The Budget Outlook. Auerbach, Gale, Orszag. no. June The Ten-Year Budget Outlook

Similar documents
The Bush Tax Cut: One Year Later

THE CHANGING BUDGET OUTLOOK: CAUSES AND IMPLICATIONS

The Budget Outlook and Options for Fiscal Policy

The Vanishing Budget Surplus: Interpreting CBO's New Projections and Fiscal Prospects

tax break by William G. Gale and Peter R. Orszag

Facing the Music: The Fiscal Outlook at the End of the Bush Administration

tax break Perspectives on the Budget Outlook by William G. Gale and Peter R. Orszag I. Introduction

CBPP S UPDATED LONG-TERM FISCAL DEFICIT AND DEBT PROJECTIONS

The Budget Outlook: Updates and Implications

Does the Budget Surplus Justify Large-Scale Tax Cuts?: Updates and Extensions

The Budget: Plus Ça Change, Plus C est La Même Chose

Tempting Fate: The Federal Budget Outlook

The Federal Budget Outlook, Chapter 11

PERSPECTIVES ON THE BUDGET SURPLUS *

SHOULD THE BUDGET RULES BE CHANGED SO THAT LARGE-SCALE BORROWING TO FUND INDIVIDUAL ACCOUNTS IS LEFT OUT OF THE BUDGET? 1

Issues in Budget Reform

(Still) Tempting Fate

New Estimates of the Budget Outlook: Plus Ça Change, Plus C est la Même Chose. Alan J. Auerbach, William G. Gale, and Peter R.

THE US FISCAL GAP AND RETIREMENT SAVING

The Real Fiscal Danger

What The New CBO Report Shows Budget And Economic Outlook Has Not Improved by James Horney and Richard Kogan

VIEWPOINTS. tax notes. The Federal Budget Outlook: No News Is Bad News. By Alan J. Auerbach and William G. Gale

Bush Still on Track to Borrow $10 Trillion by 2014 According to Latest Official Estimates

WHAT THE NEW TRUSTEES REPORT SHOWS ABOUT SOCIAL SECURITY By Jason Furman and Robert Greenstein

The Fiscal Outlook at the Beginning of the Trump Administration. Alan J. Auerbach and William G. Gale. January 30, 2017

Should the President s Tax Cuts Be Made Permanent?

Policy. Despite substantial attention given to fiscal policy. Economic ISSUES IN

FACT SHEET CBO BUDGET OUTLOOK FY

GAO. The Federal Government s Long-Term Fiscal Outlook. January 2010 Update. United States Government Accountability Office

THE PRESIDENT S BUDGET: A PRELIMINARY ANALYSIS

The Economic Crisis and the Fiscal Crisis: 2009 and Beyond

On June 7, 2001, President George W. Bush signed the

Perspectives on the Tax Stimulus Debate

The Economic Crisis and the Fiscal Crisis: 2009 and Beyond

PRINCIPLES FOR ECONOMIC STIMULUS. By Andrew Lee

Evaluating the Budget Surplus and Tax Policy Options. Committee on the Budget United States House of Representatives. March 8, 2001.

PROPOSED SENATE TAX CUTS FOR SMALL BUSINESSES AND FARMERS NOT A TOP PRIORITY, GIVEN BUDGET OUTLOOK AND OTHER PRESSURES.

Statement of Chris Edwards, Director of Fiscal Policy, Cato Institute. before the Senate Democratic Policy Committee

The Fiscal Outlook in a Period of Policy Uncertainty

tax notes Volume 150, Number 11 March 14, 2016

Senate Proposal for Balanced Budget Amendment Would Require Extreme Budget Cuts By Richard Kogan and Cecile Murray 1

The 75-Year Budget Outlook October 25, 2018

WHAT THE 2007 TRUSTEES REPORT SHOWS ABOUT SOCIAL SECURITY By Chad Stone and Robert Greenstein

CBO s Official Baseline Projections Substantially Understate the Deficits That Will Occur if Current Policies Are Extended

WHAT YOU SHOULD KNOW ABOUT THE BUDGET OUTLOOK. William Gale Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center February 8, 2013 ABSTRACT

tbo The Budget Outlook Is Even Worse than Reported BY: DEMIAN BRADY A publication of the National Taxpayers Union Foundation FEBRUARY 8, 2019

I S S U E B R I E F PUBLIC POLICY INSTITUTE PPI PRESIDENT BUSH S TAX PLAN: IMPACTS ON AGE AND INCOME GROUPS

Federal Tax Policy and the States

SENATE FINANCE COMMITTEE PLAN INCLUDES SOUND STIMULUS PROPOSALS. by Joel Friedman, Robert Greenstein, and Richard Kogan

The Future of Social Security

Fiscal and Generational Imbalances: An Update Jagadeesh Gokhale and Kent Smetters 1, 2. August Abstract:

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2011 UPDATE IN PERSPECTIVE

center for retirement research

Defining the problem: the difference between current deficit and long-term deficits

tax break Sunsets in the Tax Code by William G. Gale and Peter R. Orszag I. Introduction

Statement of. Ben S. Bernanke. Chairman. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. before the. Committee on the Budget

SMALLER DEFICIT ESTIMATE NO SURPRISE New OMB Estimates Do Not Support Claims About Tax Cuts By James Horney

75-YEAR PAY-AS-YOU-GO PROPOSAL COULD ADVERSELY AFFECT SOCIAL SECURITY, MEDICARE, SSI, VETERANS DISABILITY, AND OTHER PROGRAMS

The Legacy of the 2001 and 2003 Bush Tax Cuts

Notes Numbers in the text and tables may not add up to totals because of rounding. Unless otherwise indicated, years referred to in describing the bud

Notes Unless otherwise indicated, the years referred to in describing budget numbers are fiscal years, which run from October 1 to September 30 and ar

WebMemo22. New CBO Budget Baseline Shows that Soaring Spending Not Falling Revenues Risks Drowning America in Debt

Taxing Capital Income Once * Leonard E. Burman

The Wrong Way to Fix Social Security. Peter R. Orszag 1 Joseph A. Pechman Senior Fellow The Brookings Institution

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

continue to average 0.2 percent of GDP from 2018 through 2028, CBO projects.

Understanding the National Debt and the Debt Ceiling

Forgotten but Not Gone: The Long-Term Fiscal Imbalance

AN ANALYSIS OF THE RECENT DETERIORATION IN THE FISCAL CONDITION OF THE U.S. GOVERNMENT

NEW TAX CUTS PRIMARILY BENEFITING MILLIONAIRES SLATED TO TAKE EFFECT IN JANUARY

Ryan Plan Gets 69 Percent of Its Budget Cuts From Programs for People With Low or Moderate Incomes By Richard Kogan and Joel Friedman

WHAT WOULD IT SAY ABOUT CONGRESS S PRIORITIES TO WAIVE PAYGO FOR THE AMT PATCH? By Aviva Aron-Dine

If Not Now, When? New Estimates of the Federal Budget Outlook

Report for Congress. The Budget for Fiscal Year Updated April 10, 2003

Updating the U.S. Budget Outlook March 2, 2018

CBO Report Echoes Trustees on Medicare, Social Security

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2006 UPDATE IN PERSPECTIVE

REPUBLICAN PROPOSAL TO PAY FOR PAYROLL TAX EXTENSION WOULD INCREASE ALREADY SEVERE CUTS IN DISCRETIONARY PROGRAMS by James R.

Mr. Chairman, Senator Conrad, and other distinguished members of the Committee,

Saving the Surplus to Save Social Security: What Does It Mean?

The Congressional Budget Office s 2012 Long-Term Budget Outlook: An Analysis

Senator Kerry s Tax Proposals. Leonard E. Burman and Jeffrey Rohaly 1 Revised July 23, 2004

DECISION TIME: THE FISCAL EFFECTS OF EXTENDING THE 2001 AND 2003 TAX CUTS FISCAL ANALYSIS INITIATIVE

Analysis of Congressional Budget Office s August 2012 Updateof the Budget and Economic Outlook

The coming financial crisis: Policy corrections needed

SOCIAL SECURITY S FINANCIAL OUTLOOK: THE 2007 REPORT IN PERSPECTIVE

SOCIAL SECURITY S $20 TRILLION SHORTFALL: WHY REFORM IS NEEDED

The Fiscal Problem: Gone Today, Here Tomorrow

GETTING TO AN EFFICIENT CARBON TAX How the Revenue Is Used Matters

AUGUST 2012 An Update to the Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2012 to 2022 Provided as a convenience, this screen-friendly version is identic

An Overview of the Clinton Budget Plan

The 2016 CBO Long-Term Budget Outlook July 12, 2016

Options to Fix the AMT

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. Economics 134 Spring 2018 Professor David Romer

CBO s 2017 Long-Term Budget Outlook March 30, 2017

PROGRAM CUTS UNDER A BALANCED BUDGET AMENDMENT: HOW SEVERE MIGHT THEY BE? By Richard Kogan

Why Tax Revenues Must Rise

shortfalls in perpetuity. 3 The 2003 Trustees report, for example, pushes the insolvency date back by assuming that older

The Budget and Economic Outlook: 2018 to 2028

Update: CBO s January 2016 Full Budget and Economic Outlook January 25, 2016

Transcription:

Auerbach, Gale, Orszag The Budget Outlook no. 100 June 2002 The official federal budget outlook has deteriorated dramatically since early 2001, due to last year s tax cut, the economic slowdown, and the terrorist attacks on September 11, 2001. The official projections, however, are overly optimistic. In addition to the pressures from the long-anticipated increase in entitlement spending as the nation ages, the government now also faces growing spending needs for defense and homeland security. These trends imply that future taxes must rise, future spending outside of defense and the elderly must decline, or obligations to the elderly and to defense be reduced. Faced with these constraints, the Bush administration proposes reduced spending for low-income households and substantial increases in federal borrowing. But rather than propose higher taxes or even reconsider some of the cuts passed last year, the administration advocates substantial new tax cuts, including making the 2001 tax cut permanent. The proposed tax cuts disproportionately benefit high-income households and would significantly worsen the budget outlook. A more responsible fiscal policy would freeze the tax cut at its current level, which would save enough revenue, relative to a permanent extension, to keep Social Security solvent through 2075. Strictly following the letter of the law and allowing the cuts to expire as scheduled in 2010 would save twice as much revenue over the same period. The Ten-Year Budget Outlook Between January 2001 and January 2002, the ten-year unified surplus projected by the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) fell from $5.6 trillion to $1.6 trillion (see table 1) for the 2002-2011 period. The decline is concentrated almost completely in the non-social Security part of the budget, which fell from a projected surplus of $3.1 trillion in January 2001 to a projected deficit of $0.7 trillion by January 2002. About 40 percent of the shift is due to last year s tax cut (the Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001, or EGTRRA), another 40 percent arises from economic and technical changes in the forecast, and the remaining 20 percent is attributable to increased spending, primarily defense and homeland security outlays in the aftermath of the terrorist attacks. These official forecasts are constructed according to a variety of statutes that are intended to provide a neutral benchmark against which proposed legislation can be measured. But the rules employed may not be the most useful or appropriate way to gauge the government s fiscal condition or to estimate the funds available to finance tax cuts or new spending. As we discuss later, these forecasts contain 1775 Massachusetts Ave. N.W. Washington, DC 20036-2188 Tel: 202-797-6105 www.brookings.edu

Alan Auerbach Options for Restoring Alan Auerbach is Robert D. Burch Professor of Economics and Law, director of the Burch Center for Tax Policy and Public Finance at the University of California, Berkeley, and a research associate at the National Bureau of Economic Research. William G. Gale considerable uncertainty. A second (Surplus or Deficit in Billions of Current Dollars) Table 1: Changing CBO Budget Projections problem arises from Projection Projection Unified Non-Social Date Horizon Budget Security Budget the treatment of retirement January 2001 2002-11 5,610 3,119 August 2001 2002-11 3,397 846 programs. The January 2002 2002-11 1,602-744 baseline counts January 2002 2003-12 2,263-242 March 2002 2003-12 2,380-125 current contributions, but not future March 2002 Administration 2003-12 681-1,824 liabilities, of the Social Security and Medicare programs. These programs will run substantial cash flow surpluses over the next decade but substantial deficits over longer horizons. Likewise, trust funds holding pension reserves for federal military and civilian employees are projected to run significant cash-flow surpluses over the next ten years, but their long-term liabilities are not included in the budget. Accounting for the overall status of such programs within the conventional ten-year budget framework is difficult. But within that ten-year window, it is less misleading to exclude the retirement programs altogether than to include only the contributions. We make such an adjustment in our calculations. William Gale is the Arjay and Frances Fearing Miller Chair in Federal Economic Policy in the Economic Studies program at the Brookings Institution. Peter R. Orszag The third problem with the baseline involves CBO projections of discretionary spending. CBO assumes real discretionary spending authority will remain constant over the budget period at the level prevailing at the beginning of the period. Such an assumption implies that real outlays will fall by about 9 percent relative to the population, and by about 20 percent relative to Gross Domestic Product (GDP), over the next decade. Historical experience suggests such changes are unlikely to occur. It would be more reasonable to assume that real discretionary spending will grow with the population, to maintain current services on a perperson basis, or with GDP. Peter Orszag is the Joseph A. Pechman Senior Fellow in Economic Studies at the Brookings Institution. Another set of problems involves the revenue projections. At least three issues arise here. First, several temporary tax provisions are scheduled to expire over the next decade. In the past, however, these temporary provisions have typically been extended each time the expiration dates approached, and CBO refers to their prospective extension as a matter of course. In light of this practice, current policy is more aptly viewed as including the continuance of these so-called extenders. To be clear, we are not arguing that extending the provisions is desirable, just that it is a realistic statement of the current policy trajectory. A second, and similar, problem with the revenue projections arises because the 2001 tax cut officially sunsets at the end of 2010, meaning the tax code will revert to what it would have 2 BROOKINGS POLICY BRIEF JUNE 2002 NO. 100

Fiscal Discipline been had EGTRRA never existed. Virtually no one believes the tax provisions will actually sunset completely. But exactly which parts of the bill Congress will extend, or when, is unclear. For purposes of constructing a current policy baseline, we assume that current policy toward the sunset provisions is the same as current policy toward the temporary provisions noted above. Thus, we assume that all of the sunset provisions will be removed and the tax cut will be made permanent. As with the temporary provisions, this assumption reflects a best guess about the current policy trajectory, not our view of optimal policy. Surplus or Deficit (billions of dollars) Figure 1: Baseline and Adjusted Budget Outcomes (in billions of dollars) 800 600 400 200 0-200 -400 1. CBO baseline 2. Exclude Retirement Trust funds 3. Fix Tax Problems 4. Hold Real DS/Person Constant 5. Hold DS/GDP Constant -600 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 1. Projection date January 2002 Projection Horizon 2003-12 CBO Baseline 2,263 - Adjustment for Retirement Funds Social Security 2,505 Medicare 390 Government Pensions 476 Third, the alternative minimum tax (AMT) is a complex levy that is intended to prevent aggressive tax sheltering but instead mainly affects households who have large families or who live in states with high income taxes. Enacted in the late 1960s and strengthened in 1986, the AMT affected about 2 million taxpayers in 2001 or about 2 percent of those with positive tax liability. Because the AMT is not indexed for inflation, the number of AMT taxpayers was projected to rise 2. 3. 4. 5. = Surplus or deficit, adjusted for retirement funds -1,108 - Adjustment for current tax policy Repeal sunset provisions 402 Reduce AMT taxpayers to pre-egtrra law levels 320 Reduce AMT taxpayers from pre-egtrra law to 2 percent 377 Extend expiring provisions 142 Interest 178 = Surplus or deficit, adjusted for retirement funds and -2,527 tax policy - Adjustment to hold discretionary spending/person constant Hold real discretionary spending/person constant 416 Interest 85 = Surplus or deficit, adjusted for retirement funds and current policy with real discretionary spending per person constant -3,028 - Further adjustment if discretionary spending/gdp constant Outlays 790 Interest 149 = Surplus or deficit, adjusted for retirement funds and current policy, with discretionary spending/gross Domestic Product constant -3,968 The Budget Outlook 3

to 18 million by 2010 under pre-egtrra law, and is now projected to rise to 35.5 million by 2010, or about one-third of all taxpayers. No one seriously expects current law to prevail. We define current policy towards the AMT as holding constant at 2 percent the share of taxpayers facing the AMT. Figure 1 shows the sizable effects of adjusting the surplus for retirement trust funds and current policy assumptions. Removing the accumulations in retirement trust funds changes the January 2002 projection for the budget balance between 2003 and 2012 from a surplus of $2.3 trillion to a deficit of $1.1 trillion. Adjusting the revenue baseline to make EGTRRA permanent, holding the number of AMT taxpayers at 2 percent, and extending the other expiring tax provisions increases the deficit to $3.0 trillion if discretionary spending is held constant on a per-person basis, and to $4.0 trillion if discretionary spending is a constant share of GDP. Figure 1 also shows the contrast between official and adjusted budget figures on an annual basis. In 2012 alone, the difference is about $1 trillion (if real per-capita discretionary spending is constant) or more (if spending grows with GDP). Perhaps more importantly, the trends are quite different: the CBO baseline suggests that the underlying fiscal status of the government will temporarily improve over the coming decade before deteriorating again as the baby boomers retire, whereas the adjusted baseline suggests no such temporary improvement. The Long-Term Fiscal Gap The adjusted budget measures provide a more accurate picture of the government s underlying financial status than the official figures, but they do not fully reflect the long-term implications of current fiscal choices. To take these factors into account, we estimate the long-term fiscal gap under Table 2: different policies. The fiscal gap Estimates of the Fiscal Gap is the size of the permanent (As Percent of GDP) increase in taxes or reductions in Forecast Horizon 2002-2075 Permanent non-interest expenditures (as a CBO Baseline 3.30 7.10 Adjusted Revenue Baseline 5.35 9.3 constant share of GDP) that Adjusted Revenue Baseline with Freeze 4.63 8.54 would be required now to keep Adjusted Revenue Baseline with Expiration of EGTRRA 3.9 7.82 Bush Budget 5.1 9.0 the long-term ratio of government Bush Budget with Adjusted Revenue Baseline 5.64 9.6 debt to GDP at its current level at the end of the forecast period. The fiscal gap measures the current budgetary status of the government, taking into account longterm influences. For example, using the CBO baseline noted above, the fiscal gap through 2075 is now 3.3 percent of GDP (table 2). This implies that an immediate increase in taxes or cut in spending of 3.3 percent of GDP or over $300 billion per year in current terms would be needed to maintain fiscal balance through 2075. These figures assume that the 2001 tax cut expires in 2010. Using the 4 BROOKINGS POLICY BRIEF JUNE 2002 NO. 100

adjusted revenue baseline, which does not make that assumption, the fiscal gap through 2075 amounts to 5.3 percent of GDP. On a permanent basis, the fiscal gap is substantially higher 7.1 percent of GDP under the CBO assumptions and 9.3 percent under our adjusted revenue baseline. The permanent effects are much larger because the budget is expected to be running substantial deficits in the years approaching and after 2075. To be sure, no one expects Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid, the programs primarily responsible for the fiscal gap, to remain in their current forms over the next seven decades. But the projections indicate what will happen if action is not taken, and the estimates serve as indicators of the changes in spending and revenues that are needed now. Although not shown in the table, the longer such changes are delayed, the more extensive the changes will have to be. These results, of course, are subject to considerable uncertainty, but the uncertainty does not mean that these projections should be ignored. The serious consequences of a relatively bad long-term outcome should spur a precautionary response from policymakers now. In addition, the longerterm budget problems are driven by demographic pressures that seem relatively likely to occur. Fiscal Policy Options: The Administration s Proposals and Alternatives The Bush administration s budget for fiscal year 2003 exacerbates an already difficult budget situation. Relative to CBO s baseline, the administration s proposals would reduce the unified budget surplus by $1.7 trillion and leave a surplus of about $700 billion from 2003 to 2012 (table 1). The budget would increase the long-term fiscal gap by about 1.8 percent of GDP relative to the CBO baseline, to 5.1 percent of GDP through 2075 and 9 percent on a permanent basis (table 2). If the administration s budget is adjusted so that the AMT problem is fixed and the expiring tax provisions are extended, the fiscal gap then rises to 5.6 percent of GDP through 2075 and 9.6 percent of GDP on a permanent basis. These figures imply massive fiscal adjustments in the future. Under the administration s proposed budget, defense and homeland security spending would rise by about $518 billion over the next ten years. Although the size and composition of the specific defense proposals has raised some questions, higher security spending in general is widely supported in response to the September 11 attacks. The real question is how such spending will be financed. As a matter of arithmetic, there are only three ways to pay for higher defense spending: reductions in other federal spending, increases in taxes, or increases in borrowing and borrowing just defers (but does not lessen) the ultimate need to cut other spending or raise taxes. The administration has chosen the first and third methods and raised overall financing needs by proposing tax cuts rather than tax increases. The administration s budget proposes significant cuts in discretionary spending outside of defense and homeland security. The proposed cuts for 2003 target community and regional development, The Budget Outlook 5

low-income energy assistance, environmental protection, job training, and other initiatives, many of which primarily benefit low- and middle-income families. The administration, furthermore, would increase net borrowing (reduce the surplus or raise the deficit) by $1.7 trillion over the next ten years. Despite the proposed spending cuts, the increase in borrowing exceeds the increases for defense by more than $1 trillion. The main reason why is that the administration actually adds to the financing problem by proposing new tax cuts, including making permanent the components of EGTRRA that are scheduled to expire in 2010. Including the effects of extending EGTRRA, the administration would cut taxes by $746 billion between 2002 and 2012, making the tax cuts themselves larger than the spending increases for defense and homeland security. With the added interest payments due to higher federal debt, the total budgetary costs of the tax cuts would be $932 billion. And, just as the spending cuts appear to hurt low-income households, the proposed tax cuts would predominantly benefit high-income households. The top 1 percent of the income distribution, for example, would receive roughly 36 percent of the benefits from making EGTRRA permanent, but pays only about 26 percent of all federal taxes. It is worth contemplating the overall message of the combined spending and tax proposals. In the aftermath of last year s tax cut and the massive deterioration of the government s financial status, the administration is proposing to finance a war on terrorism by cutting social programs and raising borrowing from young and future generations that are already saddled with substantial fiscal burdens. And the program cuts and borrowing are significantly greater than they would otherwise have to be because of the tax cuts that are also included in the budget. Alternatives approaches are both available and attractive. One way to improve fiscal balance is to rethink the 2001 tax cut legislation. Allowing the tax cut to expire as scheduled in 2010 would reduce the fiscal gap by about 1.4 percent of GDP through 2075 relative to making the tax cut permanent (table 2). A second option would freeze the cut. A freeze would allow the cuts that have already taken effect to remain in place and indeed to become permanent, but would repeal the cuts scheduled to take place in the future. Relative to a permanent extension of EGTRRA, a freeze would reduce the fiscal gap by 0.7 percent of GDP (table 2). These results show that a sizable fiscal gap existed before the tax cut was implemented, that EGTRRA substantially exacerbated the problem, and that freezing the tax cut or letting it expire would be a clear step toward restoring fiscal responsibility. Interestingly, the estimated shortfall in the Social Security trust fund is 0.7 percent of GDP over the next seventy-five years. Freezing the tax cut, therefore, would save sufficient funds (relative to making it permanent) to eliminate the actuarial imbalance in Social Security through 2075. Allowing the tax cut to expire in 2010 would save twice as much revenue over the same period. The magnitude of the savings available from curtailing the tax cut relative to the Social Security 6 BROOKINGS POLICY BRIEF JUNE 2002 NO. 100

shortfall may seem surprising. But that is because tax cut figures are often presented over ten years, while the trust fund imbalances are reported over seventy-five years, and because the administration has often argued that the tax cut is moderate while the Social Security shortfall is huge. The truth is that the tax cut has substantial long-term fiscal implications, and is significantly larger than the size of the seventy-five-year Social Security shortfall. It is also worth noting that an expiration or freeze would impose the costs of the government s fiscal imbalance on those who are most able to afford it high-income households. The tax cut in general, and the tax cuts that are scheduled to take place between 2003 and 2010 in particular, are disproportionately weighted toward higher-income households. The Budget Horizon Several of the rules governing the current budget process expire this fall, and the administration s budget puts forward a variety of ideas regarding budget rules and process. Most prominently, the administration s budget emphasizes a five-year horizon, rather than the now-standard ten-year focus, claiming that 2001 showed ten-year estimates to be too uncertain to be used. the observation that the fiscal gap is Although ten-year budget forecasts are indeed uncertain, the administration s shift to five-year figures is problematic for several reasons. First, last year, the administration used the ten-year budget forecast to argue that its tax cut was affordable. Now, by arguing that the ten-year horizon is too uncertain to be useful, the administration undercuts its own arguments for the tax cut. Second, the administration proposes important new provisions that take place beyond the five-year horizon highlighted by the proposal to eliminate the 2010 EGTRRA sunset which would be omitted entirely in a fiveyear budget. Third, it is disingenuous to argue that the decline in the ten-year surplus highlights the inherent uncertainty in medium-term projections when much of the shift reflects the effects of EGTRRA, the administration s own policy. Finally, the one- and five-year budget surpluses showed larger percentage changes in the past year than the ten-year surplus did, so it is unclear why volatility is a reason to move to shorter budget horizons. Given all of these reasons, plus politicians who consistently propose tax cuts that do not take place until well into the future, and a long-term budget gap that reveals itself fully only over an extended period of time, it is hard to imagine a more inappropriate budget reform than shortening the budget s time horizon. Conclusion The notion that the surplus is the taxpayers The sizable fiscal shortfalls estimated above imply that tax cuts are not simply a matter of returning unneeded or unused funds to taxpayers, but rather a choice to require other, future taxpayers to cover This policy brief is based on the authors working paper, The Budget Outlook and Options for Fiscal Policy, (http://www. brookings.edu/views/ papers/gale/200204. htm) which documents the calculations and cites the sources used here. money and should be returned to them ignores the taxpayers debt and must be paid by them. Brookings gratefully acknowledges the generosity of the Virginia Wellington Cabot Foundation for its support of the Policy Brief series. The views expressed in this Policy Brief are those of the authors and are not necessarily those of the trustees, officers, or other staff members of the Brookings Institution. Copyright 2002 The Brookings Institution The Budget Outlook 7

The Brookings Institution 1775 Massachusetts Ave. N.W. Washington, DC 20036 NONPROFIT ORG. U.S. POSTAGE PAID FREDERICK, MD PERMIT NO. 225 Recent Policy Briefs Putin s Agenda, America s Choice Clifford G. Gaddy and Fiona Hill (May 2002) Strengthening Institutional Capacity in Poor Countries Carol Graham (April 2002) The Enron Failure and the State of Corporate Disclosure Robert E. Litan (April 2002) Creating a Scorecard for the CRA Service Test Michael E. Stegman, Kelly Cochran, Robert Faris (March 2002) What Federal Employees Want From Reform Reform Watch #5 Paul C. Light (March 2002) The Future of Securities Markets Conference Report #10 Richard J. Herring and Robert E. Litan (March 2002) Related Materials The Federal Budget: Politics, Policy, Process (Revised Edition) Allen Schick with Felix LoStracco (2000) Defense Policy Choices for the Bush Administration 2001-05 Michael E. O Hanlon (2001) a substantial long-term deficit that last year s tax cut significantly exacerbated. Likewise, the notion that the surplus is the taxpayers money and should be returned to them ignores the observation that the fiscal gap is the taxpayers debt and must be paid by them. Thus, the issue is not whether taxpayers should have their tax payments returned, but rather which taxpayers current or future will be required to pay for the liabilities and spending obligations incurred by current and past taxpayers. Faced with the massive deterioration in the fiscal situation and the need to defend the country after the terrorist attacks, the administration has understandably raised current spending on homeland security and defense. But the administration offers no realistic program for financing this spending increase, and actually worsens the problem through further proposed tax cuts. Freezing the 2001 tax cut at its current levels would be a major step toward fiscal responsibility. In addition to addressing the fiscal imbalance, Congress and the Bush administration will need to revisit the budget process and rules in the near future. Although the current budget rules have many evident defects, they likely contributed to fiscal discipline during the 1990s. Abandoning them without an adequate replacement would be a mistake, as would reducing the budget horizon to five years. This and all previous Policy Briefs are also posted on the Brookings website at www.brookings.edu If you have questions or comments about this Policy Brief, please send an email message to policybriefs@brookings.edu Authors responses will be posted on the Brookings website.