boston: Allen & Unwin, 1978. Shoven, John. "Using the Corporate Cash Flow Tax to Integrate Corporate and Personal Taxes," in Proceedings of the 83rd annual conference of the national tax association. Columbus, OH: National Tax Association-Tax Institute of America, 1991, pp. 19-26. Weisman, Jonathan. Anti-Tax Crusaders Work for Big Shift. Washington Post, June 14, 2003, p. A01. 12

FOOTNOTES *Roger Gordon, Department of Economics, University of California, San Diego, 9500 Gilman Drive, La Jolla, CA 92093, 858-534-4828 (phone), 858-534-7040 (fax), rogordon@ucsd.edu; Laura Kalambokidis, Department of Applied Economics, University of Minnesota, 217f Classroom-Office Building, 1994 Buford Avenue, St. Paul, MN 55108-6040, 612-625-1995 (phone), 612-625-6245 (fax), lkalambo@apec.umn.edu; Jeffrey Rohaly, Urban Institute, 2100 M Street NW, Washington, DC 20037, 202-261-5877 (phone), 202-833-4388 (fax), JRohaly@ui.urban.org; Joel Slemrod, Office of Tax Policy Research, University of Michigan, 701 Tappan Street, Rm. A2120, Ann Arbor, MI 48109-1234, 734-936-3914 (phone), 734-763- 4032 (fax), jslemrod@umich.edu. 1 The Tax Reform Act of 1986, which in many ways moved the definition of taxable income closer to economic income, may be an exception. See Charles E. McLure, Jr. (1988). 2 Jonathan Weisman (2003) reported that the Bush administration was debating whether to push a plan for stealth tax reform in five easy pieces --lower marginal income tax rates, including capital gains tax rates; eliminate taxes on dividends; accelerate the speed with which businesses can write investment expenses off their tax bills [ultimately to the point of 100 percent first-year expensing of business capital investment]; expand the Roth individual retirement account to all personal saving; and exclude export and other foreign trade income of American companies from taxation. 13

3 These changes are made for nonfinancial C-corporations only, since an R-base is not an appropriate measure of the labor income generated in financial intermediaries. 4 John Shoven (1991) applied this methodology to U.S. data for 1986. Laura Kalambokidis (1992) looked at the implications for corporate tax payments by industry for each year from 1975 to 1987. Johannes Becker and Clemens Fuest (2003) apply it to Germany. 5 These estimates apply to calendar year 2004. The Congressional Budget Office does not report fiscal year estimates of corporate tax revenues, but they do report both calendar year and fiscal year projections of corporate profits. The pre-adjustment number for 2004 corporate tax reported in Table 1 is derived by assuming that the ratio of calendar year revenue to fiscal year revenue (1.012) is the same as the ratio of calendar year profit to fiscal year profit. The individual tax revenue estimates come from the Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center Microsimulation Model, described in more detail below. 6 Specifically, we reduce depreciation deductions for earlier equipment investment, reflecting the fact that in steady state half of equipment investment would have been expensed previously. Our calculations assume that the expensing provisions will be extended indefinitely, rather than expire as current legislation provides. 7 Unfortunately, due to a change in the industrial classification codes in 1998, these figures cannot be compared to those from Gordon et al. (2004a) or Gordon and Slemrod (1988), since the definition of non-financial corporations changed. In particular, we estimate that this 14

change in industrial classification resulted in a drop in reported net interest payments from approximately 192.1 to 66.1. As a result, with a comparable industrial classification, we estimate that corporate tax revenue figures would have been lower by 44.0 billion dollars in both columns 1 and 2 in Table 1, reducing the net tax revenue from taxes on capital income by this amount under both 2004 tax law and 2001 tax law. 8 The Tax Policy Center model is based on data from the 1999 public-use file produced by the Statistics of Income Division of the Internal Revenue Service. The file contains about 132,000 records with detailed information from federal individual income tax returns filed in the 1999 calendar year. A statistical match with the March 2000 Current Population Survey provides demographic and other information to supplement the tax data. The tax model has two components: a statistical routine that uses forecasts from the Congressional Budget Office, the IRS, and the Bureau of the Census to age or extrapolate the 1999 data to create representative samples of the filing and non-filing population for future years; and a detailed tax calculator that computes individual income tax liability for all tax units in the sample under current law and under alternative policy proposals. See http://taxpolicycenter.org/taxmodel for additional details. 9 There is a further $25.1 billion indirect reduction in taxable income due to the effect of the phaseout of itemized deductions and personal exemptions based on adjusted gross income (AGI) and the limitation on itemized deductions--the $357.8 billion in disallowed interest deductions is a gross value before the limitation on itemized deductions is applied. When calculating the revenue impact of moving to an R-base tax, due to data limitations it is assumed that all capital income that is subject to the regular tax is excluded from both the regular base and the alternative 15

minimum tax base (AMT). Because the AMT taxes some forms of capital income differently than the regular tax, this leads us to slightly underestimate the revenue loss from moving to the R-base tax. 10 For the first estimate, we assume that individuals first deposit into the accounts assets yielding interest income, short-term capital gains, and dividends not eligible for the preferential rates, and then deposit assets yielding dividends and long-term capital gains, until the limit is reached. That behavior would minimize tax liability. We ignore any increase in borrowing to finance further deposits in these accounts. 16